Abstract
Temporal aggregation alters time-series properties of high-frequency data, thereby affecting the estimation of models based on time-aggregated low-frequency data. This paper examines the effect of temporal aggregation of interest rates on forward-looking Taylor-type monetary policy rules. Results show that using quarterly-averaged interest rates in standard forward-looking structures adds a spurious bias to parameters that measure the extent of interest rate smoothing and serial correlation of shocks. Consequently, empirical interpretations of persistence in policy interest rate changes are distorted.
Acknowledgments
I am grateful to Refet Gurkaynak, Bill Neilson, Mohammed Mohsin, Christian Vossler, seminar participants at the University of Tennessee and the Central Bank of Republic of Turkey, and three anonymous referees for helpful comments. Any remaining errors are mine.
Appendix
Previous studies show that temporal aggregation changes both the ARIMA order of a time series and the size of its autoregressive and moving average coefficients. I provide below a brief summary of past research to demonstrate how averaging affects the ARIMA order of a time series differently from sampling.
Suppose that the underlying data generating process yt can be described by the following ARIMA (p, d, q) model.

where Δ=(1–L) and L is the lag operator.
It is assumed that the underlying ARIMA (p, d, q) model operates on the time interval 1, indexed by t. Temporally aggregated processes, both sampled and averaged, are observed at interval m>1, indexed by T.
A sampled sub-series {ysT} is generated from the original series {yt} by selecting values distanced at m periods such that ysT=ymt for m>1, an integer representing the sampling ratio between the original series and the temporally aggregated sub-series. Sampled sub-series {ysT} follows an ARIMA (p, d, r) process where r=(p+d)+(q–p–d)/m.[18] Moving average order of the sampled representation, if not an integer, is rounded down to the previous integer. Therefore, the number of moving average lags is p+d or p+d–1, depending on whether q>p+d or q<p+d.
An averaged sub-series {yaT} is generated by averaging every m adjacent value from the original series {yt} such that observations from the original series do not overlap. Averaged sub-series yaT=[ymt+ymt–1+…+ymt-m+1]/m follows an ARIMA (p, d, r) process where r=(p+d+1)+(q–p–d–1)/m. Consequently, the number of moving average lags in the averaged sub-series is p+d+1 or p+d, depending on whether q>p+d+1 or q<p+d+1.[19]
Evidently, number of autoregressive lags (p) and order of integration (d) remain unchanged for the two sub-series generated from the same underlying process {yt} at the same sampling ratio m. By contrast, the averaged sub-series may have one more moving average lag (q) than its sampled counterpart.
To determine the implications of this result for monetary policy evaluation, I estimate univariate ARIMA models of temporally aggregated interest rates for the same sample period from above, 1987Q4 to 2005Q. Sarno, Thornton, and Valente (2005) reports that an ARIMA (2, 1, 1) specification is satisfactory in modeling daily federal funds rate, as this structure is parsimonious and leaves no serial correlation in residuals.[20] Then, theoretical results from this section suggest that the sampled funds rate series must follow an ARIMA (2, 1, 2) process, while the averaged funds rate series must follow an ARIMA (2, 1, 3) process, where the number of autoregressive and moving average lags in the two sub-series is less than or equal to designated numbers.
Table A1 presents estimates for quarterly-averaged and end-of-quarter funds rates under alternative ARIMA specifications. Here, I consider higher-order AR and MA components to the extent implied by theory: up to two autoregressive lags in both sub-series; up to two and three moving average lags in the end-of-quarter and quarterly-averaged sub-series, respectively. Results are reported for specifications favored by a combination of factors including parsimony, Akaike and Bayesian information criteria, tests of white noise residuals, and speed of model conversion.
Univariate ARIMA estimates for target federal funds rate.
Specification | QA | EOQ |
---|---|---|
ARIMA (1, 1, 0) | ||
AR (1) [p-value] | 0.68 [0.00] | 0.61 [0.00] |
AIC | 61.74 | 81.13 |
BIC | 68.61 | 88.00 |
Portmanteau (Q) test statistic [p-value] | 30.08 [0.87] | 30.97 [0.85] |
ARIMA (2, 1, 0) | ||
AR (1) [p-value] | 0.69 [0.00] | 0.61 [0.00] |
AR (2) [p-value] | –0.02 [0.90] | –0.01 [0.97] |
AIC | 63.71 | 83.13 |
BIC | 72.87 | 92.29 |
Portmanteau (Q) test statistic [p-value] | 30.15 [0.87] | 31.02 [0.85] |
ARIMA (2, 1, 1) | ||
AR (1) [p-value] | 1.63 [0.00] | 1.57 [0.00] |
AR (2) [p-value] | –0.70 [0.00] | –0.64 [0.00] |
MA (1) [p-value] | –1.00 [0.00] | –0.99 [0.00] |
AIC | 59.91 | 80.23 |
BIC | 71.36 | 91.68 |
Portmanteau (Q) test statistic [p-value] | 28.43 [0.92] | 32.68 [0.79] |
AIC/BIC represent Akaike and Bayesian information criteria; smaller values indicate an improved tradeoff between goodness of fit and model complexity. Null hypothesis for the Portmanteau (Q) test is that residuals follow a white noise process.
Differences in parameter estimates remain, indicating that between sampled and averaged interest rates, indicating that averaging affects time-series properties of the daily interest rate series differently than sampling. Although this result is consistent with underlying theory, it should be taken with caution in regard to policy evaluation, as univariate models considered here disregard the main determinants of monetary policy, inflation and output gap.
References
Anderson, T., and H. Rubin. 1949. “Estimation of The Parameters of A Single Equation in a Complete System of Stochastic Equations.” Annals of Mathematical Statistics 20: 46–63.10.1214/aoms/1177730090Search in Google Scholar
Baum, C., M. Schaffer, and S. Stillman. 2003. “Instrumental Variables and GMM: Estimation and Testing.” The Stata Journal 3: 1–31.10.1177/1536867X0300300101Search in Google Scholar
Cameron, C., and P. Trivedi. 2009. Microeconometrics Using Stata. Texas: Stata Press.Search in Google Scholar
Castelnuovo, E. 2003. “Taylor rules, Omitted Variables, and Interest rate Smoothing in the US.” Economics Letters 81: 55–59.10.1016/S0165-1765(03)00152-6Search in Google Scholar
Christiano, L., and M. Eichenbaum. 1987. “Temporal Aggregation and Structural Inference in Macroeconomics.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 26: 63–130.10.1016/0167-2231(87)90022-4Search in Google Scholar
Clarida, R., J. Gali, and M.Gertler. 2000. “Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence and Some Theory.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 115: 147–180.10.1162/003355300554692Search in Google Scholar
Coibion, O., and Y. Gorodnichenko. 2012. “Why are Target Interest Rate Changes so Persistent?” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 4: 126–162.10.1257/mac.4.4.126Search in Google Scholar
Consolo, A., and C. Favero. 2009. “Monetary Policy Inertia: More a Fiction than A Fact?” Journal of Monetary Economics 49: 1161–1187.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2009.06.007Search in Google Scholar
Cragg, J., and S. Donald. 1993. “Testing Identifiability and Specification in Instrumental Variable Models.” Econometric Theory 9: 222–240.10.1017/S0266466600007519Search in Google Scholar
Dufour, J. M., L. Khalaf, and M. Kichian. 2006. “Inflation Dynamics and the New Keynesian Phillips Curve: An Identification Robust Econometric Analysis.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 30: 1707–1727.10.1016/j.jedc.2005.08.013Search in Google Scholar
English, W., W. Nelson, and B. Sack. 2003. “Interpreting the Significance of the Lagged Interest Rate in Estimated Monetary Policy Rules.” The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics (Contributions) 3: 1–16.10.2202/1534-6005.1073Search in Google Scholar
Gerlach-Kristen, P. 2004. “Interest-Rate Smoothing: Monetary Policy Inertia or Unobserved Variables?” The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics (Contributions) 4: 1–17.10.2202/1534-6005.1169Search in Google Scholar
Kleibergen, F., and R. Paap. 2006. “Generalized Reduced Rank Tests Using the Singular Value Decomposition.” Journal of Econometrics 133: 97–126.10.1016/j.jeconom.2005.02.011Search in Google Scholar
Orphanides, A. 2001. “Monetary Policy Rules Based on Real-Time Data.” American Economic Review 91: 964–985.10.1257/aer.91.4.964Search in Google Scholar
Rudebusch, G. 2002. “Term Structure Evidence on Interest Rate Smoothing and Monetary Policy Inertia.” Journal of Monetary Economics 49: 1161–1187.10.1016/S0304-3932(02)00149-6Search in Google Scholar
Rudebusch, G. 2006. “Monetary Policy Inertia: Fact or Fiction?” International Journal of Central Banking 2: 85–135.10.2139/ssrn.864484Search in Google Scholar
Rudebusch, G., and T. Wu. 2008. “A Macro-Finance Model of the Term Structure, Monetary Policy and the Economy.” The Economic Journal 118: 906–926.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2008.02155.xSearch in Google Scholar
Sack, B., and V. Wieland. 2000. “Interest-Rate Smoothing and Optimal Monetary Policy: A Review of Recent Empirical Evidence.” Journal of Economics and Business 52: 205–228.10.1016/S0148-6195(99)00030-2Search in Google Scholar
Sarno, L., D. Thornton, and G. Valente. 2005. “Federal Funds Rate Prediction.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 37: 449–471.10.1353/mcb.2005.0035Search in Google Scholar
Stock, J., and M. Yogo. 2005. “Testing for Weak Instruments in Linear IV Regression.” In Andrews DWK Identification and Inference for Econometric Models. New York: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511614491.006Search in Google Scholar
Taylor, J. 1993. “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39: 195–214.10.1016/0167-2231(93)90009-LSearch in Google Scholar
Taylor, A. 2001. “Potential Pitfalls for the Purchasing-Power-Parity Puzzle? Sampling and Specification Biases in Mean-Reversion Tests of the Law of One Price.” Econometrica 69: 473–498.10.1111/1468-0262.00199Search in Google Scholar
Tiao, G. 1972. “Asymptotic Behavior of Temporal Aggregates of Time Series.” Biometrika 59: 525–531.10.1093/biomet/59.3.525Search in Google Scholar
Wei, W. 1981. “Effect of Systematic Sampling on ARIMA Models.” Communications in Statistical-Theoretical Mathematics 10: 2389–2398.10.1080/03610928108828197Search in Google Scholar
Weiss, A. 1984. “Systematic Sampling and Temporal Aggregation in Time Series Models.” Journal of Econometrics 26: 271–281.10.1016/0304-4076(84)90022-8Search in Google Scholar
Woodford, M. 2003. Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9781400830169Search in Google Scholar
Working, H. 1960. “Note on the Correlation of First Differences of Averages in a Random Chain.” Econometrica 26: 916–918.10.2307/1907574Search in Google Scholar
©2014 by De Gruyter
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Advances
- Optimal portfolios with wealth-varying risk aversion in the neoclassical growth model
- Inventories and the stockout constraint in general equilibrium
- Optimal second best taxation of addictive goods in dynamic general equilibrium: a revenue raising perspective
- Inflation effects on capital accumulation in a model with residential and non-residential assets
- Optimal capital-income taxation in a model with credit frictions
- Contributions
- Interest rate fluctuations and equilibrium in the housing market
- News shocks and learning-by-doing
- Capacity utilization and the effects of energy price increases in Japan
- Small-scale New Keynesian model features that can reproduce lead, lag and persistence patterns
- Optimal policy and Taylor rule cross-checking under parameter uncertainty
- The impact of American and British involvement in Afghanistan and Iraq on health spending, military spending and economic growth
- Why does natural resource abundance not always lead to better outcomes? Limited financial development versus political impatience
- The skill bias of technological change and the evolution of the skill premium in the US since 1970
- Aggregate impacts of recent US natural gas trends
- Organizational learning and optimal fiscal and monetary policy
- Industrial specialization, financial integration and international consumption risk sharing
- Leverage, investment, and optimal monetary policy
- Public debt in an OLG model with imperfect competition: long-run effects of austerity programs and changes in the growth rate
- Temporal aggregation and estimated monetary policy rules
- International transmission of productivity shocks with nonzero net foreign debt
- Did the euro change the effect of fundamentals on growth and uncertainty?
- Topics
- Real factor prices and factor-augmenting technical change
- Monetary policy and TIPS yields before the crisis
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Advances
- Optimal portfolios with wealth-varying risk aversion in the neoclassical growth model
- Inventories and the stockout constraint in general equilibrium
- Optimal second best taxation of addictive goods in dynamic general equilibrium: a revenue raising perspective
- Inflation effects on capital accumulation in a model with residential and non-residential assets
- Optimal capital-income taxation in a model with credit frictions
- Contributions
- Interest rate fluctuations and equilibrium in the housing market
- News shocks and learning-by-doing
- Capacity utilization and the effects of energy price increases in Japan
- Small-scale New Keynesian model features that can reproduce lead, lag and persistence patterns
- Optimal policy and Taylor rule cross-checking under parameter uncertainty
- The impact of American and British involvement in Afghanistan and Iraq on health spending, military spending and economic growth
- Why does natural resource abundance not always lead to better outcomes? Limited financial development versus political impatience
- The skill bias of technological change and the evolution of the skill premium in the US since 1970
- Aggregate impacts of recent US natural gas trends
- Organizational learning and optimal fiscal and monetary policy
- Industrial specialization, financial integration and international consumption risk sharing
- Leverage, investment, and optimal monetary policy
- Public debt in an OLG model with imperfect competition: long-run effects of austerity programs and changes in the growth rate
- Temporal aggregation and estimated monetary policy rules
- International transmission of productivity shocks with nonzero net foreign debt
- Did the euro change the effect of fundamentals on growth and uncertainty?
- Topics
- Real factor prices and factor-augmenting technical change
- Monetary policy and TIPS yields before the crisis