Abstract
This paper studies the supply-side distortions and the consequences resulted from provider-side cost containing universal health insurance (UHI) scheme. A two-sector overlapping generations model of endogenous physicians’ specialty choice is presented. We find that the general public is possible to be benefited from the cost containing UHI if the quality of medical services does not deteriorate too much. However, physicians in the medical service sector suffer from such scheme and end up earning lower incomes, regardless of one’s specialty and talent. Inequality among physicians also increases.
Acknowledgements
We would like to thank Been-Lon Chen, Hung-Ju Chen, Julen Esteban-Pretel, Minchung Hsu, Hans van Kippersluis, Yiting Li, Pei-Ju Liao, Alistair Mounro, Svetlana Pashchenko, Ponpoje Porapakkarm, Zheng Michael Song, Ping Wang and the participants of the 2016 Taipei International Conference on Growth, Trade and Dynamics, the CUHK macro/trade lunch meeting, the first Taiwan-Hong Kong Political Economy Conference, the seminar at the GRIPS and the National University of Taiwan and the brownbag seminar at the IEAS for their valuable comments and suggestions. Research support from Direct Grant for Research 2016–2017 by Social Science Panel at the Chinese University of Hong Kong is highly appreciated. All errors are ours.
Appendix
A Mathematical Appendix
This appendix provides proofs for the propositions and lemmas in the paper.
Lemma 1
There exists a unique solution for a* if
Proof
Rearranging eq. (10) and substitute it into eq. (13), we have
As illustrated in Figure 5 below, from the above equation, we can see that the LHS is increasing in a* with
We can see that the same result holds when λH = 0 or s = 0.

The determination of the threshold talent a*. □
Lemma 2
The threshold talent a* under any competitive equilibrium, if exists, always satisfies the inequality
Proof
The maximum output allocation, am, is given by the solution to the following maximization problem.
Solving this maximization problem gives us
From Lemma 1, we know that a* is decreasing in p and converging to a constant ac. Hence, we only need to show that
Proposition 1
All workers in the goods market at t = T are better off compared to t < T if and only if
Proof
Since agents in the goods sector value only consumption, they will be better off if and only if they could consume more. More formally, agents in the goods sector will be better off at t = T if and only if
□
Proposition
For any talent a, physicians at t = T are worse off compared to physicians at t < T with the same talent if and only if
Proof
For the medical service sector, it is clear that physicians’ welfare differs purely by wages. From the wages eqs. (11) and (12), wages increase if pH/q and pL/q increase. From eq. (10), as a* keeps constant, the relative price
B UHI in Other Countries
In Section 2, we have discussed the UHI systems in Japan and Taiwan, which are categorized as provider-side cost control systems. Different from Japan and Taiwan, the UHI systems in European countries adopt more consumer-side cost suppressing measures. Consumer-side cost control systems usually have stricter referral systems and regulate the access of certain medical services, aiming at limiting the usage of medical services and maintaining the quality of health services in the meanwhile. Therefore, despite that consumer prices under the UHI are still kept low, it is more difficult for “consumers” to abuse the system. In this appendix, we briefly discuss the UHI systems in Italy and France. We also show that the allocations of physicians in these two countries are less distorted during the past 20 years compared to those in Japan and Taiwan. For a more detailed discussion on international health care systems, please refer to Mossialos et al. (2016).
Italy
The National Health Service in Italy (Servizio Sanitario Nazionale) is regionally based, with the responsibility for health care shared by the central government, the regional governments and the autonomous provinces. The central government distributes tax revenue to every region, while the local governments have high levels of autonomy in determining the local health system and are responsible for the delivery of health services. Coverage is automatic and universal for all citizens and legal foreign residents. While visits for general practitioners and hospital stays are free, patients have to pay a copayment up to a ceiling for procedures and specialist visits.
Although Italy does not have a separate balance for its NHS, the rising public debt has forced the Italian government to take measures to control its health expenditures. For example, in July 2011, the government introduced an additional copayment of 10 euros for each prescription. In addition, the Italian government has adopted several cost control measures and lots of them are aimed at limiting the access of certain medical services. These include reducing the number of hospital beds, revising hospital and diagnostic fees, promoting generic drugs, and etc. Furthermore, the prices of reimbursable drugs are negotiated between the government and the manufacturers, and only the prices of non-reimbursable drugs are set by the market.
As suggested by Traina (2009), Italy has the highest number of physicians subject to malpractice-related criminal proceedings among European countries. Between 1996 and 2000, for cases filed related to medical malpractice, orthopaedics and traumatology were accountable for the highest number, followed by obstetrics/gynecology. Table 5 shows the changes in these specialties from 2009 to 2013. In a less than 5-year span, we observe that the two specialties suffering from the highest risks of malpractice – orthopaedics and obstetrics/gynecology – have both experienced a decline in popularity. On the contrary, specialties such as plastic surgery have experienced increasing popularity during the same period. As we can see, the recent trend of physician supply in Italy and the trends in other countries warrant some worries. However, the changes in physician distribution are mild as the Italian government are suppressing costs not only from the provider side, but also from the consumer side.
Distributions of physicians in percentage in Italy, 2009–2013.
Year | Orthopaedics | Obstetrics and gynecology | Plastic surgery |
---|---|---|---|
2009 | 4.10 | 5.58 | 0.37 |
2013 | 3.93 | 5.04 | 0.97 |
Change in Distribution | –0.17 | –0.54 | 0.61 |
Note: The data is obtained from Eurostat. Data on numbers of physicians by detailed medical specialty is not available prior to year 2009.
France
The French universal health care system, running under the statutory health insurance (SHI), provides universal and compulsory coverage to all residents. SHI is mainly financed by payroll taxes, and the public health expenditure amounts to 76–77 % of total health expenditure in recent years. The healthcare costs are shared by coinsurance and copayment. Different from the case of Japan, the coinsurance rates vary across different types of care and drugs.
SHI has been in large deficits over the past 20 years, but the deficits of SHI have been fallen in recent years. This reversing trend in deficits can be attributed to a series of initiatives on tax and regulation in 2000s. Similar to the Italian case, most of the cost-containing measures are on the consumer side. Major measures include reducing the number of acute-care hospital beds, removing many drugs from public reimbursement, promoting generic prescription and over-the-counter drugs, reducing test redundancy and official fees for self-employed radiologists biology labs. It is noteworthy that unlike Taiwan and Japan, global budgets are used only on the purchase of drugs and devices. We report in Table 6 the changes in physician distribution for some selected specialties during 2005–2014, and obviously that the changes in physician distribution are not as dramatic as those in Taiwan and Japan. Consistent with our theory, the cost suppression and regulations on the consumer side of health care do not seriously distort the physician distribution and talent allocation in France.
Distributions of physicians in percentage in France, 2005–2014.
Medical specialty | 2005 | 2014 | 2005–2014 | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Generalist medical practitioners | 49.29 | 46.38 | –2.92 | ||
Specialist medical practitioners | 50.71 | 53.62 | 2.92 | ||
General paediatricians | 3.30 | 3.56 | 0.26 | ||
Psychiatrists | 6.57 | 6.81 | 0.24 | ||
Medical group of specialists | 23.36 | 24.81 | 1.45 | ||
Internal medicine | 1.19 | 1.84 | 0.65 | ||
Cardiology | 2.93 | 3.12 | 0.19 | ||
Neurology | 0.88 | 1.08 | 0.20 | ||
Radiology | 4.29 | 4.57 | 0.28 | ||
Occupational medicine | 3.09 | 3.30 | 0.22 | ||
Surgical group of specialists | 12.94 | 13.83 | 0.89 | ||
General surgery | 2.45 | 2.21 | –0.24 | ||
Plastic surgery | 0.24 | 0.39 | 0.15 | ||
Orthopaedics | 1.10 | 1.43 | 0.33 | ||
Urology | 0.93 | 1.26 | 0.33 |
Note: The data is obtained from Eurostat. Data on numbers of physicians by detailed medical specialty is not available prior to year 2005.
C Government Intervention with Positive Price Wedge
Consider a model similar to the one in Section 5 with the government now intervening the market by subsidizing medical services with a lump sum tax. Let s be the price wedge between the consumer and the provider. We have
where ps and pd are the prices received by hospitals and paid by consumers respectively. The demand of health care is similar to eq. (5).
Consider the case where the government implements UHI without affecting the equilibrium price that the hospital receives. Hence, the hospital is still receiving the price

Temporal equilibrium when the government subsidizes medical services.
Now we turn our focus to the permanent equilibrium. From eq. (13), we can observe that a decrease in q with p fixed has the same effect as that of a price increase. Hence, more physicians will switch to the high-risk specialty, and an excess supply is created (see the left panel of Figure 7). The intuition is that without global budget, government subsidies actually make physicians wealthier. Hence, some physicians would switch to the high-risk specialty. Comparing with the temporal equilibrium, the quality actually could increase. The permanent equilibrium is shown in the right panel of Figure 7.

Permanent equilibrium when the government subsidizes the final medical services.
Now consider the case where the government decides to adopt a global budget with a spending limit B. That is, the total subsidy (the price gap multiplied by the final quantity of medical services) to health expenditures shall not exceed B. Suppose that the targeted spending B is smaller than what the government is subsidizing under the price subsidy s. As the government wants to keep the consumers’ out-of-pocket price, pd, constant, the government needs to negotiate a new price subsidy s′ < s with the medical sector.
Let ps′ be the new price that the hospital receives from providing healthcare services, and
References
Aizawa, N., and H. Fang. 2013. “Equilibrium Labor Market Search and Health Insurance Reform.” NBER Working Paper No.18698. National Bureau of Economic Research, January 2013.10.3386/w18698Search in Google Scholar
Arcidiacono, P., and S. Nicholson. 2005. “Peer Effects in Medical School.” Journal of Public Economics 89 (2–3): 327–50.10.3386/w9025Search in Google Scholar
Bhattacharya, J. 2005. “Specialty Selection and Lifetime Returns to Specialization Within Medicine.” Journal of Human Resources 40 (1): 115–43.10.3368/jhr.XL.1.115Search in Google Scholar
Cheng, S.-H., and T.-L. Chiang. 1997. “The Effect of Universal Health Insurance on Health Care Utilization in Taiwan: Results from a Natural Experiment.” JAMA 278 (2): 89–93.10.1001/jama.278.2.89Search in Google Scholar
Chou, S.-Y., J.-T. Liu, and J. K. Hammitt. 2003. “National Health Insurance and Precautionary Saving: Evidence from Taiwan.” Journal of Public Economics 87 (9–10): 1873–94.10.1016/S0047-2727(01)00205-5Search in Google Scholar
Cutler, D. M., and J. Gruber. 1996. “Does Public Insurance Crowd out Private Insurance?” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 111 (2): 391–430.10.3386/w5082Search in Google Scholar
Fang, H., and A. Gavazza. 2011. “Dynamic Inefficiencies in an Employment-Based Health Insurance System: Theory and Evidence.” The American Economic Review 101 (7): 3047–77.10.3386/w13371Search in Google Scholar
Fender, J., and P. Wang. 2003. “Educational Policy in a Credit Constrained Economy with Skill Heterogeneity.” International Economic Review 44 (3): 939–64.10.1111/1468-2354.t01-1-00095Search in Google Scholar
Frankovic, I., and M. Kuhn. 2018. “Health Insurance, Endogenous Medical Progress, and Health Expenditure Growth.” ECON WPS - Vienna University of Technology Working Papers in Economic Theory and Policy, No. 01/2018, Vienna University of Technology, Research Group Economics (ECON), Vienna.10.1016/j.jhealeco.2022.102717Search in Google Scholar
Hansen, G. D., M. Hsu, and J. Lee. 2014. “Health Insurance Reform: The Impact of a Medicare Buy-In.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 45: 315–29.10.3386/w18529Search in Google Scholar
Hsu, M. 2013. “Health Insurance and Precautionary Saving: A Structural Analysis.” Review of Economic Dynamics 16 (3): 511–26.10.1016/j.red.2012.09.001Search in Google Scholar
Hsu, M., and P.-J. Liao. 2015. “Financing National Health Insurance: The Challenge of Fast Population Aging.” Taiwan Economic Review 43 (2): 145–82.10.1016/j.socscimed.2015.09.036Search in Google Scholar
Kondo, A., and H. Shigeoka. 2013. “Effects of Universal Health Insurance on Health Care Utilization, and Supply-Side Responses: Evidence from Japan.” Journal of Public Economics 99: 1–23.10.1016/j.jpubeco.2012.12.004Search in Google Scholar
Liu, P.-Y. 2011. “An Empirical Study of Medical Malpractice Judgments from District Criminal Courts in Taiwan: 2000–2010.” Technology Law Review 8 (2): 257–94.Search in Google Scholar
McGuire, T. G., and M. V. Pauly. 1991. “Physician Response to Fee Changes with Multiple Payers.” Journal of Health Economics 10 (4): 385–410.10.1016/0167-6296(91)90022-FSearch in Google Scholar
Mino, K., K. Shimomura, and P. Wang. 2005. “Occupational Choice and Dynamic Indeterminacy.” Review of Economic Dynamics 8 (1): 138–53.10.1016/j.red.2004.10.001Search in Google Scholar
Mossialos, E., M. Wenzl, R. Osborn, and D. Sarnak, eds. January, 2016. “International Profiles of Health Care Systems, 2015.” The Commonwealth Fund.10.15868/socialsector.25100Search in Google Scholar
Nicholson, S. 2002. “Physician Specialty Choice under Uncertainty.” Journal of Labor Economics 20(4): 816–47.10.1086/342039Search in Google Scholar
Nicholson, S., and C. Propper. 2011. “Medical Workforce.” In Handbook of Health Economics, vol. 2, edited by M. V. Pauly, T. G. Mcguire, and P. P. Barros, 873–925. Amsterdam, Netherlands: Elsevier.10.1016/B978-0-444-53592-4.00014-1Search in Google Scholar
Pashchenko, S., and P. Porapakkarm. 2013. “Quantitative Analysis of Health Insurance Reform: Separating Regulation from Redistribution.” Review of Economic Dynamics 16 (3): 383–404.10.1016/j.red.2012.09.002Search in Google Scholar
Ramseyer, J. M. 2009. “The Effect of Cost Suppression under Universal Health Insurance on the Allocation of Talent and the Development of Expertise: Cosmetic Surgery in Japan.” The Journal of Law & Economics 52 (3): 497–522.10.1086/592005Search in Google Scholar
Ramseyer, J. M. 2010. “The Effect of Universal Health Insurance on Malpractice Claims: The Japanese Experience.” Journal of Legal Analysis 2 (2): 621–86.10.1093/jla/2.2.621Search in Google Scholar
Sloan, F. A. 1970. “Lifetime Earnings and Physicians’ Choice of Specialty.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 24 (1): 47–56.10.1177/001979397002400104Search in Google Scholar
Traina, F. 2009. “Medical Malpractice: The Experience in Italy.” Clinical Orthopaedics and Related Research 467 (2): 434–42.10.1007/s11999-008-0582-zSearch in Google Scholar
Wu, C.-Y., H.-J. Lai, and R.-C. Chen. 2009. “Medical Malpractice Experience of Taiwan: 2005 versus 1991.” Internal Medicine Journal 39 (4): 237–42.10.1111/j.1445-5994.2009.01801.xSearch in Google Scholar
Zhao, K. 2015. “The Impact of the Correlation between Health Expenditure and Survival Probability on the Demand for Insurance.” European Economic Review 75: 98–111.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2015.01.003Search in Google Scholar
© 2019 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston
Articles in the same Issue
- Research Articles
- Optimal Forestry Contract with Interdependent Costs
- Bi and Branching Strict Nash Networks in Two-way Flow Models: A Generalized Sufficient Condition
- Pay-What-You-Want in Competition
- Two Rationales for Insufficient Entry
- Students’ Social Origins and Targeted Grading
- Pricing, Signalling, and Sorting with Frictions
- On the Economic Value of Signals
- The Core in Bertrand Oligopoly TU-Games with Transferable Technologies
- Reasoning About ‘When’ Instead of ‘What’: Collusive Equilibria with Stochastic Timing in Repeated Oligopoly
- Timing Games with Irrational Types: Leverage-Driven Bubbles and Crash-Contingent Claims
- Costly Rewards and Punishments
- Blocking Coalitions and Fairness in Asset Markets and Asymmetric Information Economies
- Strategic Activism in an Uncertain World
- On Equilibrium Existence in a Finite-Agent, Multi-Asset Noisy Rational Expectations Economy
- Optimal Incentives Under Gift Exchange
- Public Good Indices for Games with Several Levels of Approval
- Vagueness of Language: Indeterminacy under Two-Dimensional State-Uncertainty
- Winners and Losers of Universal Health Insurance: A Macroeconomic Analysis
- Behavioral Theory of Repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma: Generous Tit-For-Tat Strategy
- Flourishing as Productive Tension: Theory and Model
- Notes
- A Note on Reference-Dependent Choice with Threshold Representation
- Regular Equilibria and Negative Welfare Implications in Delegation Games
- Unbundling Production with Decreasing Average Costs
- A Simple and Procedurally Fair Game Form for Nash Implementation of the No-Envy Solution
- Decision Making and Games with Vector Outcomes
- Capital Concentration and Wage Inequality
- Annuity Markets and Capital Accumulation
Articles in the same Issue
- Research Articles
- Optimal Forestry Contract with Interdependent Costs
- Bi and Branching Strict Nash Networks in Two-way Flow Models: A Generalized Sufficient Condition
- Pay-What-You-Want in Competition
- Two Rationales for Insufficient Entry
- Students’ Social Origins and Targeted Grading
- Pricing, Signalling, and Sorting with Frictions
- On the Economic Value of Signals
- The Core in Bertrand Oligopoly TU-Games with Transferable Technologies
- Reasoning About ‘When’ Instead of ‘What’: Collusive Equilibria with Stochastic Timing in Repeated Oligopoly
- Timing Games with Irrational Types: Leverage-Driven Bubbles and Crash-Contingent Claims
- Costly Rewards and Punishments
- Blocking Coalitions and Fairness in Asset Markets and Asymmetric Information Economies
- Strategic Activism in an Uncertain World
- On Equilibrium Existence in a Finite-Agent, Multi-Asset Noisy Rational Expectations Economy
- Optimal Incentives Under Gift Exchange
- Public Good Indices for Games with Several Levels of Approval
- Vagueness of Language: Indeterminacy under Two-Dimensional State-Uncertainty
- Winners and Losers of Universal Health Insurance: A Macroeconomic Analysis
- Behavioral Theory of Repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma: Generous Tit-For-Tat Strategy
- Flourishing as Productive Tension: Theory and Model
- Notes
- A Note on Reference-Dependent Choice with Threshold Representation
- Regular Equilibria and Negative Welfare Implications in Delegation Games
- Unbundling Production with Decreasing Average Costs
- A Simple and Procedurally Fair Game Form for Nash Implementation of the No-Envy Solution
- Decision Making and Games with Vector Outcomes
- Capital Concentration and Wage Inequality
- Annuity Markets and Capital Accumulation