Home Pricing, Signalling, and Sorting with Frictions
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

Pricing, Signalling, and Sorting with Frictions

  • Mats Godenhielm EMAIL logo , Klaus Kultti and Tuomo Virkola
Published/Copyright: June 18, 2019

Abstract

We analyse signalling and sorting in a market with frictions and private information. Buyers are heterogeneous, the sellers choose what quality to produce and post prices. Buyers do not observe quality, but infer it from prices. In equilibrium high-quality sellers signal quality with a price that is higher than under perfect information. Compared to the outcome under perfect information the higher price has two effects. First, it makes production of high-quality goods more attractive increasing its supply. Second, it makes high-valuation buyers worse-off, directing part of them to low-quality sellers. We determine which effect dominates; whether too many or too few sellers produce high quality. We also show that the prices of both high- and low-quality goods are higher, and the sellers do better and the buyers worse under private information. In addition, we show that an increase in the production cost of high quality may lead to higher profits and prices.

JEL Classification: D8; D4

Acknowledgements

Mats Godenhielm gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Finnish Cultural Foundation, the OP Group Research Foundation, the Society of Swedish Literature in Finland, and the Yrjö Jahnsson Foundation. Klaus Kultti gratefully acknowledges financial support from The Academy of Finland and the Yrjö Jahnsson Foundation.

An earlier version of this paper circulated under the title “High Price Signals High Quality”.

Appendix

A

Proof of Result 1

To demonstrate that there is perfect sorting we first eliminate the only possible symmetric equilibrium where all buyers are served; in such an equilibrium every seller would produce a high-quality good and ask the same price p < v.[13] Then we construct a perfectly sorting equilibrium, and finally we show that partially sorting equilibria do not exist.

Lemma 4.

Assume that c = 0. Then there does not exist an equilibrium where every seller offers a high-quality good at price p < v.

Proof.

Assume that such an equilibrium exists and consider a deviation where some seller asks price p<p . He encounters queue length determined either by the high-quality buyers’ indifference

(25)1eθθ(1p)=1eγγ(1p)

or by the low-quality buyers’ indifference

(26)1eθθ(vp)=1eγγ(vp)

As v < 1 one immediately sees that if (25) holds the RHS of (26) is greater than the LHS. Consequently, only the low-quality buyers contact the deviating seller. From (26) we can solve γp=γ1eγ1eγγeγ(vp) . Evaluating the derivative for the problem maxp1eγp at p=p we find that the derivative is positive if the price satisfies

(27)p>1eθ1eθθeθv

But this is always the case in the tentative equilibrium as the RHS of (27) is the equilibrium price when every seller has a low-quality good.   □

This means that when c = 0 some sellers price so that they attract low-quality buyers and other sellers price so that they attract high-quality buyers. The reason is that relatively many sellers price high to serve the high-quality buyers but sell their goods with relatively low probability. In contrast, relatively few sellers price low to attract low-quality buyers but sell their goods with high probability.

Next we construct a perfectly sorting equilibrium where all the low-quality buyers contact sellers who price low and all the high-quality buyers contact sellers who price high. We also assume that the low-pricing sellers have a low-quality good, and the high-pricing sellers have a high-quality good.[14]

Denote the expected queue length at the low-quality sellers by α=θ2y and at the high-quality sellers by β=θ2(1y) . The corresponding prices are given by pl=1eααeα1eαv and ph=1eββeβ1eβ . The three relations that have to hold are formally identical to (17), (18) and (19) and are given here for the ease of reference

(28)(1eααeα)v=1eββeβ
(29)eαv1eββ(vph)
(30)eβeαv
Lemma 5.

Assume that c = 0. The proportion of sellers who produce a low-quality good, y(θ), determined by (28) is unique.

Proof.

Expression (28) is equivalent to

f7(y)1+eα+αeα2eβ2βeβ=0

It is immediate that f7(0)<0 as we have assumed that 12eθ2θ2eθ2<0 which is equivalent to θ<θ . Similarly, it is immediate that f7(1)>0 . As f7(y)=αeαθ2y2+2βeβθ2(1y)2>0 we see that the solution y(θ) is unique.   □

Notice that f7(y)=0 implies that α > β or equivalently y<12 and β < θ < α. It is clear that (30) holds. Solving v from (28) and inserting it to (29) yields the following condition

eα1eββeβ1eααeα1eββ1eββeβ1eααeα1eββeβ1eβ

which is equivalent to

(31)βeαeααeα+eβ0

Differentiating the LHS of (31) with respect to β one finds that the LHS is decreasing as long as α > β. As this is the case for the equilibrium we construct the LHS attains its minimum at β = α. But then the LHS is zero. The next result shows that y(θ) behaves in the expected way.

Lemma 6.

Assume that c = 0. When the number of buyers increases the proportion of sellers who produce a low-quality good decreases, or yθ<0 .

Proof.

Totally differentiating (28) one easily determines

(32)yθ=1yαeα11y2βeβθ1y2αeα+11y22βeβ

Again, from (28) we can determine

(33)βα=αeα2βeβ

Let us see what the relationship between α and β would be if (32) were always zero, or by multiplying by θ/2 if it were the case that α2eα2β2eβ=0 . Totally differentiating we get

(34)βα=αeα2βeβ2α2β

but as α > β (34) is strictly less than (33). This shows the claim.   □

It remains to show that there are no equilibria where there is not perfect sorting. Notice that we need not study other prices but pl and ph because we can show that then a seller could deviate profitably the same way as in the proof of Claim 4.

Lemma 7.

Assume that c = 0. All equilibria feature perfect sorting.

Proof.

Assume to the contrary. One possibility is that proportion z of high-quality buyers contact the low-quality sellers. In this case α=θ+zθ2y and β=(1z)θ2(1y) . Now the high-quality buyers have to be indifferent between the sellers, or eβ=eαv which is equivalent to α=βln2 . Inserting this datum into (28) yields eβ=12ln2 . Inserting this back to the high-quality buyers’ indifference condition (30) gives eα=1ln2 which is a contradiction.

The other possibility is that proportion z of the low-quality buyers contacts the high-quality sellers. In this case α=(1z)θ2y and β=θ+zθ2(1y) . Now the low-quality buyers have to be indifferent between the sellers, or eα=1+eβ+2βeββ which is equivalent to 1eβ2βeβ+βeα=0 . But the LHS is decreasing in α and as we must have α > β the relation cannot hold.   □

Lemmata 4–7 allow us to state Result 1.

Proof of sufficiency for Proposition 1: All sellers produce high quality

Proof.

Assume that the number of buyers satisfies θθ and the cost satisfies c<c(θ) , and assume further that both qualities are produced. Then the sellers’ indifference relation is equivalent to

(35)c=1eββeβ1eααeαv

There are two possibilities. First, some high-quality buyers contact low-quality sellers, or formally eβ=eαv . But then we know from the construction of the equilibrium Section 5.1.3 that c>cˉ(θ) which is greater than c(θ) and consequently not compatible with our assumption.

Secondly, there is perfect sorting, or eβ>eαv . It is straightforward to ascertain that the RHS of (35) is increasing in y, and the maximum y compatible with perfect sorting is given by β=αln12 . But this gives y=θ+ln12θ2+ln1222ln12 , and inserting this into (35) one recovers function cˉ(θ) which is always larger than c(θ) and consequently our assumption is not valid.

Finally, it is straightforward to see that if everyone produces a low-quality good there is a profitable deviation to produce a high-quality good.   □

Proof of sufficiency for Proposition 1: All sellers produce low quality

Proof.

Assume that the cost satisfies c>c˜(θ) , and that both qualities are produced. Again from the sellers’ indifference condition we get (35). If there is not perfect sorting then

(36)eβ=eαv

where α=(1+z)θ2y and β=(1z)θ2(1y) . To determine the largest possible value of c compatible with both qualities being produced we need to totally differentiate (36) to get

(37)zy=1z(1y)2+1+zy211y+1y

Then differentiating the RHS of (35) with respect to y one finds after some simplification that it is positive, or (βα)βeβ12αeα>0 , because (36) implies that β > α.

This reasoning shows that the greatest value of c is attained when y approaches unity. Then α = θ, and β=θln12 . Inserting these data into (35) one recovers c˜(θ) , and our assumption is not satisfied.

If there is perfect sorting or eβ>eαv then we reason that for a fixed α the RHS of (35) is increasing with β, and the largest β compatible with perfect sorting is given by β=αln12 . Inserting this into (35) we recover cˉ(θ) and as this is always less than c˜(θ) our assumption is not valid.

Finally, it is straightforward to see that if everyone produces a high-quality good there is a profitable deviation to produce a low-quality good.   □

Proof of sufficiency for Proposition 1: Both qualities produced

Proof.

It remains to show sufficiency only for the cases where both qualities are produced. But this is done in the proofs for low and high quality where necessity is proved for the equilibria where only one quality is produced.   □

Proof of sufficiency for Lemma 1

Proof.

To show that both qualities are not produced or only low quality is not produced one proceeds as in the above proof of proposition 2: Only low quality. To show that other possible equilibria do not satisfy the intuitive criterion assume that the equilibrium price p satisfies p>ph . If a seller deviates to price p , and the buyers believe him to be a high-quality seller the expected queue length γ is determined by

1eγγ(1p)=1eββ(1p)

From this we can determine γp=γ(1eγ)(1eγγeγ)(1p) . The derivative of the deviators profit function 1eγp with respect to p turns out negative at p=p if p>1eββeβ1eβ=ph . But this shows that there is a profitable deviation downwards. An analogous argument works if v<p<ph .   □

Proof of Lemma 2

Proof.

Necessity Let us first assume that the optimal deviation under perfect information p˜=1eγγeγ1eγ is greater than v; the queue length is determined by the buyers’ indifference condition 1eγγ(1p˜)=eθv . For this deviation to be non-profitable 1eγγeγc1eθθeθv or

(38)c121+eθln12=c˜(θ)

Assume next that the optimal deviation under perfect information is less than v. Then, v is the optimal deviation that cannot be imitated by low-quality sellers. It is not profitable if (1eγ)vc1eθθeθv where the expected queue length γ is determined by the buyers’ indifference condition 1eγγ(1v)=eθv ; we know that there exists a unique γ that satisfies the relation. Denote it by γ(θ), and note that γ(0) = 0, γθ=γ2θ1eγγeγ>0 , and γ(θ) > θ for all θ > 0.

Then we study for which values of γ it is true that 1eγγeγ1eγ<v . This is equivalent to 1eγ2γeγ<0 where the LHS is decreasing for γ<12 and increasing thereafter. It is immediate that there exists γˆ(1,2) such that 1eγˆ2γˆeγˆ=0 . Inverting γ(θ)=γˆ gives θˆ0.56 , and consequently for all θ<θˆ the restriction for the cost c is given by

(39)c12eγ(θ)+12eθ+12θeθ

Sufficiency For θθˆ the proof is like in the case of perfect information. Let us first assume that both qualities are produced, and that the high-quality sellers ask price ph=v . Then it must be the case that the sellers are indifferent or (1eααeα)v=(1eβ)vc . Now, if there is not perfect sorting α=(1+z)θ2y and β=(1z)θ2(1y) for z > 0. From the high-quality buyers’ indifference condition eαv=1eββ(1v) , which is equivalent to eα=1eββ , we immediately see that α < β.

Totally differentiating the indifference condition we find that zy=1+zy . Next we determine what happens to the difference of the sellers’ revenues (1eβ)v(1eααeα)v . Differentiating this with respect to y one finds that the derivative is given by θ2veβ1+zy(1y)+(1z)(1y)2αeα1+zyy(1+z)y2>0 where the first term in the curly brackets is positive because α < β, and the second term is zero.

Similarly, if there is perfect sorting α=θ2y and β=θ2(1y) and the corresponding derivative is given by 2θvαeα1y2+eβ1(1y)2>0 . As the one seller deviation to a higher price establishes the threshold cost cˆ(θ) , and this corresponds to y = 1 we see that decreasing y makes the difference between the revenues smaller. Consequently, the costs c that are consistent with both qualities being produced must satisfy c<cˆ(θ) . But this is a contradiction. Above we assumed that the high-quality price is ph=v but the same technique applies to any price ph>v .

From the proof of Claim 1 we know that an equilibrium where only high-quality goods are produced does not exist either.   □

Proof of Lemma 3

Proof.

It is clearest to establish the situation when c = 0 since increasing c just reduces the number of high-quality sellers. Consider the case θ=θ . The analysis preceding Proposition 1 shows that at this value every seller produces a high-quality good, and earns profit v. The price is given by ph=1eββeβ1eβ>v where β=θ2 . Lowering θ everything is as under perfect information until value θ1.68 [15], where the high-quality price equals v under perfect information.

When θ1.68 the equilibrium price of the high-quality good remains at v, and the measure of high-quality sellers adjusts so that the sellers’ indifference condition is satisfied. For these values of θ we next demonstrate that the sellers’ indifference condition determines a unique y, and that the prices, pl and ph=v , constitute an equilibrium. It is clear that the price of the low-quality good is pl=1eααeα1eαv , as the logic is the same as perfect information. The indifference condition of the sellers, for any c, is given by

(40)(1eβ)vc=1eααeαv

or

(41)eα(1+α)=eβ+2c

At y = 0 the LHS of (41) is zero, at y = 1 it is eθ2(1+θ2) , and its derivative with respect to y is easily seen to be positive. At y = 0 the RHS of (41) is eθ2+2c , and at y = 1 it is 2c, and its derivative with respect to y is easily seen to be negative. Consequently, when there exists a solution it is unique, and it gives the division between low-quality and high-quality sellers. Increasing c shifts the RHS upwards and it immediate that there is a solution for any ceθ2(1+θ2) .

Next we determine the part of the parameter space where there is perfect sorting. When the cost of production increases from zero the measure of sellers who produce a low-quality good grows. At some point high-quality buyers are indifferent between contacting the high-quality and low-quality sellers, or 1eββ(1v)=eαv which is equivalent to

(42)1eββeα=0

Note first that (42) determines a unique y. Consider function f4(y)1eββeα=0 . At zero it is positive, or f4(0)=1eθ2 , and at unity it is negative, or f4(1)=1 . To see that there is a unique zero observe that the derivative is given by f4(y)=θ211y11yeβ11yeα1yαeα . As eα=1eββ>eβ we see that at the zero of f4(y) the derivative is negative, and thus the solution is unique. Let us denote this by y(θ). It is clear that y(θ)>12 , as at value one half (42) becomes 1eθθeθ which is always positive.

We have established that there is a unique y(θ)>1/2 that makes the high-quality buyers’ indifference condition (42) hold. To determine the threshold-c we first note that the thresholds under perfect and private information start to differ at θθˇ0.78 which can be solved by equating y(θ) and (20). Then we solve the sellers’ indifference condition (40) for c, using the solution y(θ) (or alternatively eβ ) from (42).

It remains to show that price ph=v constitutes an equilibrium in the pricing subgame when θ0,θˇ . Any possible deviation is upwards. Consider p˜>v . The queue length γ the deviator expects is determined by the buyers’ indifference 1eγγ(1p˜)=1eββ(1v) . The deviation is not profitable if 1eβv1eγp˜ . Utilising the indifference condition this is equivalent to

(43)121eβ1+γβ1eγ

The LHS and RHS of (43) are equal when γ = β. The derivative with respect to γ of the LHS is smaller than that of the RHS if

1eβ2βeγ<0

but this holds for γ < β as we are in the part of the parameter space where 1eβ2βeβ<0 . This also shows that the equilibrium satisfies the intuitive criterion. Sufficiency follows from the proof of claims 1 and 2.    □

Proof of Proposition 3

Proof.

a) Perfect information

We restate the sellers’ indifference condition (17) and the high-quality buyers’ indifference condition (19),

(44)f8(z,y,c)=(1eααeα)v(1eββeβ)+c=0

and

(45)g1(z,y,c)=eβeαv=0,

where α=(1+z)θ2y and β=(1z)θ2(1y) . For notational simplicity we refer to f8(z,y,c) as f and to g1(z,y,c) as g in the reminder of part a) of the proof. The effect of an increase in c on on the sellers’ profit is given by.

Dc(1eααeα)12=12αeαdαdzdzdc+dαdydydc

By applying Cramer’s rule we get

dzdc=fcgy+fygcfzgyfygz=eβθ1z2(1y)2eα12θ1+z2y2B=eββ1y+eα12αyB

and

dydc=fzgc+fcgzfzgyfygz=eβθ2(1y)+eα12θ2yB=eββ1z+eα12α1+zB

where

B=αeα12θ2y+βeβθ2(1y)eβθ1z2(1y)2eα12θ1+z2y2
αeα12θ1+z2y2βeβθ1z2(1y)2eβθ2(1y)+eα12θ2y
=αeα12α1+z+βeββ(1z)eββ1y+eα12αy+αeα12αy+βeββ1yeββ1z+eα12α1+z
=αeα12α1+zeββ1yαeα12α1+zeα12αyβeββ(1z)eββ1yβeββ(1z)eα12αy
+αeα12αyeββ1z+αeα12αyeα12α1+z+βeββ1yeββ1z+βeββ1yeα12α1+z
=12αβeαeββα1+z1y+αβ1zy

Therefore

Dc(1eααeα)12=12αeαdαdzdzdc+dαdydydc
=12αeαθ2yeββ1y+eα12αyθ1+z2y2eββ1z+eα12α1+zB

The numerator of the term in the brackets simplifies to

θ2yeββ1y+eα12αyθ1+z2y2eββ1z+eαα1+z
=αeββ1y1+z+eα12α2y1+zαeββ1zyeα12α21+zy

and is of the same sign as

1zyeββ+1z1yeα12α1+z1yeββ1z1yeα12α
=1zy1+z1yeββ=2y1+zeββ

The high-quality buyers' indifference condition g(z,y,c)=0, implies that βα , which means that 2y1+z0. The sign of the denominator B is given by 1zy1+z1y=2y1+z and hence Dc(1eααeα)12 is positive.

b) Private information

The sellers’ indifference condition and the high-quality buyers’ indifference condition condition are now

(46)f9(z,y,c)=(1eααeα)(1eβ)+2c=0
(47)g2(z,y,c)=1eββeα=0,

where α=(1+z)θ2y and β=(1z)θ2(1y) . For simplicity we refer to f9(z,y,c) as f and to g2(z,y,c) as g in the reminder of the proof. The effect of an increase in c on the sellers’ profit given by.

Dc(1eααeα)12=12αeαdαdzdzdc+dαdydydc

The partial derivatives are

fz=αeαθ2y+eβθ2(1y)
fy=αeα1+zθ2y2eβ1zθ2(1y)2
fc=2
gz=eβθ2(1y)+eαθ21y+eαβθ2y
gy=+eβ1zθ2(1y)21Peα121zθ2(1y)2eαβ121+zθ2y2
gc=0

By Cramer’s rule we get

dzdc=Afcgy+fygcBfzgyfygz

and

dydc=Cfzgc+gzfcBfzgyfygz

Where

A=fcgy+fygc=2eαeβ1zθ2(1y)2+βeα1+zθ2y2=2eαeββ1y+βeααy,

which is positive as g(z, y, z) = 0 implies that βα which means that eαeβ is positive.

B=fzgyfygz=αeαθ2y+eβθ2(1y)eβeα1zθ2(1y)2βeα1+zθ2y2
+αeα1+zθ2y2+eβ1zθ2(1y)2eβeα1zθ2(1y)2βeα1+zθ2y2

Using the definitions of α and β , canceling terms that ad up to zero and simplifying we get

B=αβeα2y1+zα+βeβαeα1z(1+z)y1y

The denominator is positive. In addition βα implies that 2y1+z0and that α+β2α , which implies that α+βeβαeαeβ12eα , the right hand side of which we show (in the next proof) to be positive. Hence B is positive, and

C=fzgc+gzfc=2eαeββ1z+βeαα1+z

which is positive as βα . We can now express

Dc(1eααeα)12=12αeαdαdzdzdc+dαdydydc
=12αeαα1+z2eαeββ1y+βeααyαy2eαeββ1z+βeαα1+zB

The numerator is positive as 1zy1+z1y=2y1+z0 . As also the denominator or B is positive we have shown that Dc(1eααeα)12 is positive. Thus an increase in the cost leads to higher profits for the sellers.   □

Proof of Proposition 4

It remains to show that Dp(1eααeα)120 in the part of the parameter space where both the sellers’ indifference condition and the high-quality buyers’ indifference are condition are binding. Formally,

(48)f10(z,y,p)=(1eααeα)v(1eβ)p+c=0

and

(49)g3(z,y,p)=1eβ1pβeαv=0

where α=(1+z)θ2y and β=(1z)θ2(1y) . For simplicity we refer to f10(z,y,c) as f and to g3(z,y,c) as g in the reminder of the proof. As in the main text we analyse how an increase in p from the equilibrium price under perfect information, namely ph=1eββeβ1eβ to p=12 affects the profits of the sellers. We use a differential approach to show that the low-quality sellers profit is increasing in p for pph,12 . The derivative of the low-quality sellers’ profit function with respect to the price of the high-quality good is

Dp(1eααeα)12=12αeαdαdzdzdp+dαdydydp

We use Cramer’s rule on (48) and (49) to determine dzdp and dydp . The partial derivatives are

fz=12αeαθ2y+eβθ2(1y)p
fy=12αeα1+zθ2y2eβ1zθ2(1y)2p
fP=1+eβ
gz=eβθ2(1y)1p+eα12θ21y+eαβ12θ2y
gy=+eβ1zθ2(1y)21peα121zθ2(1y)2eαβ121+zθ2y2
gP=1+eβ

By Cramer’s rule we get

dzdp=AfPgy+fygPBfzgyfygz

and

dydp=CfzgP+gzfPBfzgyfygz

where

A=fPgy+fygP=1eβeβ1zθ2(1y)21peα121zθ2(1y)2eαβ121+zθ2y2
+1eβ12αeα1+zθ2y2+eβ1zθ2(1y)2p
=1eβeβ12eα1zθ2(1y)2+12eααβ1+zθ2y2
=1eβeβ12eαβ(1y)+12eααβαy
B=fzgyfygz=12αeαθ2y+eβθ2(1y)peβ1zθ2(1y)21peα121zθ2(1y)2eαβ121+zθ2y2
+12αeα1+zθ2y2+eβ1zθ2(1y)2peβθ2(1y)1p+eα12θ21y+eαβ12θ2y
=12αeαθ2yeβ1zθ2(1y)21p12αeαθ2yeα121zθ2(1y)212αeαθ2yeαβ121+zθ2y2
+eβθ2(1y)peβ1zθ2(1y)21peβθ2(1y)peα121zθ2(1y)2eβθ2(1y)peαβ121+zθ2y2
12αeα1+zθ2y2eβθ2(1y)1p+12αeα1+zθ2y2eα12θ21y+12αeα1+zθ2y2eαβ12θ2y
eβ1zθ2(1y)2peβθ2(1y)1p+eβ1zθ2(1y)2peα12θ21y+eβ1zθ2(1y)2peαβ12θ2y
=12αeαθ2yeβ1zθ2(1y)21p12αeαθ2yeα121zθ2(1y)2eβθ2(1y)peαβ121+zθ2y2
12αeα1+zθ2y2eβθ2(1y)1p+12αeα1+zθ2y2eα12θ21y+eβ1zθ2(1y)2peαβ12θ2y
=12αeαθy2y2eβ1zθ2(1y)21p12αeαθy2y2eα121zθ2(1y)2eβθ1y2(1y)2peαβ121+zθ2y2
12αeα1+zθ2y2eβθ1y2(1y)21p+12αeα1+zθ2y2eα12θ1y21y2+eβ1zθ2(1y)2peαβ12θy2y2.
=2y1+z12αeαeβθ21p2y1+z12αeαeαθ212+2y1+z12βeαeβθ2p4y21y2

The denominator is positive. The sign of B is determined by the numerator. We round down the numerator by changing one β to α in the last parentheses. We get

B=2y1+z12αeαθ2eβ12eα4y21y2+βα2y1+z12βeαeβθ2p4y21y2
C=fzgP+gzfP=1eβ12αeαθ2y+eβθ2(1y)p+eβθ21y1p12eαθ21y12βeαθ2y
=1eβeβθy21y+12eααθ(1y)2yθy21yβθ(1y)2y
=1eβeβ12eαθ2(1y)12eαβαθ2y.

The denominator of B is positive. The second term is positive as βα and hence 2y1+z>0 . The sign of the first term depends eβ12eα . It is zero when p=ph . We take the derivative ofeβ12eα with respect to p and show that it is non-negative at p=ph .

ddpeβ12eα=eβdβdzdzdp+dβdydydp+12eαdαdzdzdp+dαdydydp
=eβθ21yAB+1zθ21y2CB+12eαθ2yAB1+zθ2y2CB
=eββ1zABβ1yCB+12eαα1+zABαyCB
=eββ1z+12eαα1+zAeββ1y+12eααyCB

At p=ph , B is positive. The sign of the derivative is determined by the sign of the numerator. Substituting in A and C, and simplifying, we get

eββ1zαyβ1yα1+zαβ12eα1eβ
+12eαα1+zβ1yαyβ1zeβ12eα1eβ
=2y1+zβαeβ12eα1eβ1yy1+z1z+2y1+zeβ12eα12eα1eβ1yy1+z1z

The first term of the numerator is positive as 2y1+z0 and βα . The second term is zero as eβ12eα=0 at the lower bound of pph,12 . But at this point the first term is positive and therefore so is ddpeβ12eα . Because ddpeβ12eα is continuous and positive whenever eβ12eα=0 it follows that ddpeβ12eα0 for pph,12 and hence so is B.

We can now write the derivative of the profit for low-quality sellers with respect to p as

Dp(1eααeα)12=12αeαα1+zAαyCB

As B is positive the sign of Dp(1eααeα)12 is determined by the numerator which can be written as

12αeαα1+z1eβeβ12eαβ(1y)+12eααβαy
12αeααy1eβeβ12eαβ(1z)+12eααβα1+z
=12αeαα1+zβ(1y)1eβeβ12eα12αeααyβ(1z)1eβeβ12eα

Simple algebra tells us that its sign is given by 2y1+zeβ12eα . The term in the first parentheses is positive again as βα . The term in the second parentheses is zero when p=ph . To show that the derivative Dp(1eααeα)12 is non-negative for pph,12 it remains to differentiate eβ12eα and show that it is non-negative. But this we have already done and hence the profits of the sellers are at least as high when p=12 (private information) as when p=ph (perfect information).

References

Acemoglu, D., and R. Shimer. 1999. “Holdups and Efficiency with Search Frictions.” International Economic Review 40: 872–49.10.1111/1468-2354.00043Search in Google Scholar

Adriani, F., and L. G. Deidda. 2011. “Competition and the Signaling Role of Prices.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 29: 412–25.10.1016/j.ijindorg.2010.08.002Search in Google Scholar

Albrecht, J., P. Gautier, and S. Vroman. 2015. “Directed Search in the Housing Market.” Review of Economic Dynamics 19 (January 2016): 218–23.10.1016/j.red.2015.05.002Search in Google Scholar

Bagwell, K., and M. H. Riordan. 1991. “High and Declining Prices Signal Product Quality.” The American Economic Review 81: 224–39.Search in Google Scholar

Bester, H. 1998. “Quality Uncertainty Mitigates Product Differentiation.” Rand Journal of Economics 29: 828–844.10.2307/2556096Search in Google Scholar

Burdett, K., S. Shi, and R. Wright. 2001. “Pricing and Matching with Frictions.” Journal of Political Economy 109: 1060–85.10.1086/322835Search in Google Scholar

Delacroix, A., and S. Shi. 2013. “Pricing and Signaling with Frictions.” Journal of Economic Theory 148 (4): 1301–32.10.1016/j.jet.2013.04.006Search in Google Scholar

Eeckhout, J., and P. Kircher. 2010a. “Sorting and Decentralized Price Competition.” Econometrica 78 (2): 539–74.10.2139/ssrn.1139831Search in Google Scholar

Eeckhout, J., and P. Kircher. 2010b. “Sorting versus Screening: Search Frictions and Competing Mechanisms.” Journal of Economic Theory 145: 1354–1385.10.1016/j.jet.2010.01.005Search in Google Scholar

Geromichalos A. 2014. “Directed Search and the Bertrand Paradox.” International Economic Review 55 (4): 1043–65.10.1111/iere.12082Search in Google Scholar

Janssen, M., and S. Roy. 2010. “Signaling Quality Through Price in an Oligopoly.” Games and Economic Behavior 68 (2): 192–207.10.1016/j.geb.2009.06.001Search in Google Scholar

Julien, B., J. Kennes, and I. King. 2000. “Bidding for Labor.” Review of Economic Dynamics 3 (4): 619–49.10.1006/redy.1999.0089Search in Google Scholar

Lester, B. 2011. “Information and Prices with Capacity Constraints.” American Economic Review 101 (4): 1591–600.10.1257/aer.101.4.1591Search in Google Scholar

Milgrom, P., and J. Roberts. 1986. “Price and Advertising Signals of Product Quality.” Journal of Political Economy 94: 796–821.10.1086/261408Search in Google Scholar

Moen, E. 1997. “Competitive Search Equilibrium.” Journal of Political Economy 105: 385–411.10.1086/262077Search in Google Scholar

Montgomery, J. 1991. “Equilibrium Wage Dispersion and Interindustry Wage Differentials.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106: 163–79.10.2307/2937911Search in Google Scholar

Peters, M. 1991. “Ex Ante Price Offers in Matching Games Non-steady States.” Econometrica 59 (5): 1425–54.10.2307/2938374Search in Google Scholar

Peters, M. 2010. “Noncontractible Heterogeneity in Directed Search.” Econometrica 78: 1173–200.10.3982/ECTA8379Search in Google Scholar

Shi, S. 2001. “Frictional Assignment. 1. Efficiency.” Journal of Economic Theory 98 (2001): 232–60.10.1006/jeth.2000.2713Search in Google Scholar

Shi, S. 2002. “A Directed Search Model of Inequality with Heterogeneous Skills and Skill-Biased Technology.” Review of Economic Studies 69: 467–91.10.1111/1467-937X.00213Search in Google Scholar

Shieh, S. 1996. “Price and Money-Back Guarantees as Signals of Product Quality.” Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 5 (3): 361–77.10.1111/j.1430-9134.1996.00361.xSearch in Google Scholar

Shimer, R. 1996. “Essays in Search Theory.” PhD thesis, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Dept. of Economics.Search in Google Scholar

Shimer, R. 2005. “The Assignment of Workers to Jobs in an Economy with Coordination Frictions.” Journal of Political Economy 113 (5): 996–1025.10.3386/w8501Search in Google Scholar

Wolinsky, A. 1983. “Prices as Signals of Product Quality.” Review of Economic Studies 50 (4): 648–57.10.2307/2297767Search in Google Scholar

Wright, R., P. Kircher, B. Julien, and V. Guerrieri. 2017. “Directed Search -A Guided Tour.” NBER working paper 23884.10.3386/w23884Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2019-06-18

© 2019 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Articles in the same Issue

  1. Research Articles
  2. Optimal Forestry Contract with Interdependent Costs
  3. Bi and Branching Strict Nash Networks in Two-way Flow Models: A Generalized Sufficient Condition
  4. Pay-What-You-Want in Competition
  5. Two Rationales for Insufficient Entry
  6. Students’ Social Origins and Targeted Grading
  7. Pricing, Signalling, and Sorting with Frictions
  8. On the Economic Value of Signals
  9. The Core in Bertrand Oligopoly TU-Games with Transferable Technologies
  10. Reasoning About ‘When’ Instead of ‘What’: Collusive Equilibria with Stochastic Timing in Repeated Oligopoly
  11. Timing Games with Irrational Types: Leverage-Driven Bubbles and Crash-Contingent Claims
  12. Costly Rewards and Punishments
  13. Blocking Coalitions and Fairness in Asset Markets and Asymmetric Information Economies
  14. Strategic Activism in an Uncertain World
  15. On Equilibrium Existence in a Finite-Agent, Multi-Asset Noisy Rational Expectations Economy
  16. Optimal Incentives Under Gift Exchange
  17. Public Good Indices for Games with Several Levels of Approval
  18. Vagueness of Language: Indeterminacy under Two-Dimensional State-Uncertainty
  19. Winners and Losers of Universal Health Insurance: A Macroeconomic Analysis
  20. Behavioral Theory of Repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma: Generous Tit-For-Tat Strategy
  21. Flourishing as Productive Tension: Theory and Model
  22. Notes
  23. A Note on Reference-Dependent Choice with Threshold Representation
  24. Regular Equilibria and Negative Welfare Implications in Delegation Games
  25. Unbundling Production with Decreasing Average Costs
  26. A Simple and Procedurally Fair Game Form for Nash Implementation of the No-Envy Solution
  27. Decision Making and Games with Vector Outcomes
  28. Capital Concentration and Wage Inequality
  29. Annuity Markets and Capital Accumulation
Downloaded on 22.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2018-0108/html
Scroll to top button