Abstract
This article identifies the necessary and sufficient conditions under which a monopolist, producing a network good, benefits from introducing a higher quality in the market. It is shown that, if the network externality is higher than the intrinsic quality differential, quality improvement is not optimal. Also, we obtain that, for low levels of the network effect, the monopolist prefers not to cover the market, whereas for higher levels, optimal prices are such that all consumers buy one of the two qualities. Finally, there is an introductory price strategy which is optimal for the good that benefits from network externalities.
Appendix A
The optimal second period pricing behavior of the monopolist for each of the innovation policies is analyzed here in detail.
A.1 Multiproduct monopolist
Consider first the optimal behavior of the monopolist in the policy where it sells both products, and the market remains uncovered.
A.1.1 The monopolist does not cover the market
We proceed by analyzing the second period problem of the monopolist, given the choice of first period price, . Posit that the monopolist decides to sell goods 1 and 2 in the second period, without covering the market. Since
, the market is not covered if the indifferent consumer between buying good 1 and not buying is strictly larger than 0. That is, we must have
, which is equivalent to
. We will now obtain the optimal prices and then verify if they are consistent with the hypothesis of uncovered market by the multiproduct monopolist.
Lemma 1When the monopolist decides to sell both products in period 2, there exists a positive value of, say
, such that the optimal prices are consistent with the option of not covering the market whenever
. In this interval of
, the initial price of good 1 is positive.
Proof. See Appendix B. ■
Lemma 1 states that for sufficiently small, the monopolist has the option of selling both goods in the second period, leaving the market uncovered. When
, the monopolist chooses prices given by
![[12]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq14.png)
with corresponding total profits
![[13]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq15.png)
Notice that , and thus, if we define introductory pricing by requiring an increasing path of prices over periods, introductory pricing is indeed a candidate optimum. However,
and consequently, the installed base is not maximized in period 1. Intuitively, as
is low, the consumers do not place enough importance on the network to induce the monopolist to decrease the initial price to zero, foregoing profits in period 1.
A.1.2 The monopolist covers the whole market
Consider now the second period problem when the monopolist decides to cover the market with goods 1 and 2. Given that , the market is covered when
.
Lemma 2When the monopolist decides to sell both products in period 2, there exists an interval ofvalues, namely
such that there exist optimal prices consistent with a covered market. In this interval of
values, the optimal pricing for first period is positive if
, where
, and zero otherwise.15
Proof. See Appendix B. ■
Lemma 2 states that for some values of the quality differential and the network effect intensity, selling both products and covering the market is a candidate optimum. The corresponding prices are given by
![[14]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq16.png)
when , and
![[15]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq17.png)
when .
The total profit is given by
![[16]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq18.png)
![[17]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq19.png)
Corollary 2Under the multiproduct innovation policy, the optimal pricing behavior of the monopolist is consistent either with a covered market with initial zero price or with an uncovered market.
The optimal pricing behavior is consistent with an uncovered market when , while it is consistent with a covered market with initial zero price when
. In Appendix B, we show that
when
, thus proving that
and
are disjoint intervals.
A.2 Strict quality improvement
Now, consider that the monopolist sells good 1 in the first period, while it decides to substitute good 1 for good 2 in the second. The monopolist avoids cannibalizing sales of good 1 in the second period by introducing a high-quality good. Given that network effects are delayed by one period, it disregards the impact of first period sales in period 2 and sets monopoly prices in both periods. The optimum is, thus, given by and
, and total profits are
.
A.3 No quality improvement
Finally, assume that the monopolist decides to sell only good 1 in the two periods, disregarding completely quality improvement.
Lemma 3When the monopolist decides to disregard the quality improvement, there is a threshold value for, namely,
, such that the optimal monopolist solution is given by positive initial pricing when
and zero initial pricing when
.
Proof. See Appendix B. ■
The corresponding prices are given by
![[18]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq20.png)
for , and

when .
From Lemma 3, we know that, in a solution where the monopolist disregards the quality improvement, the network is maximal only if is not too large with respect to the quality of good 1. Introductory pricing is always chosen at the optimum, however, the initial price is zero only if
is high enough.
Appendix B: Proofs
B.1 Lemma 1
Proof. When the market is uncovered, the monopolist solves the following optimization problem:

The first-order conditions are

The optimal solution is

and the equilibrium demands are

We must guarantee that that is,
which occurs when
![[19]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq26.png)
Condition [19] depends on and consequently on
Its fulfillment can only be assessed after disclosing the optimal choice of
The monopolist chooses
to maximize overall profit

This function is concave when and convex otherwise. Solving the inequality for
we have that whenever
the profit function
is concave. When the function is concave, the optimum is attained at the root of the first derivative of
, namely,

This price, belongs to the admissible interval
if and only if
. This condition can be written as
. If
and
, the function is concave, however,
Finally, when
, the function is convex and
We must now verify whether condition [19] is verified when both
and
If
, the condition [19], for the existence of an uncovered market optimal solution, is
However, since we assume
, whenever the optimal solution is
the condition is never met. Notice that
is zero when
Also, there exists an uncovered market solution when
if
However,
so, no uncovered market solution exists with
.
If , condition [19] can be rewritten as

and it is satisfied when It is easy to show that
. Hence, an uncovered market solution exists in the domain
, and it is equal to

B.2 Lemma 2
Proof. The monopolist solves the following problem:

Writing the Lagrangian, we have

and the Kuhn–Tucker conditions are

The unique finite solution for this problem occurs, when , and
We must check whether the demands are positive and smaller than 1 at this solution. The demand of good 1 evaluated at the optimal prices is
, and we must guarantee that
![[20]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq34.png)
In the first stage, the monopolist chooses to maximize overall profit given by

This function is concave when , or equivalently when
, and convex otherwise. Whenever the function is concave, it attains its maximum at
This value of
is strictly lower than
. However, if
, or equivalently,
, it can assume negative values, in which case the optimum is attained in the boundary of the admissible set, namely, at
. When the global profit is convex, it is easily seen that the optimum is attained at
. In summary, for
, the function is convex, and
; for
, the profit function is concave, and the optimum is again attained at
; and for
, the profit function is concave, and the optimal
is positive.16
We must now check whether the solutions , and
, allow to maintain consistency with the initial condition for the existence of the second period covered market equilibrium, condition [20]. When
the solution is valid if and only if
. As
is a solution if and only if
, the first and second period solutions are valid in the domain
that can be shown to be non-empty (for
).
When condition [20] implies that

which is equivalent to This expression is true whenever
, which happens for
, the domain where the solution
is valid. So, it is possible to have
, inducing a covered market solution in the second stage. ■
B.3 Corollary 2
Proof. Here, we show that . Note that

The RHS is positive for (it is increasing in
for
, and 0 for
). Taking squares,

■
B.4 Lemma 3
Proof. The demand of the monopolist is given by the mass of consumers whose valuation is above price, that is,
![[21]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq39.png)
The demand at period 2 is given by
![[22]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq40.png)
In the second period, the monopolist solves the following problem:

The Lagrangian of the problem is the following:

and the Kuhn–Tucker conditions are

This system has two solutions. We consider first the case where the restriction is not binding, i.e. and
The demand must be positive and less than 1, and this occurs if and only if
The condition that must be satisfied is
![[23]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq44.png)
If the solution is valid, the monopolist chooses to maximize:

This function is concave when in which case the profit is maximized for
So, when
, the profit function is convex, and the optimum is obtained at
. When
, the function is concave, but the optimum is attained in the lower boundary of the admissible set for
namely
When
the function is concave and
We must now check whether
or
are consistent with condition [23]. For
we must have
however, the solution
occurs only when
, and thus this solution is not consistent with the second period optimal solution given by
As for
the condition [23] boils down to
, which is true whenever
situation where
is effectively optimal.
We analyze now the possibility that the restriction is binding. In that case, and
. The condition for this solution to be valid is
![[24]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq46.png)
If this solution is valid, the monopolist maximizes in the first period, the following overall profit function:

This function is overall concave, and the optimum is attained at If
,
if
. We must now check whether the condition [24] works. Consider first
, then we must have
, which coincides with the area of parameters where
is effectively optimal. Now, if
, the condition is
. However, for
,
is not optimal. The condition is not met. ■
B.5 Theorem 1
Proof. We start by identifying the monopolist’s options as follows:
Selling both goods, leaving a part of the market unserved, and not practicing introductory pricing. The profit is
Selling only good 1 in the second period and not practising introductory pricing (no improvement option). Profit is
Selling only good 2 in the second period and obtaining profit
Selling only good 1 in the second period and practising introductory pricing (no improvement option). Profit
Selling both goods, covering the market, and practising introductory pricing. The profit is
Selling both goods, covering the market, and not practising introductory pricing. The profit is
.
Lemma A.1Wheneverwe have
Proof. First we show that
![[25]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq48.png)
Whenever , we obtain
From Corollary 2, it follows that
We must just show that

Whenever , we obtain
■
The monopolist faces the following options for the different subsets of the parameter space,
Case 1:
the monopolist chooses between options (a), (b), (c) and (f).
Case 2:
the monopolist chooses between options (a), (c), (d), and (f).
Case 3:
the monopolist chooses between options (c), (d), and (f).
Case 4:
the monopolist chooses between options (c), (d), and (e).
Case 5:
the monopolist chooses between options (c) and (d).
Case 1: we show first that (a) dominates (b), then that (a) dominates (c), and finally that (a) dominates (f)

Also,

Finally,

It is easy to see that the last two conditions hold for .
The optimal choice of the monopolist is to sell both products, uncovering the market and not practising introductory pricing.
Case 2: the monopolist may choose between options (a), (c), (d), and (f). As shown in Case 1,
(the proof was independent of the interval of values for the parameter
). Now, we show that
The strategy that we will use is the following: First, we show that
whenever
and then we use the result in Case 1 to conclude that
.

We can easily show that whenever
Therefore, the above inequality can be rewritten as:

Then, . Finally, we must show that
. We have that
, whenever
. It can be shown, after some lengthy computations, that this is the case in the domain
and
.17
Case 4: the monopolist chooses between (c), (d), and (e). We have that


and .



Then, the optimal solution is to cover the market selling both products.
Case 5: the monopolist chooses between options (c) and (d).

If this inequality holds for the smallest value of , it holds everywhere. For
, we have

And so, we can conclude that holds.
Finally, for Case 3, we must check now how compares to
and to
The sign of the expression
depends on the sign of
under concavity of the profit function. This polynomial has a single root which is always negative. At
, the polynomial is positive, which means that it is positive for all values of
So, we have that
. Now, we compute

The denominator is positive. The numerator is a polynomial of the second degree with two roots, one negative and one positive. We obtain that, within the interval that we are analyzing, the function is positive, i.e. in the interval
. If
, we know that in the interval
,
and thus
. The monopolist would then choose to sell only good 2 in period 2. However, we can guarantee that
if and only if
(this is the reason why we have assumed that
). Likewise, if
, in the interval
. So, the monopolist prefers to sell both goods and cover the market, rather than selling only one of the qualities. ■
B.6 Corollary 1
Proof. The proof of the first part of Corollary 1 follows from the proof of Theorem 1. Here, we prove the second part of Corollary 1. When , we have to solve the problem of a multiproduct vertically differentiated monopolist. As mentioned before, a monopolist will never cover the market if network externalities are not present. The question, which variety or varieties will it offer. Offering both varieties, its profit function is given by

Demands are positive if and only if Also, we assume that at least the agent with the highest valuation is willing to buy either good, i.e.
and
. Given these restrictions the profit is maximized for

This implies that

So, in practice, prices are set such that no consumer buys good 1. There is strict improvement of the quality. ■
B.7 Theorem 2
Proof. Introductory pricing occurs when the optimal price in period 1 is lower than the optimal price in period 2. We will now compare and
(obtained in Appendix A) for the optimal innovation policies in each of the intervals of
.

We can compute

Notice that the numerator of the expression is positive, whereas the denominator is positive under the condition that the profit function for the multiproduct uncovered market case is concave, as specified in the proof of Theorem 1. So, and introductory pricing is optimal. Moreover,
, since
(see proof of Theorem 1).
![[26]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq68.png)
We can compute

For , the numerator is positive. The denominator is also positive under the condition that the profit function for the multiproduct covered market case is concave, as specified in the proof of Theorem 1. So,
and introductory pricing is optimal. Moreover,
, since
(see proof of Theorem 1).
![[27]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq70.png)
Then,

B.8 Theorem 3
Proof. First, we compute the welfare of each alternative. In the uncovered market case, it is easy to obtain
![[28]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq72.png)
and
![[29]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq73.png)
For the covered market solution with
![[30]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq74.png)
![[31]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq75.png)
For the covered market solution with ,

and

Also, if strict improvement is the optimal solution, the consumer surplus is
![[32]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq78.png)
and the overall welfare is
![[33]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq79.png)
Finally, for the no improvement solution, the consumer surplus is given by
![[34]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq80.png)
and
![[35]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq81.png)
Total welfare is
![[36]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq82.png)
![[37]](/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2013-0092/asset/graphic/bejte-2013-0092_eq83.png)
Now, we perform the comparison of the welfare in the different subsets of parameter’s space.
Case 1: , first of all we compare
and
. Both these functions are convex and increasing, and at
,
and at
,
. Given this, there exists a level of
such that for
,
and for
. Concerning the other options we have seen that
. Now, we show that also
It is easy to see that
can be written as
where K is positive and
, such that

is always verified. We can thus conclude that . Also,
and
, so,
So, in this case, the optimal policy in terms of welfare is to choose an uncovered market solution, if
is lower than
, and a covered market with positive prices in period 1, otherwise.
Case 2: As before,
. And now, also
, because
and
. Monotonicity and convexity of
and
imply that results from Case 1 are also valid in this domain of parameters and, as such
. In this case, the best policy is to uncover the market.
Case 3: follows from Case 2.
.
Case 4: first we show that
,

Now, we show that

Case 5: We know that for
,
. Given that
, whenever
the result holds.
Therefore, as long as , the solutions chosen through welfare maximization coincide with the solutions chosen by the monopolist. ■
Acknowledgments
The author would like to thank the editors, Armin Schmutzler and Burkhard C. Schipper. The author gratefully acknowledges financial support from FCT (Fundação para a Ciência e a Tecnologia). This article is part of project PTDC/EGE-ECO/122507/2010 and of the Strategic Project PEst-OE/EGE/UI0436/2011. This article has benefited from comments and discussion with Robert Becker, Paul Belleflamme, Paolo Colla, Jean Gabszewicz, Luca Lambertini, Luca David Opromolla, and Jacques Thisse. The author gratefully acknowledges their contribution. The usual disclaimer applies.
References
Baake, P., and A.Boom. 2001. “Vertical Product Differentiation, Network Externalities, and Compatibility Decisions.” International Journal of Industrial Organization19:267–84.10.1016/S0167-7187(99)00029-6Suche in Google Scholar
Bensaid, B., and J.Lesne. 1996. “Dynamic Monopoly Pricing with Network Externalities.” International Journal of Industrial Organization14:837–55.10.1016/0167-7187(95)01000-9Suche in Google Scholar
Bental, B., and M.Spiegel. 1995. “Network Competition, Product Quality, and Market Coverage in the Presence of Network Externalities.” The Journal of Industrial Economics43(2):197–208.10.2307/2950481Suche in Google Scholar
Cabral, L., D.Salant, and G.Woroch. 1999. “Monopoly Pricing with Network Externalities.” International Journal of Industrial Organization17:199–214.10.1016/S0167-7187(97)00028-3Suche in Google Scholar
Coase, J. R. 1972. “Durability and Monopoly.” Journal of Law and Economics15:143–9.10.1086/466731Suche in Google Scholar
Constantatos, C., and S.Perrakis. 1997. “Vertical Differentiation: Entry and Market Coverage with Multiproduct Firms.” International Journal of Industrial Organization16:81–103.10.1016/S0167-7187(96)01038-7Suche in Google Scholar
Farrell, J., and G.Saloner. 1985. “Standardization, Compatibility, and Innovation.” The RAND Journal of Economics16(1):70–83.10.2307/2555589Suche in Google Scholar
Fudenberg, D., and J.Tirole. 2000. “Pricing a Network Good to Deter Entry.” The Journal of Industrial Economics48:373–90.10.1111/1467-6451.00129Suche in Google Scholar
Gabszewicz, J. J., and F.Garcia. 2008. “A Note on Expanding Networks and Monopoly Pricing.” Economics Letters98:9–15.10.1016/j.econlet.2007.03.012Suche in Google Scholar
Gabszewicz, J. J., and F.Garcia. 2007a. “Intrinsic Quality Improvements and Network Externalities.” International Journal of Economic Theory3:261–78.10.1111/j.1742-7363.2007.00059.xSuche in Google Scholar
Gabszewicz, J. J., and F.Garcia. 2007b. “Optimal Monopoly Price Paths with Expanding Networks.” Review of Network Economics6:41–8.10.2202/1446-9022.1109Suche in Google Scholar
Gabszewicz, J. J., and J.Thisse. 1980. “Entry (and Exit) in a Differentiated Industry.” Journal of Economic Theory22:327–38.10.1016/0022-0531(80)90046-0Suche in Google Scholar
Gabszewicz, J. J., and J.Thisse. 1979. “Price Competition, Quality and Income Disparities.” Journal of Economic Theory20:340–59.10.1016/0022-0531(79)90041-3Suche in Google Scholar
Garcia, F., and J.Resende. 2011. “Dynamic Games of Network Effects.” Dynamics, Games and Science II2:323–42.10.1007/978-3-642-14788-3_25Suche in Google Scholar
Katz, M., and C.Shapiro. 1992. “Product Introduction with Network Externalities.” The Journal of Industrial Economics40(1):55–83.10.2307/2950627Suche in Google Scholar
Lambertini, L., and R.Orsini. 2010. “R&D for Quality Improvement and Network Externalities.” Networks and Spatial Economics10:113–24.10.1007/s11067-007-9034-7Suche in Google Scholar
Lambertini, L., and R.Orsini. 2003. “Monopoly, Quality and Network Externalities.” Keio Economic Studies40:1–16.Suche in Google Scholar
Shy, O. 1996. “Technology Revolutions in the Presence of Network Externalities.” International Journal of Industrial Organization14:785–800.10.1016/0167-7187(96)01011-9Suche in Google Scholar
- 1
For instance, when Apple introduced the iPad mini, a new port, the Thunderbolt, replaced the port used in the older versions of iPads, rendering the iPad mini incompatible with several components such as speakers, card readers, and so on. While the Thunderbolt is deemed a higher quality technology, according to Apple, “it supports high-resolution displays and high-performance data devices through a single, compact port…(and) sets new standards for speed, flexibility, and simplicity”, there is still the loss in compatibility with the previous generations of iPad users. To overcome this loss, Apple sells separately a converter device.
- 2
Bensaid and Lesne (1996) have the same modelization for the network effect, while Cabral et al. (1999) focus on immediate (or communication) networks. For a detailed characterization of network effects, see Garcia and Resende (2011).
- 3
In the presence of learning-by-doing, late consumers benefit from improved versions of the initial product, which become available once some consumers use the good. When word-of-mouth is observed, consumers are not fully informed of the qualities of the product, and the existence of an installed base reduces the search cost of obtaining this information.
- 4
Sony introduced PlayStation 3, incompatible with the previous versions of its product. Their argument has been that the intrinsic quality of the new console more than compensated consumers for the loss of network effects.
- 5
Introductory pricing consists of an increasing path of prices through time, starting either with a price equal to zero or a low positive price. Note that we assume that the average cost is zero, so the lowest possible price in the first period is zero.
- 6
The intrinsic quality refers to the value of the good that is independent of the network effect.
- 7
Baake and Boom (2001) and Bental and Spiegel (1995) have also combined the use of a vertical product differentiation model with network externalities. However, Baake and Boom (2001) focus on compatibility decisions, without addressing the quality improvement problem. Similarly, Bental and Spiegel (1995) analyze the market coverage issue when network effects are present in a static framework.
- 8
Fudenberg and Tirole (2000) assume the existence of two types of consumers that are, however, homogeneous in their preferences for the technological improvement and differ only in their stand-alone values.
- 9
- 10
We can think that some costless R&D activity has been undertaken, and it resulted in quality improvement.
- 11
This assumption implies that the two goods are sufficiently differentiated, and its importance will become clear below.
- 12
We assume, without loss of generality, that both in period 1 and in period 2 the utility from not buying any unit of any good is zero.
- 13
Notice that in this model, there are two sources of quality differentiation: one exogenous given by the quality differentiation
and one endogenous given by the network effect generated in period 1,
The monopolist is, thus, able to manipulate, in the first period, the endogenous component of good 1’s quality through its pricing choices.
- 14
Constantatos and Perrakis (1997) address the issue of market coverage for a multiproduct monopolist threatened by entry, in the absence of network externalities.
- 15
Notice that.
- 16
It is easily shown that
.
- 17
The computations are available from the author upon request.
©2013 by Walter de Gruyter Berlin / Boston
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Masthead
- Masthead
- Advances
- Dependence and Uniqueness in Bayesian Games
- Monopolistic Signal Provision†
- Multi-task Research and Research Joint Ventures
- Transparent Restrictions on Beliefs and Forward-Induction Reasoning in Games with Asymmetric Information
- A Simple Bargaining Procedure for the Myerson Value
- On the Difference between Social and Private Goods
- Optimal Use of Rewards as Commitment Device When Bidding Is Costly
- Labor Market and Search through Personal Contacts
- Contributions
- Learning, Words and Actions: Experimental Evidence on Coordination-Improving Information
- Are Trust and Reciprocity Related within Individuals?
- Optimal Contracting Model in a Social Environment and Trust-Related Psychological Costs
- Contract Bargaining with a Risk-Averse Agent
- Academia or the Private Sector? Sorting of Agents into Institutions and an Outside Sector
- Topics
- Poverty Orderings with Asymmetric Attributes
- Dictatorial Mechanisms in Constrained Combinatorial Auctions
- When Should a Monopolist Improve Quality in a Network Industry?
- On Partially Honest Nash Implementation in Private Good Economies with Restricted Domains: A Sufficient Condition
- Revenue Comparison in Asymmetric Auctions with Discrete Valuations
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Masthead
- Masthead
- Advances
- Dependence and Uniqueness in Bayesian Games
- Monopolistic Signal Provision†
- Multi-task Research and Research Joint Ventures
- Transparent Restrictions on Beliefs and Forward-Induction Reasoning in Games with Asymmetric Information
- A Simple Bargaining Procedure for the Myerson Value
- On the Difference between Social and Private Goods
- Optimal Use of Rewards as Commitment Device When Bidding Is Costly
- Labor Market and Search through Personal Contacts
- Contributions
- Learning, Words and Actions: Experimental Evidence on Coordination-Improving Information
- Are Trust and Reciprocity Related within Individuals?
- Optimal Contracting Model in a Social Environment and Trust-Related Psychological Costs
- Contract Bargaining with a Risk-Averse Agent
- Academia or the Private Sector? Sorting of Agents into Institutions and an Outside Sector
- Topics
- Poverty Orderings with Asymmetric Attributes
- Dictatorial Mechanisms in Constrained Combinatorial Auctions
- When Should a Monopolist Improve Quality in a Network Industry?
- On Partially Honest Nash Implementation in Private Good Economies with Restricted Domains: A Sufficient Condition
- Revenue Comparison in Asymmetric Auctions with Discrete Valuations