Startseite Carbon Tax with Individuals’ Heterogeneous Environmental Concerns
Artikel
Lizenziert
Nicht lizenziert Erfordert eine Authentifizierung

Carbon Tax with Individuals’ Heterogeneous Environmental Concerns

  • Luca Spinesi ORCID logo EMAIL logo
Veröffentlicht/Copyright: 23. Juni 2025

Abstract

This study analyzes the effects of carbon taxation and environmental awareness on wage inequality and economic growth. The findings reveal that a stricter carbon tax positively correlates with wage inequality and growth. When R&D firms lack complete control over the magnitude of innovation leaps, a tighter carbon tax exacerbates wage inequality while fostering income growth and green innovation. When firms fully determine their innovation leap, a stricter carbon tax reduces wage inequality and slows GDP growth. Changes in the population’s environmental awareness generate different results. When R&D firms lack complete control over innovation leaps, greater ecological awareness increases wage inequality and GDP growth, but only if green products command a higher markup. When firms fully determine innovation leaps, rising ecological awareness induces a U-shaped effect on the skill premium and an inverted U-shaped effect on the share of unskilled workers, while consistently supporting per capita GDP growth.

JEL Classification: I24; O30; O44; Q58

Corresponding author: Luca Spinesi, PhD, Department of Economics, University of Rome Tre, Via Silvio d’Amico 77, 00145, Roma, Italy, E-mail:

  1. Funding sources: This research did not receive any specific grant from funding agencies in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit sectors.

Appendix A

A1

The supply of unskilled and skilled labor is the same as in Dinopoulos and Segerstrom (1999). Each individual chooses to train and become skilled at the beginning of life; the duration of the training period – when the individual cannot work – is exogenously fixed at T > 0. Hence an individual with ability θ decides to train if and only if the following arbitrage condition is satisfied:

(A1.1) t e t s r υ d υ w L s d s < t + T e t s r υ d υ max θ γ , 0 w H d s ,

with 0 < γ < 1/2. Note that an individual with ability θ > γ is postulated able to accumulate human capital θ γ after training, whereas an individual with an ability lower than γ (i.e. θγ) never gets any skill from schooling. Therefore, a skilled worker with ability θ > γ > 0 earns a wage θ γ w H after training from time t + T > 0 onwards and does not earn any wage during her period of training. Since the stock market is assumed to be perfectly efficient, the returns of each financial asset must be equal to the riskless rate of return r, and therefore r t = ρ holds at all dates t. From equation (6) this implies a constant value of the consumption c θ,η , quantity of goods q q , q a , and unskilled and skilled wage w L , w H respectively. Considering eq. (A1.1) with equality, the ability threshold θ 0 is obtained which renders an individual indifferent to becoming skilled or to remaining unskilled for all her life. Hence, the individual will train if and only if her ability is higher than

(A1.2) θ 0 = 1 / e ρ T w L w H + γ = σ w L w H + γ .

where σ 1 / e ρ T . An individual with ability θ > θ 0 will decide to train and will accumulate quantity θ γ of human capital.

The supply of unskilled labor at each time t, L, equals the number of individuals in the population who decide to remain unskilled, i.e. L = θ 0 N = θ 0, and the skilled labor force at each time t is H = 1 θ 0 N = 1 θ 0 . The average skill level of workers who have finished training is 1 γ / 2 + θ 0 γ / 2 = θ 0 + 1 2 γ / 2 . Therefore the supply of skilled labor at each time t, measured in efficiency units, is given by H = θ 0 + 1 2 γ 1 θ 0 1 2 . Q.E.D.

A2

In the main text, a quality ladder model is employed, as exemplified by Grossman and Helpman (1991). Specifically, in the context of non-drastic innovations and Bertrand competition, producers of top-quality services and those offering the highest environmental quality services adopt a limit pricing strategy. With free entry into the production of the second-best quality, profits are expected to be zero in equilibrium.

Considering the aforementioned context, if the subsequent innovation introduces a superior quality services product j + 1 , considering the top environmental quality services 1 a i + 1 , free entry into producing the second-best environmental quality services 1 a i is viable. Therefore, the price-quality ratio of the top quality leader producing quality services j + 1 is p n , ω q λ j + 1 / a i , where λ is the exogenous and constant quality services jump in each variety, whereas the price-quality ratio of the follower producing the second best quality services j of the same variety is m c λ j / a i . The quality services leader has the lowest price-quality ratio whenever p n q λ j + 1 m c λ j , i.e. whenever p n q λ m c , which implies p n q = λ m c . Similarly, if the next innovation introduces a better environmental quality product and, given the top quality services λ j+1, free entry in producing the second best quality services λ j is viable. The price-quality ratio of the top environmental quality leader producing with the i + 1 t h version of a variety is p n a λ j / a i + 1 , whereas the price-quality ratio of the follower producing with the i t h second best environmental quality version of the same variety is m c λ j / a i . The top environmental quality leader has the lowest price-quality ratio whenever p n a λ j / a i + 1 m c λ j / a i , i.e. whenever p n a m c a , which implies p n a = m c a . Therefore, the top quality services leader has the lowest price-quality ratio p n q = λ m c , and the top environmental quality leader has the lowest price-quality ratio p n a = m c a . Q.E.D.

A3

It is assumed that individuals differ in their willingness to pay η for the environmental quality services of the product distributed in 0,1 according to any continuous cumulative distribution function (cdf) F η with usual properties F η > 0 , F 0 = 0 , F 1 = 1 . It is assumed that the individual’s type η and personal ability θ are independently distributed. The individual type η is private information, and its cumulative distribution function across individuals is assumed to be common knowledge. To ensure the generation of strictly positive profit flows, the leading provider of environmental quality should set a price that satisfies the inequality p n a = η m c a > m c , indicating η > η ̄ = a . Consequently, in equilibrium, the demand for all individuals with type η η ̄ = a is zero. Since an individual’s type η is private information and only the top environmental quality product can be sold at a price higher than the marginal cost mc, all individuals with η > η ̄ = a would be willing to pay at most p n a = m c a . Accordingly, the top environmental quality leader should opt for a uniform price p n a = m c a for all individuals with η > η ̄ = a to maximize profits. Therefore, 1 F η ̄ , with η ̄ = a , represents the population share with a strictly positive demand for state-of-the-art environmental quality service products, and F η ̄ indicates the proportion of individuals who demand the state-of-the-art quality service product. Q.E.D.

A4

Here, we explore a scenario where the government provides a fiscal incentive to companies producing environmentally superior products. In this context, the fiscal impact on polluting emissions is determined by τ a ( i max m ) a i max , where m ≥ 0 is a non-negative integer. When m = 0, the fiscal impact on polluting emissions simplifies to τ a i max a i max = τ . For m ≥ 1, the fiscal impact on polluting emissions for the top environmental quality product becomes τ a ( i max m ) a i max = τ a m < τ . Consequently, as ‘m’ increases, the environmental tax on state-of-the-art environmental quality products decreases, emphasizing an inverse relationship between m and the tax rate. Therefore, the profit flows of the patent holder solves the following maximization problem:

(A4.1) M a x q l t p n l + τ a ( i max m ) a i max q l t + m c q l t q l t τ a ( i max m ) a i max ,

where instantaneous profit flows net of the tax burden charged on consumers are considered, l = q , a , e = 1 is used. The maximization problem (A4.1) reduces to:

(A4.2) M a x q l t p n l q l t m c q l t .

As above, the innovation’s target is quality services improvement, and the solution to the maximization problem as in equation (A4.2) implies p n q = λ m c . When the innovation’s target is pollution abatement improvement, the solution to the maximization problem as in equation (A4.2) implies p n a = m c a . Q.E.D.

A5

There is a set Λ = Q , A comprising R&D firms dedicated to patenting improvements in quality services (Q) and environmental quality services (A), respectively, with QA = ∅. The Lebesgue measure is μ q Q 0,1 and μ a A 0,1 , respectively. Consequently, the combined rate of innovation arrival at time t is represented by I t = Q A I f t d f , signifying the collective Poisson arrival rate of innovations generated by all R&D firms. As usual in quality ladder models à la Grossman and Helpman (1991) and Aghion and Howitt (1992), Arrow’s effect is at work. Cozzi (2007) has proved that the standard Schumpeterian growth models are compatible with positive and finite R&D investment by the incumbent monopolist. All the analysis in this paper is compatible with Cozzi’s (2007) findings. Therefore, this model allows for positive, yet non-strategic sighted, R&D investment by the incumbent monopolist.

A6

Let us analyze the incumbent leader producer both of top quality services and top environmental quality services. Let us v l t , with l = q , a , denote the expected discounted profit flows of a successful quality leader at time t producing the best quality services (q) and the best environmental quality services (a), respectively. Since each incumbent firm is targeted by R&D firms that try to discover the next best quality services and the next best environmental services, the shareholder suffers a loss v l t with probability I l t d t = l I f t d f d t , which represents the aggregate Poisson arrival rate of innovation produced by all R&D firms that aim to producing the best quality services (l = q) and the best environmental quality services (l = a), respectively. Thus, the event of no innovation occurs with probability 1 I l t d t . Over a time interval dt, the shareholder of a stock issued by a successful R&D firm receives a dividend π l t d t , and the value of the firm appreciates by d v l t = v ̇ l t d t . Since the stock market is assumed to be perfectly efficient, the expected rate of return of a stock issued by a successful R&D firm must be equal to the riskless rate of return r:

(A6.1) r d t = v ̇ l t v l t 1 I l t d t d t v l t 0 v l t I l t d t + π l t v l t d t .

Dividing by dt, and taking the limits as dt → 0, the following condition for the expected discounted value of the firm producing either the top quality services or pollution abatement services respectively is obtained:

(A6.2) v l t = π l t r + I l t v . l t v l t ,

where v . l t v l t = π ̇ l t π l t = 0 . Hence, the expected discounted value (A6.2) boils down to

(A6.3) v l t = π l t ρ + I l t .

where r = ρ in equilibrium, and ρ > 0. Q.E.D.

Appendix B

The Appendix proves the existence of a unique steady state value for the threshold ability parameter θ 0. In the following equations, the time index t has been eliminated for the sake of simplicity, unless it is strictly necessary for comprehension of the text.

B1

Substituting (18) in (10) and (9), we can write the quantity of each variety targeted by quality service innovations and environmental quality service innovations respectively as:

(B1.1) q q = F η ̄ θ 0 Δ m c w L λ m c + τ ,

and

(B1.2) q a = 1 F η ̄ θ 0 Δ m c w L m c a + τ a m .

The stream of monopoly profit flows accruing to the firm that manufactures the state-of-the-art of quality services and environmental quality services respectively are therefore:

(B1.3) π q = λ 1 m c F η ̄ θ 0 Δ m c w L λ m c + τ ,

and

(B1.4) π a = 1 a 1 m c 1 F η ̄ θ 0 Δ m c w L m c a + τ a m .

Considering (B1.3) and (B1.4), the no-arbitrage condition for the state-of-the-art quality services and the state-of-the-art environmental quality services as in equation (16) can be written respectively as:

(B1.5) λ 1 m c F η ̄ θ 0 Δ m c w L λ m c + τ = b q 1 s σ θ 0 γ ρ + I q ,

and

(B1.6) 1 a 1 m c 1 F η ̄ θ 0 Δ m c w L m c a + τ a m = b a 1 s σ θ 0 γ ρ + I a ,

where w H = σ θ 0 γ has been used.

Solving equations (B1.5) and (B1.6) for I q and I a respectively, the following Poisson arrival rate of innovations are obtained:

(B1.7) I q = θ 0 θ 0 γ F η ̄ λ 1 m c Δ m c w L σ b q 1 s λ m c + τ ρ ,

and

(B1.8) I a = θ 0 θ 0 γ 1 F η ̄ 1 a 1 m c Δ m c w L σ b a 1 s m c a + τ a m ρ ,

Summing equations (B1.7) and (B1.8), the aggregate supply of skilled workers H = b q I q  + b a I a is obtained

(B1.9) H = θ 0 θ 0 γ σ 1 s m c w L m c × F η ̄ λ 1 m c a + τ a m + 1 F η ̄ 1 a 1 λ m c + τ F η ̄ m c a + τ a m + 1 F η ̄ λ m c + τ + 2 b q + b a ρ

where Δ = λ m c + τ m c a + τ a m F η ̄ m c a + τ a m + 1 F η ̄ λ m c + τ has been used. Considering equation (B1.9), the skilled labor market clearing condition (19) can be written as:

(B1.10) θ 0 + 1 2 γ 1 θ 0 1 2 = θ 0 θ 0 γ Ω 2 b q + b a ρ ,

where Ω m c σ 1 s m c w L Λ > 0 , with

Λ F η ̄ λ 1 m c a + τ a m + 1 F η ̄ 1 a 1 λ m c + τ F η ̄ m c a + τ a m + 1 F η ̄ λ m c + τ .

The left hand side of the equation (B1.10) is a strictly concave quadratic polynomial in θ 0 with roots 2 γ 1 < 0 (recall γ 0 , 1 2 ) and 1. The right hand side of the same equation is a strictly convex quadratic polynomial in θ 0 with two real roots, one negative and one positive, where the positive root is:

(B1.11) θ 0 = 1 2 γ + γ 2 + 8 b q + b a ρ Ω γ , 1 ,

if the stated parameter restrictions are satisfied. Therefore, one and only one real and positive steady state solution θ 0 * γ , 1 exists. Q.E.D.

Therefore, equations (19) and (B1.11) imply a constant value of the threshold ability θ 0, that implies a constant value of the aggregate quantities (B1.1) and (B1.2), profits (B1.3) and (B1.4), Poisson arrival rate of innovations (B1.7), (B1.8), and (B1.9), no-arbitrage condition (16), the per capita consumption (18). In this way, the Euler equation is satisfied for r t = ρ . Therefore, the economy is in a steady-state. This also implies that the per capita average instantaneous utility function grows at the same pace as the aggregate innovation, i.e. u ̇ u = g = I q ln λ + I a ln 1 / a . As usual, the individual utility growth rate is also interpreted as the measure of the log-run economic growth rate of the GDP per capita. Q.E.D.

Appendix C

This appendix derives the general equilibrium condition in the case of endogenous markups. Both conditions (25) and (26) are strictly quadratic polynomial in 1 / a and λ respectively, with 1 / a = λ , with two real roots, one negative and one positive, where the positive root is:

(C1) 1 a + = λ + = m c F η + m c τ 2 m c F η + m c F η + m c τ 2 + 8 τ m c F η 2 m c F η ,

that considering F η = 1 F η = 1 2 can be rewritten as

(C2) 1 a + = λ + = 3 2 m c τ + 3 2 m c τ 2 + 4 τ m c m c .

The analysis, which considers the optimal choice of the innovation jump size for the best environmental service 1 / a and the best quality service λ versions of the product – along with the corresponding markups set by firms – remains the same as in the case of an exogenous innovation jump size, except for the characterization of the R&D sector as outlined in the main text. The results from Appendices A and B continue to hold under endogenous firm markups, with the only modification to substitute the variables b ̃ q and b ̃ a to respectively b q and b a in the conditions from (B1.5) to (B1.11). Q.E.D.

Appendix D

D1

This appendix establishes the impact of more stringent ERTs on incentives for human capital accumulation and, consequently, on wage inequality and per capita growth rate. In equation (B1.11), the ERTs τ are expressed in the variable Ω m c σ 1 s m c w L Λ . To analyze the effects of a marginal change in the ERTs τ on the threshold ability parameter θ 0 * , we can focus on the term Λ F η ̄ λ 1 m c a + τ a m + 1 F η ̄ 1 a 1 λ m c + τ F η ̄ m c a + τ a m + 1 F η ̄ λ m c + τ . Using calculus, the following relationships are established:

(D1.1) Λ τ = F η ̄ 1 F η ̄ m c 1 a λ 1 a λ a m F η ̄ m c a + τ a m + 1 F η ̄ λ m c + τ 2 > 0 , for  1 / a > λ , a m . Λ τ = F η ̄ 1 F η ̄ m c 1 a λ 1 a λ a m F η ̄ m c a + τ a m + 1 F η ̄ λ m c + τ 2 > 0 , for  λ > 1 / a  and  λ > 1 / a m + 1 . Λ τ = F η ̄ 1 F η ̄ m c 1 a λ 1 a λ a m F η ̄ m c a + τ a m + 1 F η ̄ λ m c + τ 2 < 0 , for  λ > 1 / a  and  λ < 1 / a m + 1 .

In the first row of condition (D1.1), when 1 / a > λ is satisfied, more stringent ERTs τ lead to Λ τ > 0 . Consequently, increased ERTs τ result in a higher value for Ω, a lower positive root in equation (B1.11), a reduced threshold ability parameter θ 0 * , and an elevated aggregate Poisson arrival rate of innovation (B1.9) along the new equilibrium. The second row of condition (D1.1) determines the same qualitative effects as before when λ > 1 / a and λ > 1 / a m + 1 .

When λ > 1 / a and λ < 1 / a m + 1 is true, based on the third row of condition (D1.1), more stringent ERTs τ lead to Λ τ < 0 . Consequently, increased ERTs τ result in a lower value for Ω, a higher positive root in equation (B1.11), an elevated threshold ability parameter θ 0 * , and a reduced aggregate Poisson arrival rate of innovation (B1.9) along the new equilibrium. Q.E.D.

D2

This appendix establishes the impact of a change in the proportion of environmentally conscious individuals on incentives for human capital accumulation and, consequently, on wage inequality and per capita growth rate. In equation (B1.11), the ERTs τ are expressed in the variable Ω m c σ 1 s m c w L Λ . To analyze the effects of a marginal change in the proportion of environmental conscious individuals on the threshold ability parameter θ 0 * , we can focus on the term Λ F η ̄ λ 1 m c a + τ a m + 1 F η ̄ 1 a 1 λ m c + τ F η ̄ m c a + τ a m + 1 F η ̄ λ m c + τ . Using calculus, the following relationships are established:

(D2.1) Λ F η ̄ = 1 a 1 λ m c + τ m c λ 1 a + τ 1 a m F η ̄ m c a + τ a m + 1 F η ̄ λ m c + τ 2 > 0 , for  λ > 1 / a . Λ F η ̄ = 1 a 1 λ m c + τ m c λ 1 a + τ 1 a m F η ̄ m c a + τ a m + 1 F η ̄ λ m c + τ 2 < 0 , for  1 / a > λ .

In the first row of condition (D2.1), when λ > 1 / a is satisfied, a larger proportion of environmentally conscious individuals, i.e. a lower F η ̄ , leads to a lower Λ, and therefore to a lower value for Ω. Consequently, when λ > 1 / a is satisfied, a larger proportion of environmentally conscious individuals leads to higher positive root in equation (B1.11), an increased threshold ability parameter θ 0 * , and a reduced aggregate Poisson arrival rate of innovation (B1.9) along the new equilibrium.

When 1 / a > λ is true, based on the second row of condition (D2.1), a larger proportion of environmentally conscious individuals, i.e. a lower F η ̄ , leads to a higher Λ, and therefore to a higher value for Ω. Consequently, when 1 / a > λ is satisfied, a larger proportion of environmentally conscious individuals leads to lower positive root in equation (B1.11), a reduced threshold ability parameter θ 0 * , and an elevated aggregate Poisson arrival rate of innovation (B1.9) along the new equilibrium. Q.E.D.

Q.E.D.

Appendix E

This appendix provides an explanation of how the parameter values are calibrated. The baseline calibration value for the threshold ability parameter θ 0 and the aggregate innovation rate I is obtained using equations (19) and (B1.9). To this aim, the variables σ 1 e ρ T , γ = θ 0 σ w H / w L , Ω m c σ 1 s m c w L Λ , are used. Table 2 shows some key parameter values with the respective source used.

Table 2:

Baseline calibration US.

ρ = 0.04 World Development Indicators (2023)
θ 0 = 0.729 Barro and Lee (2013)
δ = w H / w L = 1.73 Goldin and Katz (2007), Neves et al. (2018)
σ = 1.197 Calibrated
γ = 0.0369 Calibrated
1 F η ̄ = 0.173 Sustainable Market Share Index (2023)
mc = 0.787 OECD (2021)
m c w L = 0.6 US Bureau of Labor Statistics (2017)
τ = 0.81 OECD (2021)
s = 0.16 Muresianu and Watson (2021)
ι q  = 0.727 Calibrated
ι a  = 0.286 Calibrated
g = 1.8 % World Development Indicators (2023)

The subjective discount rate ρ is set to the usual value of 0.04 to generate an interest rate of 4 %. This value corresponds to the long-term real interest rate for the period 1992–2020, sourced from the OECD Statistics dataset (annual percentage), and it aligns with the estimated value of Neves et al. (2018). It is worth noting that using a different value of ρ does not affect the qualitative calibration results. The value θ 0 = 0.729 for the US is obtained from Barro and Lee (2013), representing the average educational attainment of the total population aged 25 and over who completed tertiary education during the period 1990–2019. Similarly, the skill premium measure w H = w H / w L = 1.73 is derived from Goldin and Katz (2007), as depicted in Figure 1 and Table A1.8 (also calculated in Neves et al. 2018), and pertains to the average skill premium for the period 1990–2005.

To compute σ 1 e ρ T , a training length T of 4 years is assumed, representing the time an individual spends acquiring skills from tertiary education. These values adhere to standard measures for a developed economy, as outlined in Dinopoulos and Segerstrom (1999), resulting in σ = 1.9722. The parameter γ is subsequently internally calibrated through the equation (A1.2), yielding γ = θ 0 σ w H / w L = 0.0369 . Therefore, the skill premium is calculated according to the equation δ = w H w L = σ θ 0 γ , with w L  = 1 and compared to its actual value as measured by Goldin and Katz (2007) and Neves et al. (2018).

The NYU Stern Center for Sustainable Business (Sustainable Market Share Index 2023) shows that products marketed as sustainable hold a 17.3 % market share in 2022 in the US. Therefore, we set the share of environmental conscious individuals of the US to 1 F η ̄ = 0.173 .

Due to the lack of physical capital in the model set-up, the total cost of firms, i.e. mc, is reduced by the average value (as a percentage of GDP) of Gross Capital Formation (henceforth: GCF). The US GCF average value (as a percentage of GDP) for the period 1990–2019 comes from the OECD (2021) data and is 0.213, so that mc = 1 − 0.213 = 0.787 is obtained. Consistently with the value of all the other variables, the parameters obtained with Shephard’s lemma – i.e. m c w L – should represent the value of labor employment as a percentage of the GDP. The US labor share average value for the period 1990–2016 comes from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (2017) and is m c w L = 0.6 .

To calibrate the tax on pollution, data on all environmentally related taxes (ERTs) from the OECD Statistics dataset for the period 1995–2016 for the US economy are utilized. To be consistent with the other numerical values used for the marginal cost mc in the numerical simulation, the data of ERTs are measured as the percentage of the GDP. The data on ERTs refer to energy products (including vehicle fuels); motor vehicles and transport services; measured or estimated emissions to air and water, ozone depleting substances, certain non-point sources of water pollution, waste management and noise, as well as management of water, land, soil, forests, biodiversity, wildlife and fish stocks. The data have been cross-validated and complemented with Revenue statistics from the OECD Tax Statistics database and official national sources. The ERTs average value for the period 1995–2016 for the US is τ = 0.81 %.

In the U.S., the actual R&D tax credit allows companies to claim credits for spending on qualified research expenditures (QREs). To date, the R&D tax credit has four separate elements: the regular credit, the alternative simplified credit (ASC), the energy research credit, and the basic (or university) research credit The regular R&D credit equals 20 percent of a firm’s QREs above a certain baseline level (Muresianu and Watson 2021; Guenther 2016). The ASC equals 14 percent of a firm’s QREs above half of its average QREs over the past three years, i.e. a moving average. If the firm has no QREs over the previous three years, the credit is 6 percent of QREs for the current year. The actual energy research credit equals 20 percent of a firm’s QREs on payments to nonprofit organizations for the purpose of conducting energy research in the public interest. It can also be claimed on payments to colleges, universities, federal labs, and small firms, provided the taxpayer does not hold a majority stake in the firm performing the research. The value of the R&D subsidy is set s = 0.16 as an average value of regular and alternative simplified credit. Perturbations of this value according to actual data on alternative simplified credit tax do not alter the calibration results.

The labor productivity coefficients ι i q and ι i a in the R&D sector are established at ι i a = 0.286 and ι i q = 0.727 as a benchmark parameter for the US. In the calibration process, the values ι i a = 0.286 and ι i q = 0.727 are determined to ensure that the simulated values of the threshold ability parameter θ 0 and the growth rate of GDP per capita g align with the actual data. Specifically, in the baseline calibration, the calibrated threshold ability value θ 0 is compared to the average educational attainment of the total population aged 25 and over who completed tertiary education during the period 1990–2019, sourced from Barro and Lee (2013). The calibrated growth rate of GDP per capita g is compared with the average GDP per capita growth per annum for the period 1976–2022 (World Development Indicators 2023), i.e. g = 1.8 %.

As per usual in this model setup, the average individual utility growth rate ( u ̇ u ) is interpreted as the measure of the long-run economic growth rate of GDP per capita g (see, for example, Dinopoulos and Segerstrom 1999; Segerstrom 1998). Specifically, u ̇ u = g = I q μ q ln λ + I a μ a 1 a . The weights μ q  = 0.191 and μ a  = 0.191 attached to quality service and environmental quality service innovations, respectively, are calibrated to match the actual data of the growth rate of GDP per capita in the US g = 1.8 %. It is noteworthy that, as anticipated, the values of the weights μ q and μ a coincide because free entry in the R&D sector implies zero-expected profits for quality service and environmental quality services.

Finally, from the optimal conditions (22) and (24), a unique real-valued solution, accompanied by two imaginary solutions, for the optimal innovation leaps, 1 / a and λ, are found. This result persists with different values of the parameters and variables in conditions (22) and (24).

Appendix F: Social Optimum

This appendix delves into the social optimum. To facilitate a consistent comparison between decentralized and centralized economies, we focus on the analysis of the Balanced Growth Path (BGP) equilibrium. The solution for a centralized economy involves two steps (refer to, for example, Grossman and Helpman 1991). Initially, the centralized solution considers the entire population at each point in time, encompassing all individuals of type θ. It first addresses the static allocation of labor in manufacturing, assuming the total number of workers is fixed. Subsequently, the social planner determines the optimal distribution of labor between manufacturing and R&D, while fixing the optimal threshold ability θ 0,sp . Environmental concerns represented by individuals of type η influence the decision-making process related to the innovative effort for quality service and the environmental quality service of the products.

With the temporal aspect omitted, the social planner resolves the static allocation problem:

(F1) M a x 0 1 u θ d θ s.t.  θ 0 = m c w L q ,

where u θ is given in (2), q is the aggregate quantity of the product. The solution to the problem (F1) is trivial and implies

(F2) q = θ 0 m c w L

Let us turn now to the dynamic optimization problem of the social planner. Since the total employment in manufacturing is taken as given in the static problem, the social planner chooses the optimal threshold ability θ 0 to accumulate human capital taking as exogenously given the duration of the training period T. Since the social planner chooses the optimal threshold ability to accumulate human capital θ 0, it determines the aggregate rate of innovation I. Moreover, the expected number of innovations before time t of better quality versions and better environmental quality versions equals J q t = 0 t I q s d s and J a t = 0 t I a s d s , respectively.

These facts together with what we know to be the optimal allocation of resources across varieties, allows us to write the following problem

(F3) M a x 0 e ρ t ln λ J q + ln 1 a J a + ln θ 0 ln m c w L d t .

We maximize (F3) subject to the non-negativity constraint I q  ≥ 0, I a ≥ 0, the resource constraint

(F4) θ 0 + θ 0 + 1 2 γ 1 θ 0 1 2 = m c w L q + b I q + I a ,

the dynamic equations

(F5) J ̇ q = I q ,

(F6) J ̇ a = I a ,

and the inequality constraint for the threshold ability parameter θ 0

(F7) γ θ 0 1 .

Considering equation (F2), the resource constraint (F4) becomes

(F8) θ 0 + 1 2 γ 1 θ 0 1 2 = b q I q + b a I a ,

and the dynamics constraints (F5) and (F6) can be written respectively as:

(F9) J ̇ q = θ 0 + 1 2 γ 1 θ 0 1 2 b q b a b q I a ,

and

(F10) J ̇ a = θ 0 + 1 2 γ 1 θ 0 1 2 b a b q b a I q .

Dropping constant and given terms, the current value Hamiltonian is

(F11) H c v = ln λ J q + ln 1 a J a + ln θ 0 + ξ q θ 0 + 1 2 γ 1 θ 0 1 2 b q b a b q I a + ξ a θ 0 + 1 2 γ 1 θ 0 1 2 b a b q b a I q + ξ 1 θ 0 γ + ξ 2 1 θ 0 ,

where ξ q and ξ a are the costate variables, and ξ 1 and ξ 2 are the Lagrange multipliers for the inequality constraint (F7). Using Pontryagin’s maximum principle we derive the necessary and sufficient conditions for a maximum that apply whenever the non-negativity constraints I q  ≥ 0 and I a ≥ 0 do not bind:

(F12) 1 θ 0 + ξ q b q + ξ a b a γ θ 0 + ξ 1 ξ 2 = 0 ,

(F13) ln λ = ρ ξ q ξ ̇ q ,

(F14) ln 1 a = ρ ξ a ξ ̇ a ,

the transversality conditions lim t e ρ t ξ q J q = 0 and lim t e ρ t ξ a J a = 0 , and the slackness conditions ξ 1 θ 0 γ = 0 , ξ 2 1 θ 0 = 0 . The solutions to (F13) and (F14) together with the appropriate transversality condition require that ξ q = ln λ ρ > 0 for all t, and ξ a = ln 1 a ρ > 0 for all t, where ρ > 0 is assumed. Let us consider the optimal condition (F12). Let us suppose that γ < θ 0 < 1, so that ξ 1 = ξ 2 = 0, and the optimal condition (F12) becomes

(F15) ξ q b q + ξ a b a θ 0 2 + γ ξ q b q + ξ a b a θ 0 1 = 0 .

Let us define Γ = ξ q b q + ξ a b a = 1 ρ ln λ b q + ln 1 a b a > 0 , equation (F15) is a strictly convex quadratic polynomial in θ 0 with two real roots, one negative and one positive, where the positive root is:

(F16) θ 0 , s p = γ 2 + γ + 4 Γ 2 .

Some tedious calculations shows that θ ̂ 0 < 1 always holds, and θ ̂ 0 > γ when 1 > 2γ 2Γ holds. Q.E.D.

When the social planner determines the step size of innovation for the quality services version, denoted by λ, and for the environmental quality services version, given by 1 / a , the current value Hamiltonian is:

(F17) H c v = ln λ J q + ln 1 a J a + ln θ 0 + ξ q θ 0 + 1 2 γ 1 θ 0 1 2 b q b a b q I a + ξ a θ 0 + 1 2 γ 1 θ 0 1 2 b a b q b a I q + ξ 1 θ 0 γ + ξ 2 1 θ 0 + ξ λ λ 1 + ξ 1 / a 1 a 1 ,

where ξ λ and ξ 1 / a are the Lagrange multipliers associated with the inequality constraints λ ≥ 1 and 1 / a 1 , respectively. By applying Pontryagin’s Maximum Principle, the necessary and sufficient conditions for an optimum, assuming that the non-negativity constraints I q  ≥ 0 and I a ≥ 0 are not binding, correspond to the conditions from (F12) to (F14). These are supplemented by the complementary slackness conditions ξ 1 θ 0 γ = 0 , ξ 2 1 θ 0 = 0 . Furthermore, the necessary and sufficient conditions for the step sizes of innovation, λ and 1 / a , to be optimal are given by:

(F18) 1 λ J q ξ q ι q λ 2 θ 0 + 1 2 γ 1 θ 0 1 2 b a I a + ξ a ι q I q + ξ λ = 0 ,

and

(F19) 1 1 / a J a ξ a ι a 1 / a 2 θ 0 + 1 2 γ 1 θ 0 1 2 b q I q + ξ q ι a I a + ξ 1 / a = 0 .

Let us consider the case where λ > 1 and 1 / a > 1 , implying that ξ λ = ξ 1 / a = 0 . Given the dynamic constraints (F9) and (F10), along with the relationships b q = λ ι q and b a = 1 a ι a , the optimality conditions (F18) and (F19) can be rewritten as follows:

(F20) 1 λ J q ξ q λ J ̇ q ξ a ι q J ̇ q = 0 ,

and

(F21) 1 1 / a J a ξ a 1 / a J ̇ a ξ q ι a J ̇ a = 0 .

From conditions (F20) and (F21), we obtain: J ̇ q = 1 ξ q + ξ a λ ι q J q , and J ̇ a = 1 ξ a + ξ q 1 / a ι a J a .

Thus, the transversality conditions lim t e ρ t ξ q J q = 0 and lim t e ρ t ξ a J a = 0 can be rewritten as:

(F22) lim t e ρ t ξ q J q 0 e 1 ξ q + ξ a λ ι q t = 0 , and lim t e ρ t ξ a J a 0 e 1 ξ a + ξ q 1 / a ι a t = 0

As before, the solutions to (F13) and (F14), together with the appropriate transversality conditions, require that ξ q = ln λ ρ > 0 for all t, and ξ a = ln 1 / a ρ > 0 for all t, where ρ > 0 is assumed. Therefore, the transversality conditions can be rewritten as:

(F23) lim t ξ q J q 0 e 1 ln λ + ln 1 / a λ ι q 1 ρ t = 0 , a n d lim t ξ a J a 0 e 1 ln 1 / a + ln λ 1 / a ι a 1 ρ t = 0 .

For these conditions to hold, the following inequalities must be satisfied:

1 ln λ + ln 1 / a λ ι q 1 < 0 and 1 ln 1 / a + ln λ 1 / a ι a 1 < 0 . Given the above, we obtain:

J ̇ q = ρ ln λ + ln 1 / a λ ι q J q , and J ̇ a = ρ ln 1 a + ln λ 1 / a ι a J a , where J ̇ q = I q and J ̇ a = I a . This implies that the innovation rate in a centralized economy reaches its highest possible level when λ → 1 and 1 a 1 from the right. This result, along with the conditions: 1 ln λ + ln 1 / a λ ι q 1 < 0 and 1 ln 1 a + ln λ 1 / a ι a 1 < 0 suggests that a social planner with environmental concerns should set λ → 1 from the right and 1 / a e from the right, where ι q 0,1 and ι a 0,1 .

This policy choice allows the economy to achieve the highest possible growth rate of per capita income while ensuring environmental sustainability.

Given λ → 1 and 1 / a e , the optimal share of the unskilled population in the centralized economy (F16) becomes

(F24) θ 0 , s p = γ 2 + γ + 4 ρ 1 / a ι a 2 .

Q.E.D.

We present the share of unskilled labor and the per capita GDP growth rate of the centralized economy as obtained from numerical simulations. These values are compared with the corresponding figures for the U.S. economy, which closely align with those of the decentralized equilibrium. The simulation results indicate that these two sets of values converge when the market share of eco-friendly products reaches approximately 30 % (i.e. 1 F η = 0.3 ) and the carbon tax remains at its current level in the U.S. economy (τ = 0.81 %). Table 3 summarizes the results of this numerical simulation for the U.S. economy. The values corresponding to the U.S. economy are based on the conditions 1 F η = 0.3 and τ = 0.81 %. The second and third rows of the table report the values of key economic variables for the centralized economy and the U.S. economy, respectively. In each row, the second and third columns present the markups for the standard-quality product (λ) and the eco-friendly product (1/a), while the subsequent two columns report the share of unskilled labor (θ 0) and the per capita GDP growth rate for the centralized economy (g).

Table 3:

Centralized economy and US economy.

λ 1 / a θ 0 g
Centralized economy 1.001 2.718 0.380 2.07
US economy 2.963 2.306 0.769 2.08
  1. The italic value indicates the predicted values of the numerical simulation.

Q.E.D.

References

Acemoglu, D., U. Akcigit, D. Hanley, and W. Kerr. 2016. “The Transition to Clean Technology.” Journal of Political Economy 124 (1): 52–104. https://doi.org/10.1086/684511.Suche in Google Scholar

Aghion, P., and P. Howitt. 1992. “A Model of Growth through Creative Destruction.” Econometrica 60: 323–51. https://doi.org/10.2307/2951599.Suche in Google Scholar

Aghion, P., R. Bénabou, R. Martin, and A. Roulet. 2023. “Environmental Preferences and Technological Choices: Is Market Competition Clean or Dirty?.” The American Economic Review: Insights 5 (1): 1–19. https://doi.org/10.1257/aeri.20210014.Suche in Google Scholar

Allo, M., and M. L. Loureiro. 2014. “The Role of Social Norms on Preferences towards Climate Change Policies: A Meta-Analysis.” Energy Policy 73: 563–74. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2014.04.042.Suche in Google Scholar

Aloi, M., and F. Tournemaine. 2013. “Inequality, Growth and Environmental Quality Trade-Offs in a Model with Human Capital Accumulation.” Canadian Journal of Economics 46: 1123–55. https://doi.org/10.1111/caje.12046.Suche in Google Scholar

Barro, R., and Jong-Wha Lee. 2013. “A New Data Set of Educational Attainment in the World, 1950-2010.” Journal of Development Economics 104: 184–98. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2012.10.001.Suche in Google Scholar

Bretschger, L. 2017. “Climate Policy and Economic Growth.” Resource and Energy Economics 49: 1–15. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2017.03.002.Suche in Google Scholar

Bretschger, L., and S. Smulders. 2012. “Sustainability and Substitution of Exhaustible Natural Resources: How Structural Change Affects Long-Term R&D-Investments.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 36 (4): 536–49.10.1016/j.jedc.2011.11.003Suche in Google Scholar

Brock, W. A., and M. S. Taylor. 2005. “Economic Growth and the Environment: A Review of Theory and Empirics.” In Handbook of Economic Growth, edited by P. Aghion, and S. Durlauf. North-Holland, Amsterdam.10.1016/S1574-0684(05)01028-2Suche in Google Scholar

Busch, C. 2024. “Towards a Theory of Serendipity: A Systematic Review and Conceptualization.” Journal of Management Studies 61 (3): 1110–51. https://doi.org/10.1111/joms.12890.Suche in Google Scholar

Chu, A. C., and S. Pan. 2013. “The Escape-Infringement Effect of Blocking Patents on Innovation and Economic Growth.” Macroeconomic Dynamics 17 (4): 955–69. https://doi.org/10.1017/s136510051100068x.Suche in Google Scholar

Constant, K. 2019. “Environmental Policy and Human Capital Inequality: A Matter of Life and Death.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 97: 134–57. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2018.04.009.Suche in Google Scholar

Cozzi, G. 2007. “The Arrow Effect under Competitive R&D.” The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics Contributions 7: 2.10.2202/1935-1690.1215Suche in Google Scholar

Dechezleprêtre, A., and D. Popp. 2015. Fiscal and Regulatory Instruments for Clean Technology Development in the European Union. CESifo Working Paper No. 5361. http://personal.lse.ac.uk/dechezle/cesifo1_wp5361.pdf.Suche in Google Scholar

Dechezleprêtre, A., R. Martin, and S. Bassi. 2019. “Climate Change Policy, Innovation and Growth.” In Handbook on Green Growth, 217–39. Edward Elgar Publishing.10.4337/9781788110686.00018Suche in Google Scholar

Dienes, C. 2015. “Actions and Intentions to Pay for Climate Change Mitigation: Environmental Concern and the Role of Economic Factors.” Ecological Economics 109: 122–9. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2014.11.012.Suche in Google Scholar

Dinopoulos, E., and P. Segerstrom. 1999. “A Schumpeterian Model of Protection and Relative Wages.” The American Economic Review 89: 450–72. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.89.3.450.Suche in Google Scholar

Elhaffar, G., F. Durif, and L. Dubé. 2020. “Towards Closing the Attitude-Intention-Behavior Gap in Green Consumption: A Narrative Review of the Literature and an Overview of Future Research Directions.” Journal of Cleaner Production 275: 122556. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.122556.Suche in Google Scholar

Frank, P., and C. Brock. 2018. “Bridging the Intention–Behavior Gap Among Organic Grocery Customers: The Crucial Role of Point-of-Sale Information.” Psychology and Marketing 35 (8): 586–602. https://doi.org/10.1002/mar.21108.Suche in Google Scholar

Gillingham, K., R. G. Newell, and W. A. Pizer. 2008. “Modeling Endogenous Technological Change for Climate Policy Analysis.” Energy Economics 30: 2734–53. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2008.03.001.Suche in Google Scholar

Goldin, C., and L. Katz. 2007. “The Race between Education and Technology: The Evolution of US Educational Wage Differentials, 1890–2005.” NBER WP 12984. March.10.3386/w12984Suche in Google Scholar

Grossman, G., and E. Helpman. 1991. Innovation and Growth in the World Economy. Cambridge: MIT Press.Suche in Google Scholar

Guenther, G. 2016. Research Tax Credit: Current Law and Policy Issues for the 114th Congress. Congressional Research Service.Suche in Google Scholar

Hassett, K. A., M. Aparna, and G. E. Metcalf. 2009. “The Incidence of a U.S. Carbon Tax: A Lifetime Regional Analysis.” Energy Journal 30 (2): 157–79.10.5547/ISSN0195-6574-EJ-Vol30-No2-8Suche in Google Scholar

Hassett, K. A., M. Aparna, and G. E. Metcalf. 2010. “Distributional Impacts in a Comprehensive Climate Policy Package.” NBER Working Paper 1610.Suche in Google Scholar

Hémous, D., and M. Olsen. 2021. “Directed Technical Change in Labor and Environmental Economics.” Annual Review of Economics 13: 571–97. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-092120-044327.Suche in Google Scholar

Holdren, J. P. 2006. “The Energy Innovation Imperative: Addressing Oil Dependence, Climate Change, and Other 21st Century Energy Challenges.” Innovations 1: 3–23. https://doi.org/10.1162/itgg.2006.1.2.3.Suche in Google Scholar

Jha, A., P. H. Matthews, and N. Z. Muller. 2019. “Does Environmental Policy Affect Income Inequality? Evidence from the Clean Air Act.” AEA Papers and Proceedings 109: 271–6. https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20191062.Suche in Google Scholar

Joshia, Y., and Z. Rahmanb. 2015. “Factors Affecting Green Purchase Behaviour and Future Research Directions.” International Strategic Management Review 3: 128–43. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ism.2015.04.001.Suche in Google Scholar

Layton, D. F., and G. Brown. 2000. “Heterogeneous Preferences Regarding Global Climate Change.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 82 (4): 616–24. https://doi.org/10.1162/003465300559091.Suche in Google Scholar

Leszczyńska, A. 2014. “Willingness to Pay for Green Products vs Ecological Value System.” International Journal of Synergy and Research 3: 67–77. https://doi.org/10.17951/ijsr.2014.3.0.67.Suche in Google Scholar

Lin, C. Y., and G. Wagner. 2007. “Steady-state Growth in a Hotelling Model of Resource Extraction.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 54: 68–83.10.1016/j.jeem.2006.12.001Suche in Google Scholar

Lu, Y. X. 2022. “Interactive Effects of Monetary Policy and Patent Protection: The Role of Endogenous Innovation Size.” Economic Modelling 113: 105909. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2022.105909.Suche in Google Scholar

Market Research Report. 2021. Transparency Market Research. Albany, NY: Transparency Market Research. https://www.transparencymarketresearch.com/sample/sample.php?flag=B&rep_id=39809.Suche in Google Scholar

Moisander, J. 2007. “Motivational Complexity of Green Consumerism.” International Journal of Consumer Studies 31: 404–9. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1470-6431.2007.00586.x.Suche in Google Scholar

Muresianu, A., and W. Watson. 2021. “Reviewing the Federal Tax Treatment of Research & Development Expenses.” Fiscal Fact no. 759, 1–18.Suche in Google Scholar

Neves, P. C., Ó. Afonso, and T. N. Sequeira. 2018. “Population Growth and the Wage Skill Premium.” Economic Modelling 68: 435–49. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2017.08.019.Suche in Google Scholar

OECD. 2015. Towards Green Growth? Tracking Progress. Paris: OECD Publishing.Suche in Google Scholar

OECD. 2021. “OCED.Stat.” https://stats.oecd.org/.Suche in Google Scholar

Ohlendorf, N., M. Jakob, J. C. Minx, C. Schröder, and J. C. Steckel. 2020. “Distributional Impacts of Carbon Pricing: A Meta-Analysis.” Environmental and Resource Economics 78: 1–42. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-020-00521-1.Suche in Google Scholar

Peretto, P. 2009. “Energy Taxes and Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 57: 269–83. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2008.07.007.Suche in Google Scholar

Peretto, P. 2012. “Resource Abundance, Growth, and Welfare. A Schumpeterian Perspective.” Journal of Development Economics 97: 142–55. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2010.12.001.Suche in Google Scholar

Popp, D. 2010. “Innovation and Climate Policy.” NBER Working Paper 15673.10.3386/w15673Suche in Google Scholar

Popp, D., R. G. Newell, and A. B. Jaffe. 2009. “Energy, the Environment, and Technological Change.” NBER WP 14832.10.3386/w14832Suche in Google Scholar

Prices, H-L. C. 2017. Report of the High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices. Washington: World Bank.Suche in Google Scholar

Rausch, S., G. E. Metcalf, J. M. Reilly, and S. Paltsev. 2010. Distributional Implications of Proposed U.S. Greenhouse Gas Control Measures, Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change Mimeo. MIT, Cambridge, MA.10.3386/w16053Suche in Google Scholar

Romer, P. 1990. “Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of Political Economy 98: S71–S102. https://doi.org/10.1086/261725.Suche in Google Scholar

Sampat, B. N. 2015. Serendipity. New York: Columbia University.10.2139/ssrn.2545515Suche in Google Scholar

Segerstrom, P. S. 1998. “Endogenous Growth without Scale Effects.” The American Economic Review: 1290–310.Suche in Google Scholar

Serret, Y., and N. Johnstone. 2006. The Distributional Effects of Environmental Policy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.10.4337/9781781951132Suche in Google Scholar

Seymore, S. B. 2009. “Serendipity.” NCL Review 88: 185–210.Suche in Google Scholar

Spinesi, L. 2022. “The Environmental Tax: Effects on Inequality and Growth.” Environmental and Resource Economics 82 (3): 529–72. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-022-00662-5.Suche in Google Scholar

Stern, N., and A. Valero. 2021. “Innovation, Growth and the Transition to Net-Zero Emissions.” Research Policy 50 (9): 104293. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2021.104293.Suche in Google Scholar

Sustainable Market Share Index. 2023. NYU Stern Center for Sustainable. New York. https://www.stern.nyu.edu/experience-stern/about/departments-centers-initiatives/centers-of-research/center-sustainable-business/research/csb-sustainable-market-share-index.Suche in Google Scholar

Toman, M. 2012. “Green Growth: An Exploratory Review.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, 6067.10.1596/1813-9450-6067Suche in Google Scholar

U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2017. Montly Labor Review. https://www.bls.gov/opub/mlr/2017/article/estimating-the-us-labor-share.htm.Suche in Google Scholar

Valero, A. 2021. “Education and Economic Growth.” Discussion Paper No. 1764. Centre for Economic Performance.10.4324/9780429202520-20Suche in Google Scholar

van der Ploeg, R., and C. Withagen. 2011. Growth and the Optimal Carbon Tax: When to Switch from Exhaustible Resources to Renewables?. Mimeo.Suche in Google Scholar

Wicker, P., and S. Becken. 2013. “Conscientious vs. Ambivalent Consumers: Do Concerns about Energy Availability and Climate Change Influence Consumer Behaviour?.” Ecological Economics 88: 41–8. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2013.01.005.Suche in Google Scholar

Wijekoon, M., and R. F. Sabri. 2021. “Determinants that Influence Green Product Purchase Intention and Behavior: A Literature Review and Guiding Framework.” Sustainability 13: 6219. https://doi.org/10.3390/su13116219.Suche in Google Scholar

World Development Indicators (WDI). 2023. World Bank. https://databank.worldbank.org/source/world-development-indicators Suche in Google Scholar

Xepapadeas, A. 2005. “Economic Growth and the Environment.” In Handbook of Env Ec, Vol. 3, edited by K. Maler, and J. Vincent. North-Holland, Amsterdam.Suche in Google Scholar

Received: 2025-01-13
Accepted: 2025-06-04
Published Online: 2025-06-23

© 2025 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Heruntergeladen am 21.10.2025 von https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejeap-2025-0022/html
Button zum nach oben scrollen