Abstract
This study analyzes the effects of carbon taxation and environmental awareness on wage inequality and economic growth. The findings reveal that a stricter carbon tax positively correlates with wage inequality and growth. When R&D firms lack complete control over the magnitude of innovation leaps, a tighter carbon tax exacerbates wage inequality while fostering income growth and green innovation. When firms fully determine their innovation leap, a stricter carbon tax reduces wage inequality and slows GDP growth. Changes in the population’s environmental awareness generate different results. When R&D firms lack complete control over innovation leaps, greater ecological awareness increases wage inequality and GDP growth, but only if green products command a higher markup. When firms fully determine innovation leaps, rising ecological awareness induces a U-shaped effect on the skill premium and an inverted U-shaped effect on the share of unskilled workers, while consistently supporting per capita GDP growth.
-
Funding sources: This research did not receive any specific grant from funding agencies in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit sectors.
A1
The supply of unskilled and skilled labor is the same as in Dinopoulos and Segerstrom (1999). Each individual chooses to train and become skilled at the beginning of life; the duration of the training period – when the individual cannot work – is exogenously fixed at T > 0. Hence an individual with ability θ decides to train if and only if the following arbitrage condition is satisfied:
with 0 < γ < 1/2. Note that an individual with ability θ > γ is postulated able to accumulate human capital
where
The supply of unskilled labor at each time t, L, equals the number of individuals in the population who decide to remain unskilled, i.e. L = θ
0
N = θ
0, and the skilled labor force at each time t is
A2
In the main text, a quality ladder model is employed, as exemplified by Grossman and Helpman (1991). Specifically, in the context of non-drastic innovations and Bertrand competition, producers of top-quality services and those offering the highest environmental quality services adopt a limit pricing strategy. With free entry into the production of the second-best quality, profits are expected to be zero in equilibrium.
Considering the aforementioned context, if the subsequent innovation introduces a superior quality services product
A3
It is assumed that individuals differ in their willingness to pay η for the environmental quality services of the product distributed in
A4
Here, we explore a scenario where the government provides a fiscal incentive to companies producing environmentally superior products. In this context, the fiscal impact on polluting emissions is determined by
where instantaneous profit flows net of the tax burden charged on consumers are considered,
As above, the innovation’s target is quality services improvement, and the solution to the maximization problem as in equation (A4.2) implies
A5
There is a set
A6
Let us analyze the incumbent leader producer both of top quality services and top environmental quality services. Let us
Dividing by dt, and taking the limits as dt → 0, the following condition for the expected discounted value of the firm producing either the top quality services or pollution abatement services respectively is obtained:
where
where r = ρ in equilibrium, and ρ > 0. Q.E.D.
The Appendix proves the existence of a unique steady state value for the threshold ability parameter θ 0. In the following equations, the time index t has been eliminated for the sake of simplicity, unless it is strictly necessary for comprehension of the text.
B1
Substituting (18) in (10) and (9), we can write the quantity of each variety targeted by quality service innovations and environmental quality service innovations respectively as:
and
The stream of monopoly profit flows accruing to the firm that manufactures the state-of-the-art of quality services and environmental quality services respectively are therefore:
and
Considering (B1.3) and (B1.4), the no-arbitrage condition for the state-of-the-art quality services and the state-of-the-art environmental quality services as in equation (16) can be written respectively as:
and
where
Solving equations (B1.5) and (B1.6) for I q and I a respectively, the following Poisson arrival rate of innovations are obtained:
and
Summing equations (B1.7) and (B1.8), the aggregate supply of skilled workers H = b q I q + b a I a is obtained
where
where
The left hand side of the equation (B1.10) is a strictly concave quadratic polynomial in θ
0 with roots
if the stated parameter restrictions are satisfied. Therefore, one and only one real and positive steady state solution
Therefore, equations (19) and (B1.11) imply a constant value of the threshold ability θ
0, that implies a constant value of the aggregate quantities (B1.1) and (B1.2), profits (B1.3) and (B1.4), Poisson arrival rate of innovations (B1.7), (B1.8), and (B1.9), no-arbitrage condition (16), the per capita consumption (18). In this way, the Euler equation is satisfied for
This appendix derives the general equilibrium condition in the case of endogenous markups. Both conditions (25) and (26) are strictly quadratic polynomial in
that considering
The analysis, which considers the optimal choice of the innovation jump size for the best environmental service
D1
This appendix establishes the impact of more stringent ERTs on incentives for human capital accumulation and, consequently, on wage inequality and per capita growth rate. In equation (B1.11), the ERTs τ are expressed in the variable
In the first row of condition (D1.1), when
When
D2
This appendix establishes the impact of a change in the proportion of environmentally conscious individuals on incentives for human capital accumulation and, consequently, on wage inequality and per capita growth rate. In equation (B1.11), the ERTs τ are expressed in the variable
In the first row of condition (D2.1), when
When
Q.E.D.
This appendix provides an explanation of how the parameter values are calibrated. The baseline calibration value for the threshold ability parameter θ
0 and the aggregate innovation rate I is obtained using equations (19) and (B1.9). To this aim, the variables
Baseline calibration US.
ρ = 0.04 | World Development Indicators (2023) |
θ 0 = 0.729 | Barro and Lee (2013) |
|
Goldin and Katz (2007), Neves et al. (2018) |
σ = 1.197 | Calibrated |
γ = 0.0369 | Calibrated |
|
Sustainable Market Share Index (2023) |
mc = 0.787 | OECD (2021) |
|
US Bureau of Labor Statistics (2017) |
τ = 0.81 | OECD (2021) |
s = 0.16 | Muresianu and Watson (2021) |
ι q = 0.727 | Calibrated |
ι a = 0.286 | Calibrated |
g = 1.8 % | World Development Indicators (2023) |
The subjective discount rate ρ is set to the usual value of 0.04 to generate an interest rate of 4 %. This value corresponds to the long-term real interest rate for the period 1992–2020, sourced from the OECD Statistics dataset (annual percentage), and it aligns with the estimated value of Neves et al. (2018). It is worth noting that using a different value of ρ does not affect the qualitative calibration results. The value θ
0 = 0.729 for the US is obtained from Barro and Lee (2013), representing the average educational attainment of the total population aged 25 and over who completed tertiary education during the period 1990–2019. Similarly, the skill premium measure
To compute
The NYU Stern Center for Sustainable Business (Sustainable Market Share Index 2023) shows that products marketed as sustainable hold a 17.3 % market share in 2022 in the US. Therefore, we set the share of environmental conscious individuals of the US to
Due to the lack of physical capital in the model set-up, the total cost of firms, i.e. mc, is reduced by the average value (as a percentage of GDP) of Gross Capital Formation (henceforth: GCF). The US GCF average value (as a percentage of GDP) for the period 1990–2019 comes from the OECD (2021) data and is 0.213, so that mc = 1 − 0.213 = 0.787 is obtained. Consistently with the value of all the other variables, the parameters obtained with Shephard’s lemma – i.e.
To calibrate the tax on pollution, data on all environmentally related taxes (ERTs) from the OECD Statistics dataset for the period 1995–2016 for the US economy are utilized. To be consistent with the other numerical values used for the marginal cost mc in the numerical simulation, the data of ERTs are measured as the percentage of the GDP. The data on ERTs refer to energy products (including vehicle fuels); motor vehicles and transport services; measured or estimated emissions to air and water, ozone depleting substances, certain non-point sources of water pollution, waste management and noise, as well as management of water, land, soil, forests, biodiversity, wildlife and fish stocks. The data have been cross-validated and complemented with Revenue statistics from the OECD Tax Statistics database and official national sources. The ERTs average value for the period 1995–2016 for the US is τ = 0.81 %.
In the U.S., the actual R&D tax credit allows companies to claim credits for spending on qualified research expenditures (QREs). To date, the R&D tax credit has four separate elements: the regular credit, the alternative simplified credit (ASC), the energy research credit, and the basic (or university) research credit The regular R&D credit equals 20 percent of a firm’s QREs above a certain baseline level (Muresianu and Watson 2021; Guenther 2016). The ASC equals 14 percent of a firm’s QREs above half of its average QREs over the past three years, i.e. a moving average. If the firm has no QREs over the previous three years, the credit is 6 percent of QREs for the current year. The actual energy research credit equals 20 percent of a firm’s QREs on payments to nonprofit organizations for the purpose of conducting energy research in the public interest. It can also be claimed on payments to colleges, universities, federal labs, and small firms, provided the taxpayer does not hold a majority stake in the firm performing the research. The value of the R&D subsidy is set s = 0.16 as an average value of regular and alternative simplified credit. Perturbations of this value according to actual data on alternative simplified credit tax do not alter the calibration results.
The labor productivity coefficients
As per usual in this model setup, the average individual utility growth rate
Finally, from the optimal conditions (22) and (24), a unique real-valued solution, accompanied by two imaginary solutions, for the optimal innovation leaps,
Appendix F: Social Optimum
This appendix delves into the social optimum. To facilitate a consistent comparison between decentralized and centralized economies, we focus on the analysis of the Balanced Growth Path (BGP) equilibrium. The solution for a centralized economy involves two steps (refer to, for example, Grossman and Helpman 1991). Initially, the centralized solution considers the entire population at each point in time, encompassing all individuals of type θ. It first addresses the static allocation of labor in manufacturing, assuming the total number of workers is fixed. Subsequently, the social planner determines the optimal distribution of labor between manufacturing and R&D, while fixing the optimal threshold ability θ 0,sp . Environmental concerns represented by individuals of type η influence the decision-making process related to the innovative effort for quality service and the environmental quality service of the products.
With the temporal aspect omitted, the social planner resolves the static allocation problem:
where u θ is given in (2), q is the aggregate quantity of the product. The solution to the problem (F1) is trivial and implies
Let us turn now to the dynamic optimization problem of the social planner. Since the total employment in manufacturing is taken as given in the static problem, the social planner chooses the optimal threshold ability θ
0 to accumulate human capital taking as exogenously given the duration of the training period T. Since the social planner chooses the optimal threshold ability to accumulate human capital θ
0, it determines the aggregate rate of innovation I. Moreover, the expected number of innovations before time t of better quality versions and better environmental quality versions equals
These facts together with what we know to be the optimal allocation of resources across varieties, allows us to write the following problem
We maximize (F3) subject to the non-negativity constraint I q ≥ 0, I a ≥ 0, the resource constraint
the dynamic equations
and the inequality constraint for the threshold ability parameter θ 0
Considering equation (F2), the resource constraint (F4) becomes
and the dynamics constraints (F5) and (F6) can be written respectively as:
and
Dropping constant and given terms, the current value Hamiltonian is
where ξ q and ξ a are the costate variables, and ξ 1 and ξ 2 are the Lagrange multipliers for the inequality constraint (F7). Using Pontryagin’s maximum principle we derive the necessary and sufficient conditions for a maximum that apply whenever the non-negativity constraints I q ≥ 0 and I a ≥ 0 do not bind:
the transversality conditions
Let us define
Some tedious calculations shows that
When the social planner determines the step size of innovation for the quality services version, denoted by λ, and for the environmental quality services version, given by
where ξ
λ
and
and
Let us consider the case where λ > 1 and
and
From conditions (F20) and (F21), we obtain:
Thus, the transversality conditions
As before, the solutions to (F13) and (F14), together with the appropriate transversality conditions, require that
For these conditions to hold, the following inequalities must be satisfied:
This policy choice allows the economy to achieve the highest possible growth rate of per capita income while ensuring environmental sustainability.
Given λ → 1 and
Q.E.D.
We present the share of unskilled labor and the per capita GDP growth rate of the centralized economy as obtained from numerical simulations. These values are compared with the corresponding figures for the U.S. economy, which closely align with those of the decentralized equilibrium. The simulation results indicate that these two sets of values converge when the market share of eco-friendly products reaches approximately 30 % (i.e.
Centralized economy and US economy.
λ |
|
θ 0 | g | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Centralized economy | 1.001 | 2.718 | 0.380 | 2.07 |
US economy | 2.963 | 2.306 | 0.769 | 2.08 |
-
The italic value indicates the predicted values of the numerical simulation.
Q.E.D.
References
Acemoglu, D., U. Akcigit, D. Hanley, and W. Kerr. 2016. “The Transition to Clean Technology.” Journal of Political Economy 124 (1): 52–104. https://doi.org/10.1086/684511.Suche in Google Scholar
Aghion, P., and P. Howitt. 1992. “A Model of Growth through Creative Destruction.” Econometrica 60: 323–51. https://doi.org/10.2307/2951599.Suche in Google Scholar
Aghion, P., R. Bénabou, R. Martin, and A. Roulet. 2023. “Environmental Preferences and Technological Choices: Is Market Competition Clean or Dirty?.” The American Economic Review: Insights 5 (1): 1–19. https://doi.org/10.1257/aeri.20210014.Suche in Google Scholar
Allo, M., and M. L. Loureiro. 2014. “The Role of Social Norms on Preferences towards Climate Change Policies: A Meta-Analysis.” Energy Policy 73: 563–74. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2014.04.042.Suche in Google Scholar
Aloi, M., and F. Tournemaine. 2013. “Inequality, Growth and Environmental Quality Trade-Offs in a Model with Human Capital Accumulation.” Canadian Journal of Economics 46: 1123–55. https://doi.org/10.1111/caje.12046.Suche in Google Scholar
Barro, R., and Jong-Wha Lee. 2013. “A New Data Set of Educational Attainment in the World, 1950-2010.” Journal of Development Economics 104: 184–98. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2012.10.001.Suche in Google Scholar
Bretschger, L. 2017. “Climate Policy and Economic Growth.” Resource and Energy Economics 49: 1–15. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2017.03.002.Suche in Google Scholar
Bretschger, L., and S. Smulders. 2012. “Sustainability and Substitution of Exhaustible Natural Resources: How Structural Change Affects Long-Term R&D-Investments.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 36 (4): 536–49.10.1016/j.jedc.2011.11.003Suche in Google Scholar
Brock, W. A., and M. S. Taylor. 2005. “Economic Growth and the Environment: A Review of Theory and Empirics.” In Handbook of Economic Growth, edited by P. Aghion, and S. Durlauf. North-Holland, Amsterdam.10.1016/S1574-0684(05)01028-2Suche in Google Scholar
Busch, C. 2024. “Towards a Theory of Serendipity: A Systematic Review and Conceptualization.” Journal of Management Studies 61 (3): 1110–51. https://doi.org/10.1111/joms.12890.Suche in Google Scholar
Chu, A. C., and S. Pan. 2013. “The Escape-Infringement Effect of Blocking Patents on Innovation and Economic Growth.” Macroeconomic Dynamics 17 (4): 955–69. https://doi.org/10.1017/s136510051100068x.Suche in Google Scholar
Constant, K. 2019. “Environmental Policy and Human Capital Inequality: A Matter of Life and Death.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 97: 134–57. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2018.04.009.Suche in Google Scholar
Cozzi, G. 2007. “The Arrow Effect under Competitive R&D.” The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics Contributions 7: 2.10.2202/1935-1690.1215Suche in Google Scholar
Dechezleprêtre, A., and D. Popp. 2015. Fiscal and Regulatory Instruments for Clean Technology Development in the European Union. CESifo Working Paper No. 5361. http://personal.lse.ac.uk/dechezle/cesifo1_wp5361.pdf.Suche in Google Scholar
Dechezleprêtre, A., R. Martin, and S. Bassi. 2019. “Climate Change Policy, Innovation and Growth.” In Handbook on Green Growth, 217–39. Edward Elgar Publishing.10.4337/9781788110686.00018Suche in Google Scholar
Dienes, C. 2015. “Actions and Intentions to Pay for Climate Change Mitigation: Environmental Concern and the Role of Economic Factors.” Ecological Economics 109: 122–9. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2014.11.012.Suche in Google Scholar
Dinopoulos, E., and P. Segerstrom. 1999. “A Schumpeterian Model of Protection and Relative Wages.” The American Economic Review 89: 450–72. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.89.3.450.Suche in Google Scholar
Elhaffar, G., F. Durif, and L. Dubé. 2020. “Towards Closing the Attitude-Intention-Behavior Gap in Green Consumption: A Narrative Review of the Literature and an Overview of Future Research Directions.” Journal of Cleaner Production 275: 122556. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.122556.Suche in Google Scholar
Frank, P., and C. Brock. 2018. “Bridging the Intention–Behavior Gap Among Organic Grocery Customers: The Crucial Role of Point-of-Sale Information.” Psychology and Marketing 35 (8): 586–602. https://doi.org/10.1002/mar.21108.Suche in Google Scholar
Gillingham, K., R. G. Newell, and W. A. Pizer. 2008. “Modeling Endogenous Technological Change for Climate Policy Analysis.” Energy Economics 30: 2734–53. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2008.03.001.Suche in Google Scholar
Goldin, C., and L. Katz. 2007. “The Race between Education and Technology: The Evolution of US Educational Wage Differentials, 1890–2005.” NBER WP 12984. March.10.3386/w12984Suche in Google Scholar
Grossman, G., and E. Helpman. 1991. Innovation and Growth in the World Economy. Cambridge: MIT Press.Suche in Google Scholar
Guenther, G. 2016. Research Tax Credit: Current Law and Policy Issues for the 114th Congress. Congressional Research Service.Suche in Google Scholar
Hassett, K. A., M. Aparna, and G. E. Metcalf. 2009. “The Incidence of a U.S. Carbon Tax: A Lifetime Regional Analysis.” Energy Journal 30 (2): 157–79.10.5547/ISSN0195-6574-EJ-Vol30-No2-8Suche in Google Scholar
Hassett, K. A., M. Aparna, and G. E. Metcalf. 2010. “Distributional Impacts in a Comprehensive Climate Policy Package.” NBER Working Paper 1610.Suche in Google Scholar
Hémous, D., and M. Olsen. 2021. “Directed Technical Change in Labor and Environmental Economics.” Annual Review of Economics 13: 571–97. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-092120-044327.Suche in Google Scholar
Holdren, J. P. 2006. “The Energy Innovation Imperative: Addressing Oil Dependence, Climate Change, and Other 21st Century Energy Challenges.” Innovations 1: 3–23. https://doi.org/10.1162/itgg.2006.1.2.3.Suche in Google Scholar
Jha, A., P. H. Matthews, and N. Z. Muller. 2019. “Does Environmental Policy Affect Income Inequality? Evidence from the Clean Air Act.” AEA Papers and Proceedings 109: 271–6. https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20191062.Suche in Google Scholar
Joshia, Y., and Z. Rahmanb. 2015. “Factors Affecting Green Purchase Behaviour and Future Research Directions.” International Strategic Management Review 3: 128–43. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ism.2015.04.001.Suche in Google Scholar
Layton, D. F., and G. Brown. 2000. “Heterogeneous Preferences Regarding Global Climate Change.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 82 (4): 616–24. https://doi.org/10.1162/003465300559091.Suche in Google Scholar
Leszczyńska, A. 2014. “Willingness to Pay for Green Products vs Ecological Value System.” International Journal of Synergy and Research 3: 67–77. https://doi.org/10.17951/ijsr.2014.3.0.67.Suche in Google Scholar
Lin, C. Y., and G. Wagner. 2007. “Steady-state Growth in a Hotelling Model of Resource Extraction.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 54: 68–83.10.1016/j.jeem.2006.12.001Suche in Google Scholar
Lu, Y. X. 2022. “Interactive Effects of Monetary Policy and Patent Protection: The Role of Endogenous Innovation Size.” Economic Modelling 113: 105909. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2022.105909.Suche in Google Scholar
Market Research Report. 2021. Transparency Market Research. Albany, NY: Transparency Market Research. https://www.transparencymarketresearch.com/sample/sample.php?flag=B&rep_id=39809.Suche in Google Scholar
Moisander, J. 2007. “Motivational Complexity of Green Consumerism.” International Journal of Consumer Studies 31: 404–9. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1470-6431.2007.00586.x.Suche in Google Scholar
Muresianu, A., and W. Watson. 2021. “Reviewing the Federal Tax Treatment of Research & Development Expenses.” Fiscal Fact no. 759, 1–18.Suche in Google Scholar
Neves, P. C., Ó. Afonso, and T. N. Sequeira. 2018. “Population Growth and the Wage Skill Premium.” Economic Modelling 68: 435–49. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2017.08.019.Suche in Google Scholar
OECD. 2015. Towards Green Growth? Tracking Progress. Paris: OECD Publishing.Suche in Google Scholar
OECD. 2021. “OCED.Stat.” https://stats.oecd.org/.Suche in Google Scholar
Ohlendorf, N., M. Jakob, J. C. Minx, C. Schröder, and J. C. Steckel. 2020. “Distributional Impacts of Carbon Pricing: A Meta-Analysis.” Environmental and Resource Economics 78: 1–42. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-020-00521-1.Suche in Google Scholar
Peretto, P. 2009. “Energy Taxes and Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 57: 269–83. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2008.07.007.Suche in Google Scholar
Peretto, P. 2012. “Resource Abundance, Growth, and Welfare. A Schumpeterian Perspective.” Journal of Development Economics 97: 142–55. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2010.12.001.Suche in Google Scholar
Popp, D. 2010. “Innovation and Climate Policy.” NBER Working Paper 15673.10.3386/w15673Suche in Google Scholar
Popp, D., R. G. Newell, and A. B. Jaffe. 2009. “Energy, the Environment, and Technological Change.” NBER WP 14832.10.3386/w14832Suche in Google Scholar
Prices, H-L. C. 2017. Report of the High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices. Washington: World Bank.Suche in Google Scholar
Rausch, S., G. E. Metcalf, J. M. Reilly, and S. Paltsev. 2010. Distributional Implications of Proposed U.S. Greenhouse Gas Control Measures, Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change Mimeo. MIT, Cambridge, MA.10.3386/w16053Suche in Google Scholar
Romer, P. 1990. “Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of Political Economy 98: S71–S102. https://doi.org/10.1086/261725.Suche in Google Scholar
Sampat, B. N. 2015. Serendipity. New York: Columbia University.10.2139/ssrn.2545515Suche in Google Scholar
Segerstrom, P. S. 1998. “Endogenous Growth without Scale Effects.” The American Economic Review: 1290–310.Suche in Google Scholar
Serret, Y., and N. Johnstone. 2006. The Distributional Effects of Environmental Policy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.10.4337/9781781951132Suche in Google Scholar
Seymore, S. B. 2009. “Serendipity.” NCL Review 88: 185–210.Suche in Google Scholar
Spinesi, L. 2022. “The Environmental Tax: Effects on Inequality and Growth.” Environmental and Resource Economics 82 (3): 529–72. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-022-00662-5.Suche in Google Scholar
Stern, N., and A. Valero. 2021. “Innovation, Growth and the Transition to Net-Zero Emissions.” Research Policy 50 (9): 104293. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2021.104293.Suche in Google Scholar
Sustainable Market Share Index. 2023. NYU Stern Center for Sustainable. New York. https://www.stern.nyu.edu/experience-stern/about/departments-centers-initiatives/centers-of-research/center-sustainable-business/research/csb-sustainable-market-share-index.Suche in Google Scholar
Toman, M. 2012. “Green Growth: An Exploratory Review.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, 6067.10.1596/1813-9450-6067Suche in Google Scholar
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2017. Montly Labor Review. https://www.bls.gov/opub/mlr/2017/article/estimating-the-us-labor-share.htm.Suche in Google Scholar
Valero, A. 2021. “Education and Economic Growth.” Discussion Paper No. 1764. Centre for Economic Performance.10.4324/9780429202520-20Suche in Google Scholar
van der Ploeg, R., and C. Withagen. 2011. Growth and the Optimal Carbon Tax: When to Switch from Exhaustible Resources to Renewables?. Mimeo.Suche in Google Scholar
Wicker, P., and S. Becken. 2013. “Conscientious vs. Ambivalent Consumers: Do Concerns about Energy Availability and Climate Change Influence Consumer Behaviour?.” Ecological Economics 88: 41–8. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2013.01.005.Suche in Google Scholar
Wijekoon, M., and R. F. Sabri. 2021. “Determinants that Influence Green Product Purchase Intention and Behavior: A Literature Review and Guiding Framework.” Sustainability 13: 6219. https://doi.org/10.3390/su13116219.Suche in Google Scholar
World Development Indicators (WDI). 2023. World Bank. https://databank.worldbank.org/source/world-development-indicators Suche in Google Scholar
Xepapadeas, A. 2005. “Economic Growth and the Environment.” In Handbook of Env Ec, Vol. 3, edited by K. Maler, and J. Vincent. North-Holland, Amsterdam.Suche in Google Scholar
© 2025 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Frontmatter
- Research Articles
- Fair Choices During COVID-19: Firms’ Altruism and Inequality Aversion in Managing a Large Short-Time Work Scheme
- Inequality in Health Status During the COVID-19 in the UK: Does the Impact of the Second Lockdown Policy Matter?
- The Political Timing of Tax Policy: Evidence from U.S. States
- Is it a Matter of Skills? High School Choices and the Gender Gap in STEM
- Patent Licensing and Litigation
- Class Size, Student Disruption, and Academic Achievement
- Political Orientation and Policy Compliance: Evidence from COVID-19 Mobility Patterns in Korea
- Social Efficiency of Free Entry in a Vertically Related Industry with Cost and Technology Asymmetry
- Carbon Tax with Individuals’ Heterogeneous Environmental Concerns
- Equitable Redistribution and Inefficiency under Credit Rationing
- Letters
- Psychological Well-Being of Only Children: Evidence from the One-Child Policy
- Peer Effects in Child Work Decisions: Evidence from PROGRESA Cash Transfer Program
- Right Time to Focus? Time of Day and Cognitive Performance
- Employee Dissatisfaction and Intentions to Quit: New Evidence and Policy Recommendations
- On the Stability of Common Ownership Arrangements
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Frontmatter
- Research Articles
- Fair Choices During COVID-19: Firms’ Altruism and Inequality Aversion in Managing a Large Short-Time Work Scheme
- Inequality in Health Status During the COVID-19 in the UK: Does the Impact of the Second Lockdown Policy Matter?
- The Political Timing of Tax Policy: Evidence from U.S. States
- Is it a Matter of Skills? High School Choices and the Gender Gap in STEM
- Patent Licensing and Litigation
- Class Size, Student Disruption, and Academic Achievement
- Political Orientation and Policy Compliance: Evidence from COVID-19 Mobility Patterns in Korea
- Social Efficiency of Free Entry in a Vertically Related Industry with Cost and Technology Asymmetry
- Carbon Tax with Individuals’ Heterogeneous Environmental Concerns
- Equitable Redistribution and Inefficiency under Credit Rationing
- Letters
- Psychological Well-Being of Only Children: Evidence from the One-Child Policy
- Peer Effects in Child Work Decisions: Evidence from PROGRESA Cash Transfer Program
- Right Time to Focus? Time of Day and Cognitive Performance
- Employee Dissatisfaction and Intentions to Quit: New Evidence and Policy Recommendations
- On the Stability of Common Ownership Arrangements