Abstract
The optimality of the long-run capital-income tax rate is revisited in a simple neoclassical growth model with credit frictions. Firms pay their factors of production in advance, which requires borrowing at the beginning of the period. Borrowing, in turn, is constrained by the value of collateral that they own at the beginning of the period, leading to inefficiently low amounts of capital and labor. In this environment, the optimal capital-income tax in the steady state is non zero. Specifically, the quantitative analyses show that the capital-income tax is negative and, therefore, the distortions stemming from the credit friction are offset by subsidizing capital. However, when the government cannot distinguish between capital-income and profits, the capital-income tax is positive as the government levies the same tax rate on both sources of income. These results stand in contrast to the celebrated result of zero capital-income taxation of Judd (Judd, K. 1985. “Redistributive Taxation in a Simple Perfect Foresight Model.” Journal of Public Economics 28: 59–83.) and Chamley (Chamley, C. 1986. “Optimal Taxation of Capital Income in General Equilibrium with Infinite Lives.” Econometrica 54: 607–622.).
Acknowledgments
I am grateful to the editor and to an anonymous referee for very helpful comments and suggestions.
Appendix
A. The firm’s problem
At the beginning of period t, the firm obtains a loan

subject to:

and:

Letting υt and γt be the Lagrange multipliers on the constraints (A.2) and (A.3), respectively, the optimality condition with respect to

Similarly, the first order conditions with respect to lt and kt yield:


Recalling that

and, therefore, the two Lagrange multipliers are equal. By renaming the Lagrange multiplier as μt, we get conditions (11)–(12) in the text.
Alternatively, conditions (A.2) and (A.3) can be combined to get:

which is condition (10) in the text.
Substituting

which is condition (9) in the text. Therefore, the optimization problem of the firm is to maximize (A.9) subject to (A.8). Letting μt be the Lagrange multiplier on (A.8), the choices of labor and capital yield conditions (11) and (12) in the text.
B. Efficient allocations
The problem of the social planner is to maximize:

subject to the sequence of resource constraints:

and the market clearing condition of real estate:

Letting ηt be the Lagrange multiplier associated with condition (B.2), the first-order conditions with respect to ct and kt+1, respectively, read:


Combining these two conditions gives condition (17) in the text.
C. The present-value implementability constraint
I show here the derivation of the PVIC for the Ramsey problem. Recalling that

By introducing

Recall that, from the solution to the households’ problem, we have:




Substituting (C.3) in the first term of (C.2), (C.4) in the eighth term of (C.2), (C.5) in the seventh term of (C.2) and (C.6) in the last term of (C.2) yield:

Combining the second and seventh terms of (C.7) yields:

Combining the fifth and eighth terms of (C.7) gives:

Combining the fourth and last terms of (C.7) yields:

Also, the first term of (C.7) can be written as:

Finally, substituting (C.8)–(C.11) into (C.7) and re-arranging give the PVIC (condition (18) in the text):

with
References
Abo-Zaid, S. 2013. Optimal Labor-Income Tax Volatility with Credit Frictions. Mimeo: Texas Tech University.10.2139/ssrn.2051143Suche in Google Scholar
Aiyagari, S. R. 1995. “Optimal Capital Income Taxation with Incomplete Markets, Borrowing Constraints, and Constant Discounting.” Journal of Political Economy 103: 1158–1175.10.1086/601445Suche in Google Scholar
Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and V. Maksimovic. 2005. “Financial and Legal Constraints to Growth: Does Firm Size Matter?” Journal of Finance 60: 137–177.10.1111/j.1540-6261.2005.00727.xSuche in Google Scholar
Campello, M., J. R. Graham, and C. R. Harvey. 2010. “The Real Effects of Financial Constraints: Evidence from a Financial Crisis.” Journal of Financial Economics 97: 470–487.10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.02.009Suche in Google Scholar
Carlstrom, C. T., and T. S. Fuerst. 1998. “Agency Costs and Business Cycles.” Economic Theory 12: 583–597.10.1007/s001990050236Suche in Google Scholar
Carlstrom, C. T., T. S. Fuerst, and M. Paustian. 2010. “Optimal Monetary Policy in a Model with Agency Costs.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 42: 37–70.10.1111/j.1538-4616.2010.00329.xSuche in Google Scholar
Chamley, C. 1986. “Optimal Taxation of Capital Income in General Equilibrium with Infinite Lives.” Econometrica 54: 607–622.10.2307/1911310Suche in Google Scholar
Chaney, T., D. Sraer, and D. Thesmar. 2012. “The Collateral Channel: How Real Estate Shocks Affect Corporate Investment.” American Economic Review 102: 2381–2409.10.1257/aer.102.6.2381Suche in Google Scholar
Chari, V. V., and P. Kehoe. 1999. “Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy.” In: (J. B. Taylor and M. Woodford, eds.) Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier, pp. 1671–1745.Suche in Google Scholar
Chugh, S. K., and D. M. Arseneau. 2012. “Tax Smoothing in Frictional Labor Markets.” Journal of Political Economy 120: 926–985.10.1086/668837Suche in Google Scholar
Conesa, J. C., S. Kitao, and D. Krueger. 2009. “Taxing Capital? Not a Bad Idea After All!” American Economic Review 99: 25–48.10.1257/aer.99.1.25Suche in Google Scholar
Cooley, T. F., and E. C. Prescott. 1995. “Economic Growth and Business Cycles.” In: (T. F. Cooley, ed.) Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, pp. 1–38.Suche in Google Scholar
Diaz, A., and M. J. Luengo-Prado. 2010. “The Wealth Distribution with Durable Goods.” International Economic Review 51: 143–170.10.1111/j.1468-2354.2009.00574.xSuche in Google Scholar
Erosa, A., and M. Gervais. 2002. “Optimal Taxation in Life-Cycle Economies.” Journal of Economic Theory 105: 338–369.10.1006/jeth.2001.2877Suche in Google Scholar
Guo, J. T., and K. Lansing. 1999. “Optimal Taxation of Capital Income with Imperfectly Competitive Product Markets.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 23: 967–995.10.1016/S0165-1889(98)00047-5Suche in Google Scholar
Harding, J. P., S. S. Rosenthal, and C. F. Sirmans. 2007. “Depreciation of Housing Capital, Maintenance, and House Price Inflation: Estimates From a Repeat Sales Model.” Journal of Urban Economics 61: 193–217.10.1016/j.jue.2006.07.007Suche in Google Scholar
Iacoviello, M. 2005. “House Prices, Borrowing Constraints and Monetary Policy in The Business Cycle.” American Economic Review 95: 739–764.10.1257/0002828054201477Suche in Google Scholar
Judd, K. 1985. “Redistributive Taxation in a Simple Perfect Foresight Model.” Journal of Public Economics 28: 59–83.10.1016/0047-2727(85)90020-9Suche in Google Scholar
Judd, K. 1997. “The Optimal Tax Rate for Capital Income is Negative.” NBER Working Paper No. 6004.10.3386/w6004Suche in Google Scholar
Judd, K. 2002. “Capital Income Taxation with Imperfect Competition.” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 92: 417–421.10.1257/000282802320191723Suche in Google Scholar
Kim, J., and F. J. Ruge-Murcia. 2009. “How Much Inflation is Necessary to Grease the Wheels?” Journal of Monetary Economics 56: 365–377.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2009.03.004Suche in Google Scholar
Kiyotaki, N., and J. Moore. 1997. “Credit Cycles.” Journal of Political Economy 105: 211–248.10.1086/262072Suche in Google Scholar
Lucas, R. E., and N. L. Stokey. 1983. “Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy in An Economy without Capital.” Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 55–93.10.1016/0304-3932(83)90049-1Suche in Google Scholar
NFIB. 2012. Small Business, Credit Access and a Lingering Recession. National Federation of Independent Business. Available at: http://www.nfib.com/Portals/0/PDF/AllUsers/research/studies/small-business-credit-study-nfib-2012.pdf.Suche in Google Scholar
Schmitt-Grohe, S., and M. Uribe. 2004. “Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy Under Sticky Prices.” Journal of Economic Theory 114: 198–230.10.1016/S0022-0531(03)00111-XSuche in Google Scholar
©2014 by De Gruyter
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Frontmatter
- Advances
- Optimal portfolios with wealth-varying risk aversion in the neoclassical growth model
- Inventories and the stockout constraint in general equilibrium
- Optimal second best taxation of addictive goods in dynamic general equilibrium: a revenue raising perspective
- Inflation effects on capital accumulation in a model with residential and non-residential assets
- Optimal capital-income taxation in a model with credit frictions
- Contributions
- Interest rate fluctuations and equilibrium in the housing market
- News shocks and learning-by-doing
- Capacity utilization and the effects of energy price increases in Japan
- Small-scale New Keynesian model features that can reproduce lead, lag and persistence patterns
- Optimal policy and Taylor rule cross-checking under parameter uncertainty
- The impact of American and British involvement in Afghanistan and Iraq on health spending, military spending and economic growth
- Why does natural resource abundance not always lead to better outcomes? Limited financial development versus political impatience
- The skill bias of technological change and the evolution of the skill premium in the US since 1970
- Aggregate impacts of recent US natural gas trends
- Organizational learning and optimal fiscal and monetary policy
- Industrial specialization, financial integration and international consumption risk sharing
- Leverage, investment, and optimal monetary policy
- Public debt in an OLG model with imperfect competition: long-run effects of austerity programs and changes in the growth rate
- Temporal aggregation and estimated monetary policy rules
- International transmission of productivity shocks with nonzero net foreign debt
- Did the euro change the effect of fundamentals on growth and uncertainty?
- Topics
- Real factor prices and factor-augmenting technical change
- Monetary policy and TIPS yields before the crisis
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Frontmatter
- Advances
- Optimal portfolios with wealth-varying risk aversion in the neoclassical growth model
- Inventories and the stockout constraint in general equilibrium
- Optimal second best taxation of addictive goods in dynamic general equilibrium: a revenue raising perspective
- Inflation effects on capital accumulation in a model with residential and non-residential assets
- Optimal capital-income taxation in a model with credit frictions
- Contributions
- Interest rate fluctuations and equilibrium in the housing market
- News shocks and learning-by-doing
- Capacity utilization and the effects of energy price increases in Japan
- Small-scale New Keynesian model features that can reproduce lead, lag and persistence patterns
- Optimal policy and Taylor rule cross-checking under parameter uncertainty
- The impact of American and British involvement in Afghanistan and Iraq on health spending, military spending and economic growth
- Why does natural resource abundance not always lead to better outcomes? Limited financial development versus political impatience
- The skill bias of technological change and the evolution of the skill premium in the US since 1970
- Aggregate impacts of recent US natural gas trends
- Organizational learning and optimal fiscal and monetary policy
- Industrial specialization, financial integration and international consumption risk sharing
- Leverage, investment, and optimal monetary policy
- Public debt in an OLG model with imperfect competition: long-run effects of austerity programs and changes in the growth rate
- Temporal aggregation and estimated monetary policy rules
- International transmission of productivity shocks with nonzero net foreign debt
- Did the euro change the effect of fundamentals on growth and uncertainty?
- Topics
- Real factor prices and factor-augmenting technical change
- Monetary policy and TIPS yields before the crisis