Abstract
Using a two-sector model with potentially different capital shares in each sector, I show that the evolution of the skill premium from 1970 to 2005 is consistent with skill-neutrality and even a mild unskill-bias of technological change. The main channel of adjustment to changes in labor supply is instead via the reallocation of capital. New investment occurs predominantly in the skilled sector, to the detriment of the unskilled sector of the economy. This result is shown both theoretically in a simple model and in a quantitative exercise using data on the US economy.
Acknowledgments
I would like to thank Rachel Ngai, Ethan Ilzetzki, Zsofia Barany and Ashwini Natraj for helpful discussions and Francesco Caselli for valuable advice and constant support. I would also like to thank the editor and another referee for valuable comments. All remaining errors are of course my own. Finally, I am grateful for financial support from the ESRC and a LSE research studentship.
Appendix
Notes on the algorithm
As there is very little previous numerical work involving irreversibility constraints [one notable exception being Coleman (1997)], the algorithm is developed from scratch. There are two parts to it: a value function iteration for given production efficiencies and an update mechanism for the guess of the production efficiencies.
Value function iteration with irreversibility constraint, given production efficiencies
At its core is a finite horizon value function iteration that incorporates an irreversibility constraint. I am interested in a period of T=35 years, corresponding to the period from 1970 to 2005. The terminal value is the steady state value towards which the economy converges, given that all values grow at their BGP rates from the final period of interest onwards. Between the last period of interest and the terminal value are m periods at which the production efficiencies grow at their BGP rates and relative labor supply stays constant. m is chosen large enough so that the choice of terminal value does not affect the results in the period of interest, a method known as tatonnement. An assumption implicit in this method is that the model converges to a steady state [see Judd (1998)], hence it is important to ascertain theoretically that a steady state indeed exists and that the model converges to it, to be able to trust the results. My model converges to a balanced growth path with both production efficiency growth rates uniquely determined by the overall growth rate of the economy, and the capital shares β and γ.
Each value function iteration takes as given the (T+m×2)-matrix of skilled and unskilled production efficiencies. Using a vector of n values for unskilled capital, I derive the corresponding values for ks for which rates of return to capital are equalized each period. I use these values for skilled and unskilled capital to derive the optimal choice of next period’s capital, given each ks–ku combination possible in the current period.
As the irreversibility constraint might be binding somewhere along the optimal path, running the value function iteration under the binding constraint is also necessary. For this, a separate grid is introduced for next period’s values of unskilled capital under the binding constraint. Then the value function iteration is used to find the optimal choice of next period’s skilled capital, given that the irreversibility constraint on unskilled capital is binding.
Given the initial values for ks and ku, it is straightforward to pick the optimal paths for both types of capital for 35 periods. If the unconstrained optimal choice violates the irreversibility constraint, the optimal value will be that from the constrained choices.
Updating the guess for production efficiency
With the optimal paths for the two types of capital and the values of production efficiency, I calculate skilled and unskilled wages as implied by the model. The next step calculates the difference between these wages and the actual wages as given in the data. If the sum of squared errors implied by this difference is above the convergence criterion specified, the efficiency matrix is updated. The new matrix will be a weighted average of the old matrix used to derive the latest optimal paths for capital and the values for skilled and unskilled production efficiency that would yield the wages from the data, given the paths for capital. The weights on the old and new efficiencies, λ and 1–λ, are chosen such that convergence is as smooth as possible, as giving too much weight to the new solution can lead to overshooting the true solution and slow down convergence (Judd (1998)). Some values of λ may also send the algorithm into an infinite loop that repeats the same few guesses over and over. If this happens, λ is decreased or increased to escape the loop.
With the new efficiency matrix, the value function iteration described above starts again until the sum of squared errors of the model’s wages compared to actual wages is below a critical value. Note that as there is no uncertainty whatsoever in the model, it is possible in principle to arrive at the exact solution, provided the grid on capital is infinitely fine. This would, however, come at a large cost in computing time.
Effects of changing the initial guess of production efficiency, years to terminal value, or steady state growth rates
As mentioned in Section 1.4.2, the initial guess for production efficiency is chosen to be one in the first period and grow at a certain constant rate afterwards. I also run the program for a variety of other growth rates, equal for both production efficiencies and different, constant and changing. The first period production efficiency however stays the same throughout.
Changing the initial growth rate for production efficiency does not affect results. This is true whether the same growth rate is used for all periods or the growth rate varies for blocks of time. As an example, changing the growth rate for the initial guess from 0.025 to 0.08 for five periods yields the same final production efficiency growth rates as the uniform growth rate for the initial guess.
The choice of m, years until terminal value, depends on the number of grid points chosen. The finer the grid, the larger m needs to be for the results to be unaffected by the exact choice of terminal value. Increasing the number of years between the last period of interest and the terminal value beyond the point where results are constant will only lead to increased computing times. Of course, it is important to check that the number of years is large enough in the first place.
The parameter g is the steady state growth rate to which the economy converges eventually. It does not appear in the period of interest, but is needed to provide a terminal value for the value function iteration. It also pins down, together with β and γ, the growth rates of skilled and unskilled production efficiency after T. I assume that in the long run the economy will converge to its past long run growth rate of 2.5%.
As this is only an assumption, it is very desirable that the results do not depend on the exact choice of this value. Decreasing the steady state growth rate by one percentage point, increases both production efficiency growth rates in the last ten periods by less than one percent (not percentage point), while earlier periods are not affected. Since most of the larger differences between the production efficiency growth rates occur before 1990, the main results do not depend on the choice of steady state growth rate.
Table A1 shows the parameter values used for the algorithm. λ gives the weights of the new and old values of production efficiencies for the updated guess and the next value function iteration. Finally, the convergence criterion determines how small the sum of squared differences between the model’s wages and wage data must be for the program to stop updating.
Preferred parameter specification, Part 2.
Parameter | T | n | m | g | λ | Convergence criterion |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Value | 35 | 1500 | 100 | 0.025 | 0.09 | 10*e–6 |
Derivation of capital shares
Tables A2 and A3 show the skill classification of industries. Each industry is classifies as skilled if the average of its 1970 and its 2005 share of hours worked by high skilled labor is at least 20%, and classified as unskilled otherwise.
Skilled industries.
Industry | Skill Share avg. | Skill Share 1970 | Skill Share 2005 | Capital Share avg. |
---|---|---|---|---|
Education | 63.56 | 58.79 | 68.33 | 0.22 |
Research and development | 56.20 | 40.42 | 71.98 | 0.18 |
Legal, technical, advertising | 51.13 | 41.56 | 60.70 | 0.08 |
Computer, related activities | 50.48 | 35.29 | 65.67 | 0.36 |
Chemicals ex pharma | 46.95 | 31.76 | 62.14 | 0.50 |
Office, accounting, computing | 40.75 | 21.00 | 60.49 | 0.25 |
Activities of membership org | 38.29 | 35.40 | 41.17 | 0.06 |
Insurance, pension funding | 32.63 | 21.20 | 44.05 | 0.20 |
Telecommunication eq. | 32.49 | 12.12 | 52.86 | 0.44 |
Radio and television receivers | 31.52 | 12.14 | 50.90 | 0.25 |
Health and social work | 30.18 | 22.13 | 38.23 | 0.16 |
Financial intermediation | 30.10 | 15.74 | 44.46 | 0.51 |
Publishing | 29.62 | 9.96 | 49.28 | 0.26 |
Aircraft and spacecraft | 29.18 | 14.61 | 43.74 | 0.08 |
Electronic valves and tubes | 29.17 | 10.58 | 47.77 | 0.27 |
Other instruments | 29.11 | 15.38 | 42.84 | 0.16 |
Scientific instruments | 28.64 | 15.20 | 42.09 | 0.15 |
Media activities | 28.46 | 12.93 | 43.98 | 0.22 |
Pharmaceuticals | 27.50 | 18.42 | 36.58 | 0.47 |
Real estate activities | 27.21 | 17.09 | 37.33 | 0.90 |
Other air transport | 24.06 | 11.91 | 36.22 | 0.23 |
Coke, petroleum, nuclear fuel | 23.84 | 15.62 | 32.06 | 0.63 |
Other business activities | 23.74 | 17.37 | 30.12 | 0.32 |
Post and telecoms | 22.77 | 7.39 | 38.15 | 0.54 |
Public administration | 21.71 | 12.18 | 31.24 | 0.32 |
Crude petroleum, natural gas | 21.17 | 14.61 | 27.72 | 0.77 |
Other electrical machinery | 20.52 | 10.59 | 30.44 | 0.25 |
Wholesale, commission trade | 20.28 | 12.02 | 28.53 | 0.26 |
Unskilled industries.
Industry | Skill share avg. | Skill share 1970 | Skill share 2005 | Capital share avg. |
---|---|---|---|---|
Renting of machinery and eq. | 19.36 | 8.43 | 30.29 | 0.79 |
Other water transport | 18.88 | 6.81 | 30.96 | 0.30 |
Electricity supply | 18.75 | 8.13 | 29.38 | 0.68 |
Gas supply | 18.12 | 8.48 | 27.76 | 0.66 |
Other recreational activities | 17.94 | 5.81 | 30.06 | 0.26 |
Tobacco | 17.82 | 7.01 | 28.64 | 0.61 |
Printing and reproduction | 16.64 | 12.56 | 20.72 | 0.24 |
Machinery | 15.67 | 6.87 | 24.47 | 0.24 |
Supporting transport act | 15.65 | 10.29 | 21.01 | 0.37 |
Mining of metal ores | 15.43 | 6.23 | 24.63 | 0.47 |
Motor vehicles and trailers | 14.12 | 6.14 | 22.09 | 0.34 |
Retail trade household goods | 13.70 | 7.10 | 20.29 | 0.16 |
Railroad and transport eq. | 13.56 | 4.62 | 22.49 | 0.45 |
Pulp and paper | 12.17 | 5.82 | 18.52 | 0.35 |
Building, repairing of ships | 11.82 | 6.94 | 16.69 | 0.15 |
Manufacturing nec | 11.77 | 5.84 | 17.71 | 0.26 |
Food and beverages | 11.66 | 5.87 | 17.45 | 0.39 |
Insulated wire | 11.26 | 6.41 | 16.11 | 0.48 |
Basic metals | 11.26 | 6.41 | 16.11 | 0.31 |
Other non-metallic mineral | 10.60 | 5.34 | 15.85 | 0.26 |
Rubber and plastics | 10.43 | 5.00 | 15.87 | 0.22 |
Fabricated metal | 10.12 | 6.54 | 13.71 | 0.27 |
Agriculture | 9.80 | 3.10 | 16.50 | 0.53 |
Other service activities | 9.50 | 1.97 | 17.02 | 0.11 |
Sewage and sanitation | 9.45 | 0.27 | 18.62 | 0.62 |
Wearing apparel, fur | 9.12 | 2.89 | 15.36 | 0.18 |
Hotels, restaurants | 8.58 | 4.01 | 13.15 | 0.22 |
Other mining, quarrying | 8.36 | 6.55 | 10.16 | 0.50 |
Sale of motor vehicles, fuel | 8.14 | 4.87 | 11.41 | –0.08 |
Construction | 7.48 | 3.74 | 11.23 | 0.14 |
Forestry | 7.48 | 0.70 | 14.27 | 0.64 |
Fishing | 7.48 | 0.70 | 14.27 | 0.45 |
Textiles | 7.04 | 2.46 | 11.61 | 0.25 |
Other inland transport | 6.79 | 2.75 | 10.82 | 0.30 |
Wood and cork | 6.63 | 4.01 | 9.24 | 0.30 |
Mining of coal, lignite; peat | 6.32 | 3.12 | 9.52 | 0.48 |
Leather and footwear | 6.31 | 3.75 | 8.88 | 0.29 |
References
Acemoglu, D. 2002a. “Directed Technical Change.” Review of Economic Studies 69 (4): 781–809.10.1111/1467-937X.00226Search in Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. 2002b. “Technical Change, Inequality, and the Labor Market.” Journal of Economic Literature 40 (1): 7–72.Search in Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and D. Autor. 2010. “Skills, Tasks and Technologies: Implications for Employment and Earnings.” NBER Working Papers 16082, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.10.3386/w16082Search in Google Scholar
Aghion, P., P. Howitt, and G. L. Violante. 2002. “General Purpose Technology and Wage Inequality.” Journal of Economic Growth 7 (4): 315–345.10.1023/A:1020875717066Search in Google Scholar
Autor, D., F. Levy, and R. Murnane. 2003. “The Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical Exploration.” Proceedings of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco (Nov).10.1162/003355303322552801Search in Google Scholar
Autor, D. H., L. F. Katz, and M. S. Kearney. 2008. “Trends in U.S. Wage Inequality: Revising the Revisionists.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 90 (2): 300–323.10.1162/rest.90.2.300Search in Google Scholar
Barany, Z. 2011. “The Minimum Wage and Inequality – The Effects of Education and Technology.” Unpublished phd thesis.Search in Google Scholar
Beaudry, P., and D. A. Green. 2002. “Changes in U.S. Wages 1976–2000: Ongoing Skill Bias or Major Technological Change?” NBER Working Papers 8787, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.10.3386/w8787Search in Google Scholar
Berman, E., J. Bound, and Z. Griliches. 1994. “Changes in the Demand for Skilled Labor within U.S. Manufacturing: Evidence from the Annual Survey of Manufactures.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 109 (2): 367–397.10.2307/2118467Search in Google Scholar
Bertola, G. 1998. “Irreversible Investment.” Research in Economics 52 (1): 3–37.10.1006/reec.1997.0153Search in Google Scholar
Bliss, C. 1968. “On Putty-clay.” The Review of Economic Studies 35 (2): 105–132.10.2307/2296542Search in Google Scholar
Burstein, A., and J. Vogel. 2010. “Globalization, Technology, and the Skill Premium: A Quantitative Analysis.” Working Paper 1.Search in Google Scholar
Caballero, R. J. 1999. “Aggregate Investment.” In Handbook of Macroeconomics, volume 1 of Handbook of Macroeconomics, edited by J. B. Taylor and M. Woodford, 813–862. Chapter 12, Amsterdam: Elsevier.10.1016/S1574-0048(99)10020-XSearch in Google Scholar
Card, D., and J. E. DiNardo. 2002. “Skill-biased Technological Change and Rising Wage Inequality: Some Problems and Puzzles.” Journal of Labor Economics 20 (4): 733–783.10.1086/342055Search in Google Scholar
Caselli, F. 1999. “Technological Revolutions.” American Economic Review 89 (1): 78–102.10.1257/aer.89.1.78Search in Google Scholar
Caselli, F. and W. J. Coleman. 2001. “The U.S. Structural Transformation and Regional Convergence: A Reinterpretation.” Journal of Political Economy 109 (3): 584–616.10.1086/321015Search in Google Scholar
Coleman, W. J. 1997. “Behavior of Interest Rates in a General Equilibrium Multisector Model with Irreversible Investment.” Macroeconomic Dynamics 1 (01): 206–227.10.1017/S1365100597002071Search in Google Scholar
Dixit, A. 1995. “Irreversible Investment with Uncertainty and Scale Economies.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 19 (1–2): 327–350.10.1016/0165-1889(93)00784-2Search in Google Scholar
Eckstein, Z., and E. Nagypal. 2004. “The Evolution of us Earnings Inequality. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 28 (2): 10–29.Search in Google Scholar
EUKLEMS. 2008. see Marcel Timmer, Mary O’Mahony & Bart van Ark, The EU KLEMS Growth and Productivity Accounts: An Overview, University of Groningen & University of Birmingham; downloadable at www.euklems.net.Search in Google Scholar
Fortin, N. M., and T. Lemieux. 1997. “Institutional Changes and Rising Wage Inequality: Is there a Linkage?” Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (2): 75–96.10.1257/jep.11.2.75Search in Google Scholar
Galor, O., and O. Moav. 2000. “Ability-biased Technological Transition, Wage Inequality, and Economic Growth.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (2): 469–497.10.1162/003355300554827Search in Google Scholar
Gilchrist, S., and J. C. Williams. 2000. “Putty-clay and Investment: A Business Cycle Analysis.” Journal of Political Economy 108 (5): 928–960.10.1086/317673Search in Google Scholar
Goldin, C., and L. F. Katz. 2007. “The Race Between Education and Technology: The Evolution of U.S. Educational Wage Differentials, 1890 to 2005.” NBER Working Papers 12984, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.10.3386/w12984Search in Google Scholar
Gottschalk, P. 1997. “Inequality, Income Growth, and Mobility: The Basic Facts.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (2): 21–40.10.1257/jep.11.2.21Search in Google Scholar
Greenwood, J., Z. Hercowitz, and P. Krusell. 1997. “Long-run Implications of Investment-specific Technological Change.” American Economic Review 87 (3): 342–362.Search in Google Scholar
Johansen, L. 1959. “Substitution versus Fixed Production Coefficients in the Theory of Economic Growth: A Synthesis.” Econometrica 27 (2): 157–176.10.2307/1909440Search in Google Scholar
Johnson, G. E. 1997. “Changes in Earnings Inequality: The Role of Demand Shifts.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (2): 41–54.10.1257/jep.11.2.41Search in Google Scholar
Jones, R. W. 1971. “A Three-factor Model in Theory, Trade and History.” In Trade, Balance of Payments and Growth, edited by Jagdeesh Bhagwati et al. North Holland, Amsterdam.Search in Google Scholar
Jorgenson, D., M. Ho, and K. Stiroh. 2003. “Growth of U.S. Industries and Investments in Information Technology and Higher Education.” Economic Systems Research 15 (3): 279–325.10.1080/0953531032000111781Search in Google Scholar
Jovanovic, B. 1998. “Vintage Capital and Inequality.” Review of Economic Dynamics 1 (2): 497–530.10.1006/redy.1998.0013Search in Google Scholar
Jovanovic, B., and Y. Yatsenko. 2012. “Investment in Vintage Capital.” Journal of Economic Theory 147 (2): 551–569.10.1016/j.jet.2010.10.017Search in Google Scholar
Judd, K. L. 1998. Numerical Methods in Economics. ISBN 0262100711. The MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar
Katz, L. F., and D. H. Autor. 1999. “Changes in the Wage Structure and Earnings Inequality.” In Handbook of Labor Economics, volume 3 of Handbook of Labor Economics, chapter 26, edited by O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, 1463–1555. Amsterdam: Elsevier.10.1016/S1573-4463(99)03007-2Search in Google Scholar
Kehoe, P. J. and A. Atkeson. 1999. “Models of Energy Use: Putty-putty versus Putty-clay. American Economic Review 89 (4): 1028–1043.10.1257/aer.89.4.1028Search in Google Scholar
Krusell, P., L. E. Ohanian, J.-V. Rios-Rull, and G. L. Violante. 2000. “Capital-skill Complementarity and Inequality: A Macroeconomic Analysis.” Econometrica 68 (5): 1029–1054.10.1111/1468-0262.00150Search in Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W. 2005. “The Sources of the Productivity Rebound and the Manufacturing Employment Puzzle.” NBER Working Papers 11354, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.10.3386/w11354Search in Google Scholar
Olson, L. J. 1989. “Stochastic Growth with Irreversible Investment.” Journal of Economic Theory 47 (1): 101–129.10.1016/0022-0531(89)90105-1Search in Google Scholar
Ruiz-Arranz, M. 2003. Wage Inequality in the U.S.: Capital-skill Complementarity vs. Skill-biased Technological Change. Harvard mimeo, Harvard University.Search in Google Scholar
Sargent, T. J. 1980. ““Tobin’s q” and the Rate of Investment in General Equilibrium.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 12 (1): 107–154.10.1016/0167-2231(80)90024-XSearch in Google Scholar
Spitz-Oener, A. 2006. “Technical Change, Job Tasks, and Rising Educational Demands: Looking Outside the Wage Structure.” Journal of Labor Economics 24 (2): 235–270.10.1086/499972Search in Google Scholar
Timmer, M. P., M. O’Mahony, and B. van Ark. 2007. “EU KLEMS Growth and Productivity Accounts: An Overview.” International Productivity Monitor 14: 71–85.10.1177/0027950107080390Search in Google Scholar
Topel, R. H. 1997. “Factor Proportions and Relative Wages: The Supply-side Determinants of Wage Inequality.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (2): 55–74.10.1257/jep.11.2.55Search in Google Scholar
©2014 by De Gruyter
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Advances
- Optimal portfolios with wealth-varying risk aversion in the neoclassical growth model
- Inventories and the stockout constraint in general equilibrium
- Optimal second best taxation of addictive goods in dynamic general equilibrium: a revenue raising perspective
- Inflation effects on capital accumulation in a model with residential and non-residential assets
- Optimal capital-income taxation in a model with credit frictions
- Contributions
- Interest rate fluctuations and equilibrium in the housing market
- News shocks and learning-by-doing
- Capacity utilization and the effects of energy price increases in Japan
- Small-scale New Keynesian model features that can reproduce lead, lag and persistence patterns
- Optimal policy and Taylor rule cross-checking under parameter uncertainty
- The impact of American and British involvement in Afghanistan and Iraq on health spending, military spending and economic growth
- Why does natural resource abundance not always lead to better outcomes? Limited financial development versus political impatience
- The skill bias of technological change and the evolution of the skill premium in the US since 1970
- Aggregate impacts of recent US natural gas trends
- Organizational learning and optimal fiscal and monetary policy
- Industrial specialization, financial integration and international consumption risk sharing
- Leverage, investment, and optimal monetary policy
- Public debt in an OLG model with imperfect competition: long-run effects of austerity programs and changes in the growth rate
- Temporal aggregation and estimated monetary policy rules
- International transmission of productivity shocks with nonzero net foreign debt
- Did the euro change the effect of fundamentals on growth and uncertainty?
- Topics
- Real factor prices and factor-augmenting technical change
- Monetary policy and TIPS yields before the crisis
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Advances
- Optimal portfolios with wealth-varying risk aversion in the neoclassical growth model
- Inventories and the stockout constraint in general equilibrium
- Optimal second best taxation of addictive goods in dynamic general equilibrium: a revenue raising perspective
- Inflation effects on capital accumulation in a model with residential and non-residential assets
- Optimal capital-income taxation in a model with credit frictions
- Contributions
- Interest rate fluctuations and equilibrium in the housing market
- News shocks and learning-by-doing
- Capacity utilization and the effects of energy price increases in Japan
- Small-scale New Keynesian model features that can reproduce lead, lag and persistence patterns
- Optimal policy and Taylor rule cross-checking under parameter uncertainty
- The impact of American and British involvement in Afghanistan and Iraq on health spending, military spending and economic growth
- Why does natural resource abundance not always lead to better outcomes? Limited financial development versus political impatience
- The skill bias of technological change and the evolution of the skill premium in the US since 1970
- Aggregate impacts of recent US natural gas trends
- Organizational learning and optimal fiscal and monetary policy
- Industrial specialization, financial integration and international consumption risk sharing
- Leverage, investment, and optimal monetary policy
- Public debt in an OLG model with imperfect competition: long-run effects of austerity programs and changes in the growth rate
- Temporal aggregation and estimated monetary policy rules
- International transmission of productivity shocks with nonzero net foreign debt
- Did the euro change the effect of fundamentals on growth and uncertainty?
- Topics
- Real factor prices and factor-augmenting technical change
- Monetary policy and TIPS yields before the crisis