Abstract
The aim of this article is to determine whether increases in private and public indebtedness affect capital misallocation, which is measured as the dispersion in capital returns across firms in different industries. This aim is achieved by using a dataset containing industry-level data for 18 European countries and controlling for macroeconomic indicators representing potential determinants of capital misallocation. The within-country variation across industries regarding indicators such as external finance dependence, technological intensity, credit constraints and competitive structure is used to find that private debt accumulation disproportionately increases capital misallocation in industries with higher financial dependence, higher R&D intensity, a larger share of credit-constrained firms and a lower level of competition. On the other hand, there are no significant and robust effects of public debt on capital misallocation found within the country–sector pairs in the sample.
1 Introduction
Finance, especially debt finance, is an extremely important part of modern economies. Debt allows firms to realize important investment projects and governments to finance necessary expenditures. On the other hand, persistent debt build-ups can make financial markets and the economy vulnerable to crises and may lead to governments defaulting on liabilities. Economists are aware that the likelihood and severity of financial crises tend to increase once economies reach a certain level of indebtedness (see Reinhart & Rogoff, 2009). Recent research conducted on the nonlinear effects of debt on economic growth suggests that high levels of private and public debt can undermine aggregate productivity (Anderson & Raissi, 2022; Cecchetti & Kharroubi, 2019; Salotti & Trecroci, 2016) and impair efficient reallocation of resources (Borio et al., 2015; Pannella, 2020).
The presence of distortions or financial frictions is argued to prevent the equalization of marginal returns to capital and labour across firms, thus leading to resource misallocation (Gilchrist et al., 2013; Hsieh & Klenow, 2009; Moll, 2014; Restuccia & Rogerson, 2017). The literature has identified many sources of these distortions and frictions, but this article argues that increased credit expansion and debt accumulation in the economy may exacerbate existing capital misallocation. The benefits of credit growth may accrue disproportionately to large and/or well-established firms having real estate assets as collateral or long-term relationships with banks, and hence stronger bargaining power. This is particularly supported by research regarding financial constraints of small- and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs).
Research suggests that SMEs are more dependent on external finance but face greater financing constraints and credit rationing (Kay et al., 2014). Although SMEs account for nearly 60% of value added and 70% of employment in the euro zone (Bremus, 2015), supply-side constraints to SME finance are prevalent: many SMEs face difficulties obtaining bank loans because they lack sufficient immovable collateral that banks prefer over movable assets such as machinery and receivables or because their opaque nature leads to information asymmetry with banks (Abraham & Schmukler, 2017; Bremus, 2015). In addition, although large firms are likely to have been established longer in the market, SMEs are more heterogeneous regarding age, size, ownership, lending relationships with banks, industries, and regions in which they operate (Banerjee, 2014; Casey & O’Toole, 2014; D’Ignazio & Menon, 2020; Jackowicz & Kozłowski, 2019; Kumar, 2017). All these imply that industries with more SMEs and fewer large firms would experience a higher increase in the spread of marginal productivity of capital across firms when banks extend additional credit to the economy (assuming this credit is used for investment).
This article’s goal is to investigate how private and public debt at the aggregate level influence capital misallocation across firms in different industries over time, which involves analysing an unbalanced panel of 18 European countries from 1999 to 2016. The measure used for capital misallocation is the dispersion in capital returns across firms within different industries as per Hsieh and Klenow (2009). The data come from the Competitiveness Research Network (CompNet) database, which is compiled by institutions such as the European Central Bank, the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, the Halle Institute for Economic Research, and the Tinbergen Institute. This micro-based dataset provides data at the country and country-sector levels but not at the firm level, which results in a lack of information concerning size, age, and other firm-level characteristics. Therefore, as proxies for industry-level variation in demand for credit and competitive structure, this study uses the Rajan and Zingales’ (1998) measure of sectoral financial dependence (based on Compustat data) and the indicator of technological intensity (obtained from Eurostat), as well as other sector-level indicators provided by CompNet such as average credit constraints, dispersion of credit constraints, average markups, and the skewness of industry TFP distribution.
To the best of my knowledge, this article is the first to analyse the effects of aggregate leverage on industry-level input misallocation, providing novel insights into how debt accumulation affects the efficiency of resource allocation in the economy. Some studies have analysed the role of financial frictions (Buera et al., 2011; Midrigan & Xu, 2014) or the overall financial development (Marconi & Upper, 2017) in generating capital misallocation. Others have studied the impacts of firm-level and aggregate leverage on within-firm productivity (Gomis & Khatiwada, 2017). Perhaps most closely related to my work conceptually is León-Ledesma and Christopoulos (2016), who analyse firm-level data from 45 economies (primarily developing countries) and demonstrate that access-to-finance obstacles and private bank credit increase the dispersion of factor market and size distortions across firms. The present work differs by focusing specifically on how the aggregate leverage of private and public sectors affects within-sector capital allocation across firms, an important economic phenomenon that deserves direct investigation.
Findings of this article suggest that rising private debt increases the dispersion of marginal returns to capital disproportionately more in sectors that are characterized by high financial dependence, high R&D intensity, more credit constraints, and low competition. The results indicate that private debt accumulation exacerbates pre-existing financial frictions, altering capital allocation toward firms with easier credit access rather than higher productivity – a distortion with potential implications for allocative efficiency and investment dynamics. On the contrary, I find that public debt has no robust effect on capital misallocation in this European sample, suggesting that private and public debt may be governed by different mechanisms. Being the first study, to my knowledge, to connect aggregate debt dynamics to within-industry inefficiencies in capital allocation, this work bridges existing gaps between macro-finance and misallocation literatures and provides evidence that curtailing excessive private debt – particularly corporate debt – could mitigate misallocation of resources and improve resilience of the economy.
The remainder of this article proceeds as follows: Section 2 summarizes the literature on the relationship between private and public debt, growth, and aggregate productivity, as well as emerging research on debt’s relationship with capital allocation efficiency, which together form the basis of developing my hypothesis. Section 3 presents data, preliminary empirical motivation, and the empirical methodology. Section 4 presents the results of the empirical analysis regarding the effects of private and public debt on capital misallocation, and finally, Section 5 concludes the study.
2 Literature Review and Hypothesis Development
2.1 The Accumulation of Debt and Economic Outcomes
Over the last three decades, extensive research has been conducted on the relationship between private sector debt and economic growth. Earlier studies found positive effects of finance on growth (Beck et al., 2000; King & Levine, 1993; Levine et al., 2000; Rajan & Zingales, 1998). Huang and Lin (2009) find that financial intermediation has stronger growth-enhancing effects in low-income countries than in high-income countries; however, more recent studies have indicated that the effect of finance on growth is unlikely to be strictly positive. Shen and Lee (2006) show that the relationship between bank development and growth has an inverse U-shape in middle-income countries. Rousseau and Wachtel (2011) find that the positive finance–growth relationship, which was estimated using data from the 1960s to the 1980s, has disappeared over subsequent decades. Law and Singh (2014) estimate a threshold value of around 90–95% of GDP, beyond which financial development indicators (i.e., private sector credit and liquid liabilities) negatively affect growth. Arcand et al. (2015) find that financial depth has a negative effect on output growth when private sector credit reaches 100% of GDP. Mian et al. (2017) show that an increase in the household debt-to-GDP ratio predicts a lower subsequent GDP growth. Kobayashi and Shirai (2018) construct a theoretical model to show that excessive debt build-up in the private sector can depress economic growth through the persistent productive inefficiency of debt-ridden firms. Other studies document the detrimental effects of private credit growth on the financial stability and intensity of subsequent recessions (Jordà et al., 2011, 2013, 2015a; Mian & Sufi, 2010; Schularick & Taylor, 2012).
In addition to the growth effects of private sector debt, studies have analysed the relationship between public debt and economic growth since the publication of Reinhart and Rogoff’s (2009) seminal book. Reinhart and Rogoff (2010) find that in a sample of both advanced and emerging economies, public debt-to-GDP ratios as high as 90% and above are associated with significantly lower growth outcomes. While the results of Reinhart and Rogoff (2010) were famously criticized (Herndon et al., 2014), they also find support in other studies. For example, the findings of Cecchetti et al. (2011) suggest that in a sample of 18 OECD countries, increases in public debt beyond 85% of GDP have a negative effect on growth. Other articles confirming the nonlinear effects of public debt on growth include Baum et al. (2013), Checherita-Westphal and Rother (2012), Karadam (2018), Woo and Kumar (2015), and Yang and Su (2018). Chudik et al. (2017) find significant negative effects of public debt build-up on economic growth in the long run, although they find no evidence for a universally applicable threshold effect of public debt on growth. Panizza and Presbitero (2014), however, find no evidence for a causal effect of public debt on growth once corrected for endogeneity.
Other literature has focused on the joint dynamics of public and private debt. Reinhart and Rogoff (2011) document numerous episodes where surges in private debt before crises and surges in public debt after crises occur across advanced and emerging market economies. Reinhart et al. (2012) argue that there is a complex interaction between the different types of debt overhang and that the lines between public and private debt often become blurred in a crisis. After examining the co-evolution of public and private sector debt in 17 advanced countries over a 140-year period (1870–2011), Jordà et al. (2015b) show that financial stability risks primarily originate in the private rather than public sector; high public debt exacerbates the effects of private sector deleveraging after financial crises and hence contributes to deepening recessions following a credit bust. Research by Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) confirms these findings by showing that, in many crises over the past century, corporate defaults were precursors to government defaults or re-schedulings as governments tended to shoulder private sector debts. Figure 1 also shows that private debt in 18 EU countries had been rising for years preceding the 2007–2008 global financial crisis, while public debt has risen following the crisis. In a recent study using data from 29 OECD countries over 1995–2014, Caner et al. (2021) find that public and private debt stimulate economic growth at low levels of indebtedness but the interaction between these two types of debt decreases growth when the aggregate debt-to-GDP ratio reaches threshold level of 220%.

Time series of private and public debt (as % of GDP), average for 18 European countries. (Source: Author’s calculations based on IMF data).
Besides investigating the effects of debt on output growth, more recent research focuses on how debt accumulation impacts productivity and allocative efficiency. In one of the earlier articles, Kim and Maksimovic (1990) apply an econometric methodology for estimating the agency costs of debt to the air transport industry to show that high debt levels are associated with firm-level inefficiency and the fall in industry-wide productivity growth. Borio et al. (2015) study a sample of 21 OECD countries over 30 years and find that credit booms tend to undermine aggregate productivity growth, mainly through labour reallocations towards sectors with lower productivity growth. For a group of 20 OECD countries from 1970 to 2009, Salotti and Trecroci (2016) show that rising public debt levels are associated with lower rates of aggregate productivity growth. Using data regarding 20 advanced economies over 25 years, Cecchetti and Kharroubi (2019) argue that a country’s credit growth is a drag on its productivity growth, because credit booms slow growth in industries with lower asset tangibility or high research and development (R&D) intensity, which are usually regarded as engines for growth. Anderson and Raissi (2022) find significant negative effects of persistent corporate debt accumulation on the growth of TFP within Italian firms from 1999 to 2015. Kim et al. (2023) propose an accounting framework that maps the dispersion of borrowing costs along the debt maturity structure to the misallocation of productive resources, and they find that inefficient allocation of debt could reduce TFP by approximately 14.4% in the US manufacturing sector.
The TFP growth is the most important determinant of output growth in the long run (Caselli, 2005; Hall & Jones, 1999; Hsieh & Klenow, 2010; Klenow & Rodriguez-Clare, 1997), and this suggests that the observed differences in per capita income across countries are primarily due to the differences in their aggregate productivity. However, recent important research suggests that input misallocation – or the inefficient allocation of resources across firms and sectors – is a key factor in explaining differences in measured TFP. An article by Restuccia and Rogerson (2008) shows that policies distorting the prices faced by different producers lead to the reallocation of resources across productive units, thus entailing important effects on aggregate TFP. Hsieh and Klenow (2009) use microdata on manufacturing firms to document much higher dispersion of marginal products of capital and labour (i.e., measures of input misallocation) across plants in China and India compared to the United States. The authors also estimate large gains from reallocation: if the levels of dispersion in marginal products in China and India were counterfactually equalized to those in the U.S., TFP levels would be increased by 30–50% in China and 40–60% in India.
These studies suggest that aggregate productivity incorporates not only firm-level productive efficiency and industry-level technological advancement but also allocative efficiency across firms and industries. While some of the aforementioned research has examined how excessive leverage affects productivity outcomes, this article focuses specifically on how debt accumulation impacts capital allocation efficiency – an important economic phenomenon in its own right. The efficiency of capital allocation across firms has direct implications for investment returns, market competitiveness, and economic resilience. While determining the mechanism through which debt affects misallocation is more of a theoretical issue, this article investigates how increases in private and public debt influence capital misallocation depending on differences in industry characteristics. Understanding the relationship between debt accumulation and capital misallocation is important, as it sheds light on how financial systems interact with real economic activity.
2.2 Possible Relationship Between Debt and Misallocation
In addition to studies examining the effects of private and public debt on growth and productivity, an emerging body of research has also begun to investigate the relationship between debt accumulation and capital allocation efficiency. Aghion et al. (2019) develop a simple model to show an inverted-U relationship between credit access and aggregate productivity growth generated by two counteracting effects: (i) a positive investment effect of credit access on incumbent firms’ productivity growth through the facilitation of innovation, and (ii) a negative reallocation effect of credit access through the exit rate of incumbent firms and its influence on the entry cost for new – potentially more efficient – innovators. In a model of rational bubbles in the credit market, Pannella (2020) shows that high-credit periods allow larger but unproductive firms to increase their leverage compared to smaller and productive firms, thereby generating a misallocation of capital. Deng et al. (2023) find that the expansion of local government debt in China inhibits the efficient allocation of capital and increases urban carbon emissions. In a similar vein, Deng and Liu (2024) use city-level data from China to show that, out of different types of finance, one driven by local governments, particularly through land sales, exacerbates resource misallocation by directing funds to low-productivity state sectors. Using matched firm- and bank-level data for Spain, Basco et al. (2025) document that housing bubbles generate capital misallocation within industries and across municipalities by raising the value of the collateral disproportionately for firms and municipalities with greater real estate assets.
The above studies suggest that growing leverage in the financial sector could impact the efficiency of resource allocation in the economy. This association between debt and capital allocation efficiency is evident in Figure 2, where both private and public debt seem to positively correlate with capital misallocation (the country-level coefficients of correlation of capital misallocation with private debt and public debt, respectively, are 0.388 and 0.348).

Scatterplot of private/public debt and capital misallocation (Source: Author’s estimations based on the IMF and CompNet data. The estimations are at the country-year level, and MRPK dispersions are weighted averages, where the weights are country-specific time-varying sectoral value-added shares). (a) Private debt and capital misallocation. (b) Public debt and capital misallocation.
Recent studies reveal at least two main mechanisms or transmission channels through which debt accumulation at the aggregate level may affect capital misallocation across firms in a country or industry. The first is the existence of financial frictions and imperfections associated with pledgeable collateral or borrowing constraints. Moll (2014) argues that in a general equilibrium framework with borrowing constraints resulting from credit market imperfections, the equilibrium allocation implies that the marginal product of capital in highly productive firms exceeds that in less productive firms, unless idiosyncratic productivity shocks are persistent. Doerr (2020) similarly finds that rising property prices reduce aggregate productivity by reallocating capital and labour towards unproductive real estate owning firms. The second channel regards bubbles arising from excessive debt accumulation. Miao and Wang (2014) construct a two-sector endogenous growth model with credit-driven stock price bubbles to show that bubbles impact economic growth by easing access to credit and improving investment efficiency on the one hand, and by reallocating capital across sectors on the other. Basco et al. (2025) and Pannella (2020) also find distortionary effects of bubbles on capital allocation in the housing and credit markets. This article builds on insights from all these studies by examining how private debt accumulation interacts with sectoral characteristics to amplify capital misallocation.
In view of the discussion above, I hypothesize in this article that an increase in the supply of bank credit and other private debt instruments may exacerbate capital misallocation by disproportionately benefiting firms with easier access to credit (e.g., due to long-term relationships with banks) or better collateral (e.g., real estate assets). In such cases, an expansion of private lending should exacerbate capital misallocation disproportionately more in industries with greater inherent demand for external finance and higher average credit constraints or larger differences in credit constraints across firms. Regarding public debt, it is possible that an increase in public debt alters the allocation of capital by crowding out private credit (and directing funds to less productive state sectors) or subsidizing certain producers at the expense of others. In addition, other differences across firms (e.g., technological intensity or exposure to competition) could form the basis for the disproportionate effects of debt accumulation, leading to increased capital misallocation.
I adopt the framework developed by Hsieh and Klenow (2009) for the measurement of capital misallocation. Appendix A provides theoretical insight into capital misallocation and discusses its empirical measurement. It shows that the dispersion of marginal revenue products of capital and labour may reflect inefficiencies in resource allocation. While such inefficiencies may reduce aggregate productivity as discussed by Hsieh and Klenow (2009), this study focuses on understanding the effects of private debt on capital misallocation. My conjecture concerning the impact of aggregate debt on capital misallocation becomes justified if an increase in debt interacts with financial market frictions (e.g., differences in possession of real estate assets or access to credit) or other market imperfections in affecting the dispersion of the marginal revenue product of capital across firms. Therefore, the testable hypothesis of this article is that an increase in private and public debt accumulation in an economy with existing sectoral differences in terms of financial and technological constraints will exacerbate capital misallocation within sectors.
3 Empirical Methodology
3.1 The Data
For capital misallocation, this study employs the 6th Vintage of CompNet database, which provides micro-based data regarding a range of indicators constructed on firm-level information, as described in Lopez-Garcia and Di Mauro (2015). The 6th Vintage of CompNet dataset represents an annual unbalanced panel covering 18 EU countries[1] from 1999 to 2016, although data availability reduces this period to 2003–2015 for most of these countries. Indicators in the dataset were collected considering two samples of firms: those with at least one employee (the “full” sample) and those with at least 20 employees (the “20E” sample). In this analysis, I use the 20E sample since it is more homogenous and comparable across countries compared to the full sample, in particular due to exclusion rules in countries such as Poland and Slovakia, where only firms with more than 10 and 20 employees, respectively, must report their accounts. The dataset reports indicators aggregated at macro-sector (1-digit sectors corresponding to NACE Rev.2 sections) and sector (2-digit NACE Rev.2 sectors) levels. For each indicator in the 20E sample, firms are weighted according to their relative presence in the sample and are thus representative of the population of firms regarding sectoral distribution. I use the macro-sector-level data that include nine sectors of the economy at the one-digit industry level: manufacturing, construction, and seven service sectors (wholesale and retail trade; information and communication; transportation and storage; accommodation and food services; professional, scientific, and technical services; administrative and support services; real estate services).[2]
I use the measure of capital misallocation defined, as in the seminal paper by Hsieh and Klenow (2009), as the dispersion of marginal revenue products of capital across firms within an industry. The intuition behind this definition is the following: under financial markets with no distortions, efficient within-industry allocation requires that marginal returns to capital across firms are equalized, since any firm with a higher return would have no difficulty in obtaining capital, hence bringing its marginal revenue product of capital down to the efficient level. Hsieh and Klenow (2009) show under some specific assumptions that an industry’s TFP is maximized when, other things equal, the dispersion of marginal revenue product of capital is zero. Therefore, the higher this dispersion, the higher is the misallocation of capital within the industry. However, capital misallocation defined this way is not necessarily comparable across industries and over time due to differences in adjustment costs and levels of uncertainty faced by firms in different industries (Asker et al., 2014). To address this issue, CompNet (6th Vintage) provides an adjusted measure of capital misallocation as proposed by Kehrig (2015).[3] This is what I use as the dependent variable in my analysis.
The data concerning private and public debt originates from the International Monetary Fund’s Global Debt Database. Private debt comprises the total stock of loans and debt securities issued by households and nonfinancial corporations (as a share of GDP), while public debt consists of the total stock of debt liabilities issued by the general government (as a share of GDP). Control variables include the Chinn and Ito (2006) capital account openness index; long-term interest rates (OECD); general government final consumption expenditure (World Bank); taxes on income, profits, and capital gains (ICTD Government Revenue Dataset[4]); trade (sum of exports and imports as a share of GDP, World Bank); sectoral average real turnover (CompNet); and an index of institutional quality measured as the sum of political risk rating indicators such as bureaucracy quality, investment profile, rule of law, and control of corruption (ICRG Researchers Dataset[5]). The variables, such as private and public debt; government consumption; taxes on income, profits, and capital gains; and trade, are all in percent of GDP. The choice of control variables as possible determinants of capital misallocation is based on studies including Bai et al. (2019), Durnev (2010), Edmond et al. (2015), Gamberoni et al. (2016), Gopinath et al. (2017), Hassan et al. (2019), Larrain and Stumpner (2017), McNabb (2018), Monacelli and Sala (2018), and Ramey and Shapiro (1998). The explanatory variables are constructed as interaction terms between a time-varying country-level component and a time-invariant sectoral-level component (except for the average real turnover, which is available at the sectoral level from the CompNet database). Regarding sector-specific interacting variables, I use (i) an indicator of external finance dependence as in Rajan and Zingales (1998) – based on Compustat data on U.S. listed firms – obtained from Franco (2018); (ii) an indicator of credit constraints (ICC) available from CompNet database (i.e., share of credit constrained firms based on the methodology used in the survey on access to finance of enterprises, SAFE)[6]; (iii) an indicator of sectoral technological intensity obtained from Eurostat (namely Eurostat indicators on high-tech industry and knowledge-intensive services).
Sector-specific interacting variables are used due to the absence of industry-level data concerning credit or debt ratios as well as the appeal of the difference-in-differences approach, which enables us to exploit the variation across industries to assess the impact of country-level variables on industry-level variables. Rajan and Zingales’ (1998) indicator is a commonly used measure of industries’ technological dependence on external finance. Because U.S. capital markets are “among the most advanced in the world, and large publicly traded firms typically face the least frictions in accessing finance” (Rajan & Zingales, 1998), the industry median of external finance dependence of large firms in the U.S. represents a useful measure of that industry’s inherent demand for external finance elsewhere. Regarding technological intensity, Calligaris et al. (2018) show that an increase in misallocation is positively correlated with R&D intensity at the sector level, and they argue that relative specialization in sectors where technology has been changing faster helps explain the patterns of misallocation across geographical areas and firm size classes. Cecchetti and Kharroubi (2019) also find negative effects of credit growth on TFP growth in sectors with high R&D intensity.
Appendix B, Table A2 provides the description and sources of data used in the analysis. The summary statistics of the variables are given in Table A3.
3.2 Preliminary Empirical Motivation
To contemplate the potential role of financial frictions in transmitting the effect of debt on capital misallocation, we can consider whether how well-established firms are in the market could be a plausible explanation for the differences in their financing constraints. Since I conjecture that borrowing constraints could be a factor that modulates the effect of debt on capital misallocation, evidence suggesting that longer-established firms face fewer such constraints could provide a hint for the transmission role of these constraints. To test the relationship between firm age and access-to-finance obstacles, I use a separate data source, where data are available from the World Bank’s Enterprise Surveys (WBES). The WBES provide firm-level data for more than 125,000 firms belonging to nearly fifty ISIC 2-digit business sectors in 146 countries, but I use the data for 26 EU countries (across several waves of the surveys)[7] since the main analysis in this study concerns the EU countries only.
The WBES dataset has a variable measuring the degree to which access to finance is an obstacle to the firm’s current operations, and it ranges from 0 (no obstacle) to 4 (very severe obstacle). It can be seen from Table 1 that while more than 60% of firms that are older than 30 years report having no obstacle to access to finance, only 47.6% of firms that are younger than 10 years report having no such obstacle. While this seems to support my conjecture that older firms face fewer financing constraints, this cross-tabulation of access-to-finance obstacles and firm age does not control for unobserved country-specific and sector-specific heterogeneity. In order to address this, I run a regression of access-to-finance obstacles on firm age as well as firm size, controlling for country, sector, and survey-year fixed effects.
Cross-tabulation of the access-to-finance obstacles and firm age (percentages)
Years since the first establishment | Total | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
≤10 | 10–30 | >30 | ||
No obstacle | 47.60 | 52.20 | 60.14 | 53.38 |
Minor obstacle | 17.45 | 16.94 | 16.29 | 16.87 |
Moderate obstacle | 18.73 | 17.17 | 14.09 | 16.67 |
Major obstacle | 10.77 | 9.59 | 6.96 | 9.14 |
Very severe obstacle | 5.45 | 4.10 | 2.52 | 3.95 |
Total | 100.00 | 100.00 | 100.00 | 100.00 |
Source of data: World Bank Enterprise Surveys.
Table 2 demonstrates that older firms face fewer access-to-finance obstacles. It also shows that firm size is negatively correlated with these obstacles. This finding implies that, if younger (smaller) firms are more capital constrained (and hence have a higher marginal product of capital in general), then an increase in the supply of credit that disproportionately benefits older (larger) and less productive firms (due to the existing nature of financing obstacles or borrowing constraints) can widen the disparity of the marginal products of capital between the younger (smaller) and older (larger) firms. Although the substantive significance of the results in Table 2 is not high (the standardized versions of the coefficients for firm age and firm size are, respectively, −0.04 and −0.02), they still seem to support my basic premise that older (and larger) firms face fewer borrowing constraints than younger (and smaller) firms.
The regression of access-to-finance obstacles on firm age
Dependent variable: access-to-finance obstacles | (1) | (2) |
---|---|---|
Firm age | −0.00198*** (0.000326) | −0.00180*** (0.000333) |
Firm size | −0.0264*** (0.00998) | |
Constant | 0.761*** (0.123) | 0.792*** (0.123) |
Country FE | Yes | Yes |
Sector FE | Yes | Yes |
Survey-year FE | Yes | Yes |
Observations | 24,674 | 24,674 |
R-squared | 0.103 | 0.104 |
Standard errors in parentheses. ***p < 0.01.
3.3 The Empirical Model
To examine the effects of private and public debt on capital misallocation, this study employs a difference-in-differences-type empirical methodology, whereby the aggregate (country-level) debt-to-GDP ratios are interacted with various sector-specific[8] indicators, like the work of Larrain and Stumpner (2017) and Rajan and Zingales (1998). The empirical model appears as follows:
where
The empirical model uses the fixed-effects (within) regression since the explanatory variables of interest may be correlated with country and sector-specific unobserved factors. Standard errors are clustered at the country level; additionally, heteroscedasticity- and autocorrelation-consistent (HAC) standard errors are used as per Driscoll and Kraay (1998), which also addresses the potential cross-sectional dependence in the data (see Hoechle, 2007). For robustness, the model is tested using (the static version of) the generalized method of moments (GMM) system estimator developed by Arellano and Bond (1991), Arellano and Bover (1995), and Blundell and Bond (1998).
4 Results
4.1 Baseline Regressions
This section discusses the results of the panel regressions. The explanatory variables include the natural logarithms of private debt, public debt, government consumption, taxes on income, profits and capital gains, trade, and sectoral average real turnover across firms,[9] while also controlling for the long-term interest rate and indices for capital account openness[10] and the quality of political institutions. The lagged values of the (logs of) private and public debt are used to account for potential endogeneity concerns, along with the lagged value of the capital account openness index – as in Larrain and Stumpner (2017) – since it is unlikely to have an immediate effect on capital misallocation.
Table 3 reports the results of fixed-effects regressions, where the explanatory variables are interacted with the sectoral-level indicator of external finance dependence. The results suggest that an increase in private debt exacerbates capital misallocation, and more so in sectors with higher financial dependence. While sectors that depend on external finance are more likely to benefit from higher credit availability, they also experience a larger increase in dispersion of marginal revenue products of capital following a rise in private sector indebtedness. To understand the size of the estimated effect, consider two (NACE 1-digit) sectors: one at the 75th percentile of the distribution of financial dependence (transportation and storage) and one at the 25th percentile (manufacturing). The difference in financial dependence between the two sectors is 0.11 (=0.40–0.29). A rise in private debt–to-GDP ratio by one standard deviation (i.e., 65.56 percentage points) is predicted to increase the dispersion in the return to capital in the sector at the 75th percentile of financial dependence by 0.457 more than in the sector at the 25th percentile (=0.994·ln(65.56)·0.11). This is equivalent to approximately 0.73 standard deviations of the dependent variable. Public debt, however, does not seem to affect capital misallocation after controlling for other potential determinants. The effect of capital account openness is found to be negative, meaning that financial liberalization reduces capital misallocation, supporting the findings of Larrain and Stumpner (2017). The coefficient of the long-term interest rate is also negative, suggesting that declining interest rates tend to increase the dispersion of returns to capital – which is supported by recent studies including Caggese and Pérez-Orive (2019), Cette et al. (2016), and Gopinath et al. (2017). No significant effect on capital misallocation of other control variables was found.
Debt-to-GDP ratios and capital misallocation: Fixed effects regressions (interaction with financial dependence)
Dependent variable: Dispersion in normalized MRPK | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | (10) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
ln(Private Debt) × Fin.Dep. (lagged) | 0.739*** (0.232) | 0.901*** (0.229) | 0.798*** (0.203) | 0.747*** (0.206) | 0.689** (0.264) | 0.608** (0.243) | 0.787*** (0.220) | 0.668** (0.295) | 0.994*** (0.144) | 0.994*** (0.259) |
ln(Public Debt) × Fin.Dep. (lagged) | 0.391** (0.171) | 0.294 (0.185) | 0.315 (0.189) | 0.385** (0.169) | 0.364* (0.188) | 0.300 (0.189) | 0.360* (0.180) | 0.303* (0.172) | 0.048 (0.216) | 0.048 (0.197) |
Capital Acc. Openness × Fin.Dep. (lagged) | −0.878** (0.380) | −1.066** (0.453) | −1.066*** (0.287) | |||||||
LT Interest Rate × Fin. Dep. | −0.045 (0.027) | −0.056** (0.022) | −0.056*** (0.013) | |||||||
ln(Govt. Consump.) × Fin. Dep. | −0.130 (0.732) | 0.043 (0.886) | 0.043 (1.185) | |||||||
ln(Taxes on IPC) × Fin. Dep. | −0.239 (0.516) | −0.024 (0.370) | −0.024 (0.330) | |||||||
ln(Trade) × Fin. Dep. | 0.573 (0.375) | −0.191 (0.632) | −0.191 (0.595) | |||||||
ln(Avg. Real Turnover) | 0.158* (0.080) | 0.073 (0.085) | 0.073 (0.117) | |||||||
Institut. Quality × Fin. Dep. | −0.031 (0.053) | −0.034 (0.052) | −0.034 (0.034) | |||||||
Constant | −1.515*** (0.435) | −1.350*** (0.421) | −1.429*** (0.364) | −1.356 (1.196) | −1.145 (0.971) | −2.209*** (0.584) | −3.000*** (0.796) | −0.946 (1.076) | −0.877 (2.495) | −0.877 (2.490) |
Standard errors | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | HAC (Driscoll-Kraay) |
Observations | 1,806 | 1,806 | 1,779 | 1,806 | 1,806 | 1,806 | 1,786 | 1,806 | 1,759 | 1,759 |
R-squared | 0.172 | 0.176 | 0.188 | 0.172 | 0.172 | 0.173 | 0.174 | 0.172 | 0.195 | 0.195 |
Standard errors in parentheses. *p < 0.1; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01.
Table 4 reports the regression estimates, where the explanatory variables are interacted with the indicator of average credit constraints. The sign of the private debt coefficient is similar to that in Table 3: in sectors with a higher share of credit-constrained firms, a rise in private debt increases capital misallocation more than in sectors with a lower share of credit-constrained firms. To understand the magnitude of this effect, consider two country–sector pairs[11]: one at the 75th percentile of the distribution of average credit constraints (information and communication in Italy) and one at the 25th percentile (administrative and support service activities in Croatia). The difference in the indicator of average credit constraints between the two country-sectors is 0.083 (=0.153–0.070). An increase in private debt by one standard deviation is predicted to increase the dispersion in the return to capital in the country-sector at the 75th percentile of average credit constraints by 1.177 units more than in the country-sector at the 25th percentile of the distribution (=3.389·ln(65.56)·0.083). This is equivalent to approximately 1.89 standard deviations of the dependent variable, which is not trivial. Although the coefficient of public debt is significantly positive in several columns that exclude most of the controls, it loses statistical significance when all controls are included. The long-term interest rate is found to improve capital allocation, as shown in Table 3, when the Driscoll-Kraay standard errors are used.
Debt–to-GDP ratios and capital misallocation: fixed effects regressions (interaction with average credit constraints)
Dependent variable: Dispersion in normalized MRPK | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | (10) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
ln(Private Debt) × Cred. Constr. (lagged) | 3.364*** (0.709) | 3.310*** (0.733) | 3.735*** (0.640) | 3.405*** (0.705) | 3.444*** (0.718) | 2.625*** (0.780) | 3.281*** (0.735) | 3.428*** (0.674) | 3.389*** (0.781) | 3.389*** (0.856) |
ln(Public Debt) × Cred. Constr. (lagged) | 1.386*** (0.368) | 1.148* (0.611) | 0.816* (0.416) | 1.343*** (0.354) | 1.447*** (0.453) | 0.685 (0.533) | 1.430*** (0.375) | 1.477** (0.666) | 0.652 (1.199) | 0.652 (0.580) |
Capital Acc. Openness × Cred. Constr. (lagged) | −1.830 (1.822) | −1.721 (3.197) | −1.721 (2.122) | |||||||
LT Interest Rate × Cred. Constr. | −0.223** (0.087) | −0.189 (0.108) | −0.189** (0.070) | |||||||
ln(Govt.Consump.) × Cred. Constr. | −0.800 (1.901) | 1.583 (2.480) | 1.583 (3.495) | |||||||
ln(Taxes on IPC) × Cred. Constr. | 0.414 (1.077) | 0.712 (1.363) | 0.712 (0.977) | |||||||
ln(Trade) × Cred. Constr. | 3.346* (1.850) | 1.405 (2.328) | 1.405 (1.784) | |||||||
ln(Avg. Real Turnover) | 0.153 (0.088) | 0.053 (0.092) | 0.053 (0.142) | |||||||
Institut. Quality × Cred. Constr. | 0.029 (0.133) | 0.016 (0.186) | 0.016 (0.118) | |||||||
Constant | −1.995*** (0.354) | −1.648** (0.618) | −1.848*** (0.306) | −1.709* (0.814) | −2.184*** (0.628) | −3.041*** (0.688) | −3.368*** (0.837) | −2.149** (0.739) | −3.456 (2.384) | −3.456 (2.101) |
Standard errors | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | HAC (Driscoll-Kraay) |
Observations | 1,482 | 1,482 | 1,455 | 1,482 | 1,482 | 1,482 | 1,473 | 1,482 | 1,446 | 1,446 |
R-squared | 0.178 | 0.179 | 0.197 | 0.179 | 0.179 | 0.181 | 0.181 | 0.179 | 0.198 | 0.198 |
Standard errors in parentheses. *p < 0.1; **p < 0.05; and ***p < 0.01.
Table 5 shows the results of regressions where the explanatory variables are interacted with sectoral R&D intensity. The strong amplification effect of private debt is again confirmed: a rise in private debt increases capital misallocation, particularly in sectors that are more technologically intensive. A potential explanation is that R&D-intensive sectors are more likely to be credit constrained due to higher informational asymmetries, lower collateral value of firms (due to the elevated usage of intangible assets such as human capital and specialized machinery), and highly uncertain and skewed investment returns (Carpenter & Petersen, 2002; Fauceglia, 2015). To better understand the size of the effect, consider again two sectors: one at the 75th percentile of the distribution of technological intensity (transportation and storage) and one at the 25th percentile (e.g., construction). The difference in technological intensity between the two sectors is 0.402 (= 0.402 – 0). An increase in private debt-to-GDP ratio by one standard deviation is predicted to increase the dispersion in the return to capital in the sector at the 75th percentile of R&D intensity by 1.01 units more than in the sector at the 25th percentile (= 0.600·ln(65.56)·0.402). This is equivalent to approximately 1.62 standard deviations of capital misallocation. Public debt, again, has no significant capital misallocation effect at the 5% level of significance. The sign of the effect of financial openness is similar to that in Table 3, meaning that capital account liberalization may improve capital allocation (especially in highly R&D-intensive sectors), but there was no observed significant effect of interest rates in the current estimation.[12]
Debt-to-GDP ratios and capital misallocation: fixed effects regressions (interaction with technological intensity)
Dependent variable: Dispersion in normalized MRPK | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | (10) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
ln(Private Debt) × Tech.Intensity (lagged) | 0.566** (0.204) | 0.639** (0.245) | 0.612*** (0.169) | 0.587*** (0.194) | 0.500** (0.213) | 0.360** (0.171) | 0.625*** (0.197) | 0.553** (0.213) | 0.600*** (0.199) | 0.600*** (0.154) |
ln(Public Debt) × Tech. Intensity (lagged) | 0.354* (0.192) | 0.311 (0.218) | 0.301 (0.183) | 0.339* (0.183) | 0.318 (0.211) | 0.213 (0.210) | 0.328* (0.184) | 0.339 (0.228) | 0.178 (0.261) | 0.178* (0.100) |
Capital Acc. Openness × Tech. Intensity (lagged) | −0.390 (0.247) | −0.495 (0.293) | −0.495*** (0.140) | |||||||
LT Interest Rate × Tech. Intensity | −0.033* (0.018) | −0.021 (0.017) | −0.021 (0.024) | |||||||
ln(Govt. Consump.) × Tech. Intensity | −0.347 (0.526) | 0.370 (0.533) | 0.370 (0.766) | |||||||
ln(Taxes on IPC) × Tech. Intensity | −0.317 (0.314) | −0.088 (0.265) | −0.088 (0.262) | |||||||
ln(Trade) × Tech. Intensity | 0.891* (0.424) | 0.631 (0.630) | 0.631 (0.436) | |||||||
ln(Avg. Real Turnover) | 0.176* (0.092) | 0.107 (0.090) | 0.107 (0.109) | |||||||
Institut. Quality × Tech. Intensity | −0.005 (0.038) | 0.014 (0.036) | 0.014 (0.011) | |||||||
Constant | −0.822*** (0.278) | −0.762** (0.289) | −0.779*** (0.195) | −0.471 (0.709) | −0.414 (0.590) | −1.716*** (0.476) | −2.486*** (0.801) | −0.740 (0.634) | −2.858** (1.230) | −2.858*** (0.942) |
Standard errors | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | HAC (Driscoll-Kraay) |
Observations | 1,806 | 1,806 | 1,779 | 1,806 | 1,806 | 1,806 | 1,786 | 1,806 | 1,759 | 1,759 |
R-squared | 0.164 | 0.165 | 0.177 | 0.164 | 0.165 | 0.167 | 0.166 | 0.164 | 0.181 | 0.181 |
Standard errors in parentheses. *p < 0.1; **p < 0.05; and ***p < 0.01.
Table 6 provides the results where capital misallocation is regressed on the two components of private debt separately: non-financial corporations’ debt and household debt. In these regressions, public debt is omitted since (i) its effect is insignificant and (ii) it does not noticeably increase the explanatory power of the regression model. The table shows that both corporate and household debt have significant amplifying effects on capital misallocation, but the effect of corporate debt is much larger (almost three times) than that of household debt. This finding is both intuitive and important since (i) capital misallocation is mainly the problem of the corporate sector, and (ii) this suggests that excessive corporate debt could be a more important factor in reallocating resources towards unproductive firms than household debt, which usually finances consumption rather than investment.
Private debt-to-GDP ratios and capital misallocation: fixed effects regressions
Financial dependence | Financial dependence | Avg. Credit constraints | Avg. Credit constraints | Technological intensity | Technological intensity | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Interacting variable | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | (10) | (11) | (12) |
ln(Corporate Debt) × Interaction (lagged) | 0.965*** (0.230) | 0.965*** (0.288) | 3.241*** (1.021) | 3.241** (1.177) | 0.569** (0.198) | 0.569*** (0.170) | ||||||
ln(Household Debt) × Interaction (lagged) | 0.365*** (0.088) | 0.365** (0.164) | 1.185** (0.417) | 1.185** (0.465) | 0.199** (0.089) | 0.199** (0.088) | ||||||
Capit. Acc. Openness × Interaction (lagged) | −0.823** (0.361) | −0.823*** (0.172) | −1.186* (0.604) | −1.186*** (0.342) | −2.241 (3.287) | −2.241 (2.112) | −0.502 (2.960) | −0.502 (2.007) | −0.449** (0.178) | −0.449*** (0.110) | −0.639* (0.339) | −0.639*** (0.161) |
LT Interest Rate × Interaction | −0.054** (0.020) | −0.054*** (0.017) | −0.051** (0.021) | −0.051*** (0.015) | −0.210** (0.088) | −0.210** (0.084) | −0.195* (0.091) | −0.195** (0.084) | −0.026 (0.019) | −0.026 (0.026) | −0.023 (0.019) | −0.023 (0.026) |
ln(Govt. Consump.) × Interaction | −0.005 (0.875) | −0.005 (1.139) | 0.738 (0.964) | 0.738 (1.027) | 0.903 (2.153) | 0.903 (3.395) | 3.727 (2.710) | 3.727 (3.066) | 0.347 (0.590) | 0.347 (0.775) | 0.802 (0.554) | 0.802* (0.660) |
ln(Taxes on IPC) × Interaction | −0.266 (0.372) | −0.266 (0.261) | −0.110 (0.399) | −0.110 (0.363) | −0.368 (1.804) | −0.368 (0.988) | −0.184 (1.315) | −0.184 (1.242) | −0.303 (0.237) | −0.303 (0.212) | −0.226 (0.258) | −0.226 (0.200) |
ln(Trade) × Interaction | 0.205 (0.606) | 0.205 (0.594) | −0.088 (0.616) | −0.088 (0.589) | 2.461 (2.301) | 2.461 (1.796) | 2.191 (2.555) | 2.191 (1.901) | 0.868 (0.573) | 0.868** (0.370) | 0.744 (0.645) | 0.744* (0.403) |
ln(Avg. Real Turnover) | 0.071 (0.084) | 0.071 (0.119) | 0.067 (0.081) | 0.067 (0.123) | 0.060 (0.090) | 0.060 (0.139) | 0.047 (0.093) | 0.047 (0.141) | 0.104 (0.090) | 0.104 (0.110) | 0.090 (0.091) | 0.090 (0.110) |
Institut. Quality × Interaction | −0.031 (0.052) | −0.031 (0.019) | −0.065 (0.052) | −0.065** (0.024) | −0.034 (0.118) | −0.034 (0.094) | −0.126 (0.132) | −0.126* (0.065) | 0.001 (0.039) | 0.001 (0.011) | −0.018 (0.040) | −0.018 (0.017) |
Constant | −1.235 (2.425) | −1.235 (1.879) | −0.109 (2.547) | −0.109 (2.116) | −2.768 (1.620) | −2.768* (1.862) | −2.388 (2.052) | −2.388 (1.963) | −2.543** (1.358) | −2.543*** (0.829) | −1.953 (1.565) | −1.953* (1.002) |
Standard errors | Clustered (country) | Driscoll-Kraay | Clustered (country) | Driscoll-Kraay | Clustered (country) | Driscoll-Kraay | Clustered (country) | Driscoll-Kraay | Clustered (country) | Driscoll-Kraay | Clustered (country) | Driscoll-Kraay |
Observations | 1,759 | 1,759 | 1,759 | 1,759 | 1,446 | 1,446 | 1,446 | 1,446 | 1,759 | 1,759 | 1,759 | 1,759 |
R-squared | 0.193 | 0.193 | 0.191 | 0.191 | 0.196 | 0.196 | 0.195 | 0.195 | 0.180 | 0.180 | 0.179 | 0.179 |
Standard errors in parentheses. *p < 0.1; **p < 0.05; and ***p < 0.01.
The observation of the much larger effect of corporate debt on capital misallocation than that of household debt warrants some discussion. Because corporate debt is more directly tied to business investment decisions, it is more likely to affect the allocation of capital among firms. On the contrary, household debt primarily finances consumption and housing, and hence may have only an indirect influence on resource misallocation across firms. Corporate debt directly affects firms’ capital structure, investment choices, and risk-taking behaviour. When corporate debt levels are high, financially constrained firms may face higher borrowing costs or credit rationing, while well-established firms with stronger banking relationships or better collateral may continue to access credit on favourable terms. This may widen the dispersion in marginal returns to capital across firms.
4.2 Robustness Tests
As a robustness check of the baseline specification, the regression model is estimated using the system GMM procedure proposed by Blundell and Bond (1998) – but without the autoregressive term[13] – by instrumenting the explanatory variables with their lags, as described in Holtz-Eakin et al. (1988). To avoid the overfitting of endogenous variables and the associated bias caused by too many instruments, the instrument matrix is collapsed as recommended by Roodman (2009). Since the data are unbalanced and include gaps, instead of first differencing, forward orthogonal deviations are employed to transform the variables, as proposed by Arellano and Bover (1995). Standard errors are clustered at the country level.
Table A4 in the Appendix reports the one-step system GMM estimates using two instrument sets: all lags of the explanatory variables dated t – 2 and earlier, and those dated from t – 2 to t – 10. The results support the earlier finding that private debt accumulation increases capital misallocation, given the sectoral-level indicators such as financial dependence, average credit constraints, and R&D intensity, albeit the coefficients are statistically significant only at the 10% level in the case of the interaction with average credit constraints. Public debt, however, is found to have a somewhat negative effect on capital misallocation, particularly when the explanatory variables are interacted with financial dependence and technological intensity. The coefficients of private debt estimated with the GMM are noticeably smaller in magnitude than those estimated with the fixed effects estimator when the explanatory variables are interacted with the indicators of financial dependence and credit constraints, while the GMM-estimated coefficients are larger in magnitude when the explanatory variables are interacted with the indicator of technological intensity. All private debt coefficients estimated with the GMM, however, lie within the 95% confidence interval of those estimated with the fixed effects estimator. As before, negative coefficients are found for capital account openness and the long-term interest rate (where the coefficients on capital account openness are statistically significant only when using financial dependence and technological intensity as interacting variables, and the coefficients on the long-term interest rate are significant only when average credit constraints and technological intensity are used as interacting variables), which suggests that financial openness and higher interest rates tend to improve capital allocation. Moreover, demand conditions (proxied by average real turnover) are found to positively correlate with capital misallocation in some of the regressions, while the quality of political institutions seems to reduce capital misallocation in all interactions.
Table A5 in the Appendix presents the results of the robustness check – using both the fixed effects and the GMM estimators – excluding two countries, Germany and Spain, due to the small number of observations for the MRPK dispersion (Germany has 16 observations due to the data availability for the manufacturing sector only, and Spain has 56 observations since the data are available only starting from 2009). In addition, the data regarding credit constraints are not available for Hungary and the Slovak Republic for the regressions using the ICC as an interacting (sectoral-level) variable. The results in Table A5 show that the findings regarding the effect of private debt are robust to excluding certain countries from regressions.
In Table A6 in the Appendix, alternative sectoral-level indicators are used for interaction with the country-level explanatory variables. These indicators are available from the CompNet database at the sectoral level and were averaged over the available time period for each country-sector. In columns (1)–(3), the industry standard deviation of credit constraints (instead of the industry mean as performed earlier) is used to interact with the country-level variables. My hypothesis is that private debt may disproportionately increase capital misallocation in sectors with more heterogeneity in credit constraints. In columns (4)–(9), two measures of sectoral competitive structure are used as interacting variables: average markups (calculated as by De Loecker & Warzynski, 2012) and the skewness of sectoral TFP distribution.[14] I conjecture that market imperfections such as the lack of competition could be the source of capital misallocation and that private debt may exacerbate this misallocation, particularly in sectors with a low level of competition (or a high level of concentration). The results in Table A6 support the hypothesis that private debt disproportionately increases capital misallocation in sectors with more heterogeneous credit constraints, higher average markups, and more skewed TFP distribution. Public debt is found to have no significant effect except in one regression, column (5), where it is found to increase capital misallocation when the Driscoll-Kraay standard errors are used. Capital account liberalization is found to have a significantly negative effect on capital misallocation when interacting with the skewness of TFP distribution, and the interest rate is found to have a significant negative effect when interacting with the dispersion of credit constraints.
Overall, the results suggest that excessive private debt accumulation is more detrimental to the efficiency of capital allocation across firms than public debt, because the latter entails no robust capital misallocation effect in this sample of European countries. The results further show that a rise in private debt disproportionately increases the dispersion of returns to capital in sectors that are, on average, more dependent on external finance, more credit-constrained, more technologically intensive, and less competitive. This confirms that continuous debt build-up in the private sector exacerbates capital misallocation by feeding on financial frictions, market imperfections, and existing differences across firms. The finding that higher long-term interest rates may reduce capital misallocation – particularly in sectors with higher financial dependence and credit constraints – strengthens this case since low interest rates are conducive to excessive debt accumulation. The results also confirm the finding of Larrain and Stumpner (2017) that capital account liberalization improves capital allocation in financially dependent industries, probably because this allows financially constrained domestic firms to access global capital markets, including foreign equity capital. An important finding of this article, however, is that private debt seems to be the most significant observable determinant of capital misallocation among all macroeconomic determinants used as explanatory variables in the panel regressions. This finding thus needs further exploration since it pertains to the economic effects of the financial sector that can destabilize entire economies.
To summarize, private debt accumulation in an economy with financial and technological constraints appears to deteriorate the efficiency of capital allocation, which is an important economic phenomenon with potential implications for investment and firm dynamics. The relationship between debt and capital misallocation deserves attention in its own right, as it directly affects how resources are distributed across firms and sectors. While the aggregate productivity effects of private debt accumulation exceed the scope of this article, it is significant that Aghion et al. (2019) find a two-sided effect of credit access on productivity growth, resulting in an inverted-U relationship. This leads to the conjecture that private debt might increase aggregate TFP at low levels of debt-to-GDP ratio by enabling firms to invest in new technologies, while high levels of private debt may reduce aggregate TFP growth due to its capital misallocation effect dominating the investment effect. Testing this conjecture, however, is left for future research.
5 Conclusion
The past two decades of research in international macroeconomics have included studies finding nonlinear effects of private and public debt on economic growth. In addition, findings of recent studies have suggested a possible inverted-U relationship between debt accumulation and aggregate productivity growth. Other research has shown that the misallocation of capital and labour across firms is responsible for significant differences in total factor productivity across countries. These developments have led to questioning the possible role of debt build-up in affecting capital allocation patterns across firms and sectors. If debt accumulation is found to reduce the efficiency of capital allocation, then policymakers may need to think more seriously about the ways to avoid excessive debt build-up, as efficient allocation of resources is crucial for economic performance.
This article aimed to determine whether increases in private and public indebtedness affect capital misallocation, which is measured as the dispersion in the return to capital across firms in different industries. For this purpose, I used a dataset containing industry-level data for 18 European countries and controlled for different macroeconomic indicators as potential determinants of capital misallocation. The within-country variation across industries was exploited in indicators such as external finance dependence, credit constraints, technological intensity, and the degree of competition. The results show that private debt accumulation significantly increases capital misallocation, particularly in industries with high financial dependence, high R&D intensity, a larger share of credit-constrained firms, and a lower level of competition among firms. Thus, private debt accumulation seems to amplify the negative impact of financial frictions and market imperfections on macroeconomic outcomes. When considering the two components of private debt, corporate debt has a much larger amplifying effect on capital misallocation compared to household debt, although the coefficients of both are significant. On the other hand, no significant effect of public debt on capital misallocation was found within industries in the sample. While capital misallocation may have broader economic implications, addressing its drivers is a key step in promoting efficient resource allocation.
Policy measures against excessive private debt accumulation could involve the use of macroprudential tools, such as caps on loan-to-value and debt-to-income ratios, as well as countercyclical capital buffers. Such measures are particularly relevant for sectors that are most vulnerable to capital misallocation effects. It may also be important to distinguish between productive and unproductive credit when designing macroprudential policies. However, implementing such policies in the European context may face certain challenges; these could include constraints from common monetary policy that limit country-specific responses and the need to balance short-term growth objectives with long-term financial stability concerns.
The article has several limitations. First, although it analysed how private (and public) debt accumulation may affect capital misallocation disproportionately in sectors that are more financially dependent, credit-constrained, technologically intensive and less competitive, it did not directly investigate mediating or moderating roles of potential transmission channels or mechanisms due to data unavailability. Second, while the article finds that private debt accumulation exacerbates existing capital misallocation within sectors, it does not tell anything about the original sources or drivers of this misallocation. Third, the article only focuses on the effects of debt accumulation on capital misallocation but does not investigate its further consequences for aggregate productivity. Last but not least, the article focuses on 18 European countries only, but fails to explore a broader set of countries, again due to the lack of available data for such an investigation.
An extension of this article’s empirical analysis would be to develop a theoretical model that accounts for the observed amplification effect of private debt on capital misallocation. Another extension would be to quantitatively analyse the implications of the misallocation-aggravating effects of private debt accumulation for the long-term aggregate productivity growth. In connection with this, future studies could examine whether industries with higher MRPK dispersion exhibit systematic differences in TFP growth or innovation dynamics, particularly in knowledge-intensive sectors. A further extension would be to test the relationship between private and public debt and misallocation for a wide range of developing countries, since the structural differences between advanced and developing economies might lead to a different nexus between finance and capital allocation patterns. These and other extensions of the analysis are left to future research.
Acknowledgments
The author is thankful to Prof. Fabio Cesare Bagliano (Università degli Studi di Torino), Dr. Luca Gambetti (Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona), Mathilde Viennot from France Stratégie, Ahlidin Malikov from Westminster International University in Tashkent, an anonymous reviewer from the Program Committee of the 25th Spring Meeting of Young Economists, and another two anonymous reviewers for their valuable suggestions and comments. I also thank the organizers and participants at the 1st CompNet Data User Conference in Paris for their comments on the earlier version of the paper. This article is an updated version of the previously published Discussion paper titled “Private debt, public debt, and capital misallocation” (Alimov, 2019).
-
Funding information: The author states no funding is involved.
-
Author contribution: The author confirms the sole responsibility for the conception of the study, presented results, and manuscript preparation.
-
Conflict of interest: The author states no conflict of interest.
-
Data availability statement: The data that support the findings of this study are available from the Competitiveness Research Network (CompNet). Restrictions apply to the availability of these data, which were used under license for the current study, and are not publicly available. Data are, however, available from the author upon reasonable request and with permission of CompNet.
-
Article note: As part of the open assessment, reviews and the original submission are available as supplementary files on our website.
Appendix A Capital Misallocation: Theory and Measurement
A.1. A Theoretical Basis for Misallocation
The framework developed by Hsieh and Klenow (2009) is adopted to measure capital misallocation. They consider an economy consisting of S sectors characterized by monopolistic competition. Each sector’s output is a constant-elasticity-of-substitution aggregate of
where
Each firm’s production function is given by a Cobb-Douglas technology of the following form:
where
where
The capital–labour ratio is given by:
Given the definition of the marginal products of capital and labour (MPK and MPL), the following results are obtained for the marginal revenue products of these inputs:
where
Equations (A6) and (A7) show that, in the absence of distortions, marginal returns to capital and labour would be equalized across firms in each sector; given firm-specific output and capital distortions, however, marginal revenue products differ across these firms.
The “revenue productivity” of the firm – as opposed to its “physical productivity” given by
In the absence of distortions, differences in firms’ physical productivity (
Simple algebra allows to express the industry TFP as:
where
When
In this last equation, the variance of log TFPR summarizes the negative effect of distortions on industry TFP. This also implies that the extent of misallocation becomes worse when there is an increase in the dispersion of marginal products of capital and labour.[16]
A.2. Empirical Measurement of Capital Misallocation
This study adopts the Hsieh and Klenow (2009) definition of the misallocation of capital, measured as the dispersion of its marginal revenue products. While CompNet database provides several measures of sectoral allocative efficiency, the measure of capital misallocation in the database is based on the Hsieh and Klenow (2009) methodology.[17] The measurement of this misallocation is explained in the CompNet User Guide and described below.
Taking equation (A2) in logs gives the empirical version of the firm-level (time-varying) production function:
where
where
After estimating the capital output elasticity
The above estimate is then used to calculate the measure of the within-sector time-series dispersion of the marginal productivity of capital for each 2-digit industry. To control for potential bias driven by sector-specific price dynamics or technology improvements, the marginal productivity of capital at the firm level is detrended and rescaled by the sectoral standard deviation (at the 2-digit level).[18] The macro-sector level of capital misallocation is then computed as the median standard deviation of the resulting series across all 2-digit industries belonging to the corresponding 1-digit industry.
Appendix B Data Description and Summary Tables
The number of firms for each EU country in each wave of the World Bank Enterprise Surveys dataset
Country | 2007 | 2009 | 2013 | 2014 | 2018 | 2019 | 2020 | 2021 | Total |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Austria | 599 | 599 | |||||||
Belgium | 609 | 609 | |||||||
Croatia | 633 | 356 | 404 | 1,393 | |||||
Cyprus | 237 | 237 | |||||||
Czech Republic | 248 | 246 | 500 | 994 | |||||
Denmark | 992 | 992 | |||||||
Estonia | 271 | 267 | 356 | 894 | |||||
Finland | 755 | 755 | |||||||
France | 1,536 | 1,536 | |||||||
Germany | 1,680 | 1,680 | |||||||
Greece | 600 | 600 | |||||||
Hungary | 291 | 298 | 800 | 1,389 | |||||
Ireland | 604 | 604 | |||||||
Italy | 740 | 740 | |||||||
Latvia | 271 | 319 | 351 | 941 | |||||
Lithuania | 275 | 252 | 355 | 882 | |||||
Luxembourg | 167 | 167 | |||||||
Malta | 241 | 241 | |||||||
Netherlands | 805 | 805 | |||||||
Poland | 455 | 527 | 1,290 | 2,272 | |||||
Portugal | 1,059 | 1,059 | |||||||
Romania | 527 | 538 | 807 | 1,872 | |||||
Slovak Republic | 272 | 265 | 428 | 965 | |||||
Slovenia | 276 | 269 | 403 | 948 | |||||
Spain | 1,049 | 1,049 | |||||||
Sweden | 597 | 585 | 1,182 | ||||||
Total | 633 | 2,886 | 3,337 | 597 | 600 | 7,971 | 4,517 | 4,864 | 25,405 |
Overview of data used in the regression analysis
Variables | Measure | Source |
---|---|---|
Dependent variable | ||
Capital misallocation (NACE 1-digit sector level) | Median standard deviation of firm-level marginal revenue products of capital (detrended and rescaled by the industry standard deviation) across NACE 2-digit industries | CompNet 6th Vintage |
Explanatory variables | ||
Private debt | Total stock of loans and debt securities issued by households and nonfinancial corporations (% of GDP) | The IMF’s Global Debt Database |
Public debt | Total stock of debt liabilities issued by the general government (% of GDP) | The IMF’s Global Debt Database |
Capital account openness | The Chinn-Ito index normalized to range 0–1 | Chinn and Ito (2006) |
Long-term interest rates | Interest rates (%) on government bonds maturing in 10 years | OECD |
Government consumption | General government final consumption expenditure (% of GDP) | The World Bank |
Taxes on income, profits, and capital gains | Total taxes on income, profits, and capital gains (% of GDP) | ICTD/UNU-WIDER Government Revenue Dataset |
Trade | The sum of exports and imports of goods and services (% of GDP) | The World Bank |
Average real turnover (NACE 1-digit sector level) | Mean of turnover (total sales net of VAT) deflated with the GDP deflator | CompNet 6th Vintage |
Institutional quality | The sum of four political risk rating indicators: (i) bureaucracy quality, (ii) investment profile, (iii) rule of law, and (iv) control of corruption | PRS Group International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) Researchers Dataset |
Sector-specific (time-invariant) indicators | ||
Financial dependence | Mean of the Rajan and Zingales (1998) measure of external finance dependence (based on U.S. firms in the corresponding sector in the 1995–2006 period) across NACE 2-digit industries | Franco (2018), measured on the basis of Compustat data on U.S. listed firms |
Average credit constraints | Time-average of the ICC calculated as the share of credit-constrained firms based on the methodology used in the SAFE | CompNet 6th Vintage |
Technological intensity | Mean of the ‘indicators on high-tech industry and knowledge-intensive services’ across NACE 2-digit industries | Eurostat |
Dispersion of credit constraints | Time-average of the standard deviation of the ICC | CompNet 6th Vintage |
De Loecker-Warzynski (2012) markups | Time-average of the markup à la De Loecker and Warzynski (2012) estimated with a Cobb-Douglas production function at the NACE 1-digit sector level | CompNet 6th Vintage |
Skewness of TFP distribution | Time-average of the skewness of TFP estimated from a Cobb-Douglas production function at the NACE 1-digit sector level | CompNet 6th Vintage |
Summary statistics of data used in the regression analysis
Obs. | Mean | Std. Dev. | Min. | Max. | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Dispersion in normalized MRPK | 1,954 | 0.575 | 0.623 | 0.000 | 4.121 |
Private debt (% of GDP) | 1,986 | 131.3 | 65.56 | 21.35 | 289.1 |
Corporate debt (% of GDP) | 1,986 | 82.57 | 37.32 | 12.75 | 176.7 |
Household debt (% of GDP) | 1,986 | 48.76 | 32.81 | 1.513 | 139.4 |
Public debt (% of GDP) | 1,986 | 57.77 | 27.47 | 11.88 | 131.8 |
Chinn-Ito capital account openness index | 1,986 | 0.895 | 0.187 | 0.166 | 1 |
Long-term interest rate (%) | 1,918 | 4.394 | 1.920 | 0.575 | 14.00 |
Government consumption (% of GDP) | 1,986 | 20.94 | 2.837 | 13.74 | 27.94 |
Taxes on income, prof. & cap. gains (% of GDP) | 1,986 | 10.99 | 6.061 | 4.297 | 32.26 |
Trade (% of GDP) | 1,986 | 103.8 | 36.91 | 45.61 | 184.3 |
Average real turnover | 1,959 | 12,558 | 9,714 | 1,071 | 59,121 |
Index of political institutions quality | 1,986 | 21.97 | 3.436 | 14 | 28 |
External finance dependence | 1,986 | 0.417 | 0.293 | 0 | 1 |
Average credit constraints | 1,637 | 0.120 | 0.064 | 0.0196 | 0.316 |
Indicator of R&D intensity | 1,986 | 0.348 | 0.386 | 0 | 1 |
Dispersion of credit constraints | 1,637 | 0.301 | 0.073 | 0.137 | 0.464 |
De Loecker-Warzynski markups | 1,685 | 34.65 | 115.05 | 0.081 | 855.3 |
Skewness of TFP distribution | 1,954 | 5.723 | 7.145 | 0.532 | 58.06 |
Appendix C Robustness Checks
Debt-to-GDP ratios and capital misallocation: One-step system GMM regressions
Interacting variable | Financial dependence | Average credit constraints | Technological intensity | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | |
ln(Private Debt) × Interaction (lagged) | 0.612*** (0.223) | 0.601** (0.271) | 1.777* (0.947) | 1.807* (0.970) | 0.712*** (0.247) | 0.683** (0.291) |
ln(Public Debt) × Interaction (lagged) | −0.399* (0.228) | −0.451* (0.244) | −1.135 (0.875) | −1.074 (0.828) | −0.364* (0.195) | −0.367* (0.216) |
Capit. Acc. Openness × Interaction (lagged) | −1.322** (0.640) | −1.336* (0.724) | −3.602 (3.079) | −3.342 (3.426) | −1.289** (0.540) | −1.201* (0.615) |
LT Interest Rate × Interaction | −0.048* (0.025) | −0.037 (0.032) | −0.228** (0.105) | −0.213* (0.119) | −0.059*** (0.019) | −0.057*** (0.019) |
ln(Govt. Consump.) × Interaction | 0.001 (0.582) | 0.130 (0.776) | 1.195 (2.465) | 1.056 (2.706) | −0.131 (0.569) | −0.065 (0.642) |
ln(Taxes on IPC) × Interaction | 0.264 (0.290) | 0.172 (0.310) | 0.091 (1.054) | 0.017 (1.144) | −0.188 (0.209) | −0.211 (0.211) |
ln(Trade) × Interaction | 0.472** (0.214) | 0.531** (0.253) | 1.135 (0.867) | 1.071 (0.893) | 0.277 (0.227) | 0.275 (0.243) |
ln(Avg. Real Turnover) | 0.232** (0.118) | 0.291 (0.179) | 0.422** (0.177) | 0.372* (0.208) | 0.194 (0.154) | 0.203 (0.165) |
Institut. Quality × Interaction | −0.131*** (0.025) | −0.144*** (0.028) | −0.389*** (0.117) | −0.399*** (0.127) | −0.058*** (0.022) | −0.062*** (0.022) |
Constant | −1.464 (1.109) | −1.983 (1.669) | −3.316* (1.741) | −2.808 (2.034) | −1.077 (1.378) | −1.163 (1.474) |
Observations | 1,759 | 1,759 | 1,446 | 1,446 | 1,759 | 1,759 |
Instrument count | 134 | 91 | 129 | 91 | 134 | 91 |
AR(1) test p-value | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 |
AR(2) test p-value | 0.441 | 0.443 | 0.603 | 0.586 | 0.423 | 0.422 |
Hansen test p-value | 1.000 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 1.000 |
Standard errors in parentheses. *p < 0.1; **p < 0.05; and ***p < 0.01.
Debt-to-GDP ratios and capital misallocation: excluding Germany and Spain
Interacting variable | Financial dependence | Average credit constraints | Technological intensity | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | |
Estimation | FE | FE | Sys-GMM | FE | FE | Sys-GMM | FE | FE | Sys-GMM |
ln(Private Debt) × Interaction (lagged) | 1.039*** (0.147) | 1.039*** (0.260) | 0.670*** (0.224) | 3.627*** (0.881) | 3.627*** (0.914) | 1.940** (0.831) | 0.627*** (0.211) | 0.627*** (0.166) | 0.705*** (0.258) |
ln(Public Debt) × Interaction (lagged) | −0.017 (0.213) | −0.017 (0.204) | −0.442** (0.223) | 0.023 (1.179) | 0.023 (0.775) | −1.069 (0.856) | 0.127 (0.266) | 0.127 (0.097) | −0.376* (0.196) |
Capit. Acc. Openness × Interaction (lagged) | −1.110** (0.448) | −1.110*** (0.303) | −1.380** (0.635) | −3.346 (3.200) | −3.346 (2.545) | −4.432 (3.289) | −0.531* (0.292) | −0.531*** (0.152) | −1.255** (0.538) |
LT Interest Rate × Interaction | −0.055** (0.022) | −0.055*** (0.012) | −0.046* (0.025) | −0.193 (0.110) | −0.193** (0.067) | −0.189** (0.091) | −0.018 (0.018) | −0.018 (0.023) | −0.050** (0.020) |
ln(Govt. Consump.) × Interaction | −0.092 (0.889) | −0.092 (1.205) | 0.069 (0.575) | 1.074 (2.615) | 1.074 (4.052) | 1.809 (2.546) | 0.334 (0.545) | 0.334 (0.780) | −0.090 (0.537) |
ln(Taxes on IPC) × Interaction | −0.090 (0.362) | −0.090 (0.341) | 0.280 (0.306) | 0.385 (1.473) | 0.385 (0.916) | 0.401 (1.026) | −0.126 (0.269) | −0.126 (0.264) | −0.100 (0.206) |
ln(Trade) × Interaction | −0.300 (0.639) | −0.300 (0.627) | 0.399* (0.206) | 0.303 (2.908) | 0.303 (2.486) | 0.461 (0.822) | 0.551 (0.633) | 0.551 (0.467) | 0.258 (0.206) |
ln(Avg. Real Turnover) | 0.080 (0.090) | 0.080 (0.129) | 0.194 (0.127) | 0.065 (0.097) | 0.065 (0.164) | 0.333** (0.135) | 0.119 (0.096) | 0.119 (0.121) | 0.197 (0.138) |
Institut. Quality × Interaction | −0.039 (0.053) | −0.039 (0.038) | −0.129*** (0.025) | −0.057 (0.219) | −0.057 (0.163) | −0.380*** (0.118) | 0.005 (0.037) | 0.005 (0.013) | −0.068*** (0.022) |
Constant | −0.514 (2.491) | −0.514 (2.568) | −1.125 (1.194) | −2.066 (2.707) | −2.066 (2.692) | −2.515* (1.335) | −2.674** (1.232) | −2.674** (0.987) | −1.110 (1.235) |
Standard errors | Clustered (country) | HAC (Driscoll-Kraay) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | HAC (Driscoll-Kraay) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | HAC (Driscoll-Kraay) | Clustered (country) |
Observations | 1,696 | 1,696 | 1,696 | 1,383 | 1,383 | 1,383 | 1,696 | 1,696 | 1,696 |
Standard errors in parentheses. *p < 0.1; **p < 0.05; and ***p < 0.01.
Debt-to-GDP ratios and capital misallocation: interaction with alternative sectoral indicators
Interacting variable | Dispersion of credit constraints | De Loecker-Warzynski (2012) Markups | Skewness of TFP distribution | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | |
Estimation | FE | FE | Sys-GMM | FE | FE | Sys-GMM | FE | FE | Sys-GMM |
ln(Private Debt) × Interaction (lagged) | 1.390*** (0.415) | 1.390*** (0.282) | 1.273*** (0.283) | 0.238** (0.092) | 0.238*** (0.074) | 0.196*** (0.067) | 0.060*** (0.017) | 0.060*** (0.009) | 0.064*** (0.021) |
ln(Public Debt) × Interaction (lagged) | 0.384 (0.533) | 0.384 (0.264) | −0.172 (0.313) | 0.130 (0.079) | 0.130** (0.046) | 0.038 (0.036) | 0.010 (0.022) | 0.010 (0.008) | 0.014 (0.019) |
Capit. Acc. Openness × Interaction (lagged) | −1.265 (1.430) | −1.265 (0.883) | −3.042** (1.299) | −0.203 (0.152) | −0.203 (0.124) | −0.200 (0.255) | −0.096** (0.045) | −0.096*** (0.021) | −0.107** (0.052) |
LT Interest Rate × Interaction | −0.079** (0.032) | −0.079** (0.033) | −0.103*** (0.034) | −0.004 (0.006) | −0.004 (0.004) | −0.015** (0.008) | −0.003 (0.002) | −0.003 (0.002) | −0.004** (0.002) |
ln(Govt. Consump.) × Interaction | 1.516 (1.938) | 1.516 (1.542) | 0.113 (1.214) | −0.272 (0.254) | −0.272 (0.170) | −0.552*** (0.200) | −0.058 (0.072) | −0.058 (0.061) | −0.090*** (0.028) |
ln(Taxes on IPC) × Interaction | 0.067 (0.195) | 0.067 (0.084) | −0.031 (0.238) | −0.079 (0.103) | −0.079 (0.092) | −0.030 (0.049) | −0.033* (0.019) | −0.033** (0.014) | −0.027 (0.019) |
ln(Trade) × Interaction | 1.062 (1.533) | 1.062 (0.930) | −0.148 (0.369) | 0.176 (0.182) | 0.176 (0.116) | 0.185*** (0.072) | 0.022 (0.029) | 0.022 (0.022) | 0.011 (0.015) |
ln(Avg. Real Turnover) | 0.063 (0.081) | 0.063 (0.141) | 0.085 (0.115) | 0.072 (0.096) | 0.072 (0.083) | 0.254 (0.174) | 0.046 (0.085) | 0.046 (0.100) | 0.195 (0.141) |
Institut. Quality × Interaction | 0.014 (0.085) | 0.014 (0.047) | −0.139** (0.058) | 0.005 (0.011) | 0.005 (0.005) | 0.004 (0.007) | 0.002 (0.002) | 0.002* (0.001) | 0.001 (0.001) |
Constant | −4.980 (3.756) | −4.980 (2.879) | 0.175 (1.184) | −1.877 (2.173) | −1.877 (1.477) | −1.766 (1.607) | −0.461 (1.476) | −0.461 (1.317) | −1.085 (1.306) |
Standard errors | Clustered (country) | HAC (Driscoll-Kraay) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | HAC (Driscoll-Kraay) | Clustered (country) | Clustered (country) | HAC (Driscoll-Kraay) | Clustered (country) |
Observations | 1,343 | 1,343 | 1,343 | 1,497 | 1,497 | 1,497 | 1,759 | 1,759 | 1,759 |
Standard errors in parentheses. *p < 0.1; **p < 0.05; and ***p < 0.01.
Note: All of the sectoral-level interacting variables are averaged over the available time period for each country-sector to make them time-invariant. I take the natural logarithm of the De Loecker and Warzynski (2012) measure of average markup before interacting it with the country-level variables.
References
Abraham, F., & Schmukler, S. (2017). Addressing the SME finance problem. Research and Policy Briefs No. 9. World Bank.Search in Google Scholar
Aghion, P., Bergeaud, A., Cette, G., Lecat, R., & Maghin, H. (2019). Coase lecture – the inverted-U relationship between credit access and productivity growth. Economica, 86, 1–31.10.1111/ecca.12297Search in Google Scholar
Alimov, B. (2019). Private debt, public debt, and capital misallocation. IWH-CompNet Discussion Papers 7/2019. Halle Institute for Economic Research (IWH).Search in Google Scholar
Anderson, G., & Raissi, M. (2022). Corporate indebtedness and low productivity growth of Italian firms. In A. Chudik, C. Hsiao, & A. Timmermann (Eds.), Essays in honor of M. Hashem Pesaran: Panel modeling, micro applications, and econometric methodology (Advances in Econometrics (Vol. 43B, pp. 205–228). Emerald Publishing Limited.10.1108/S0731-90532021000043B009Search in Google Scholar
Arcand, J. L., Berkes, E., & Panizza, U. (2015). Too much finance?. Journal of Economic Growth, 20, 105–148.10.1007/s10887-015-9115-2Search in Google Scholar
Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58, 277–297.10.2307/2297968Search in Google Scholar
Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 29–51.10.1016/0304-4076(94)01642-DSearch in Google Scholar
Asker, J., Collard-Wexler, A., & De Loecker, J. (2014). Dynamic inputs and resource (mis) allocation. Journal of Political Economy, 122, 1013–1063.10.1086/677072Search in Google Scholar
Bai, Y., Jin, K., & Lu, D. (2019). Misallocation under trade liberalization. NBER Working Papers 26188.10.3386/w26188Search in Google Scholar
Banerjee, R. (2014). SMEs, financial constraints and growth. BIS Working Papers 475.Search in Google Scholar
Basco, S., Lopez-Rodriguez, D., & Moral-Benito, E. (2025). House prices and misallocation: The impact of the collateral channel on productivity. The Economic Journal, 135, 1–35.10.1093/ej/ueae075Search in Google Scholar
Baum, A., Checherita-Westphal, C., & Rother, P. (2013). Debt and growth: New evidence for the Euro Area. Journal of International Money and Finance, 32, 809–821.10.1016/j.jimonfin.2012.07.004Search in Google Scholar
Beck, T., Levine, R., & Loayza, N. (2000). Finance and the sources of growth. Journal of Financial Economics, 58, 261–300.10.1016/S0304-405X(00)00072-6Search in Google Scholar
Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87, 115–143.10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8Search in Google Scholar
Borio, C., Kharroubi, E., Upper, C., & Zampolli, F. (2015). Labour reallocation and productivity dynamics: Financial causes, real consequences. BIS Working Papers 534.Search in Google Scholar
Bremus, F. M. (2015). The debate about financing constraints of SMEs in Europe. DIW Roundup: Politik im Fokus 66, DIW Berlin, German Institute for Economic Research.Search in Google Scholar
Buera, F. J., Kaboski, J. P., & Shin, Y. (2011). Finance and development: A tale of two sectors. American Economic Review, 101, 1964–2002.10.1257/aer.101.5.1964Search in Google Scholar
Caggese, A., & Pérez-Orive, A. (2019). Capital misallocation and secular stagnation. Barcelona GSE Working Papers 1056.Search in Google Scholar
Calligaris, S., Del Gatto, M., Hassan, F., Ottaviano, G. I., & Schivardi, F. (2018). The productivity puzzle and misallocation: An Italian perspective. Economic Policy, 33, 635–684.10.1093/epolic/eiy014Search in Google Scholar
Caner, M., Fan, Q., & Grennes, T. (2021). Partners in debt: An endogenous non-linear analysis of the effects of public and private debt on growth. International Review of Economics & Finance, 76, 694–711.10.1016/j.iref.2021.07.010Search in Google Scholar
Carpenter, R., & Petersen, B. (2002). Capital market imperfections, high-tech investment, and new equity financing. The Economic Journal, 112, F54–F72.10.1111/1468-0297.00683Search in Google Scholar
Caselli, F. (2005). Accounting for cross-country income differences. In P. Aghion & S. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of economic growth (Vol. I, pp. 679–741). North-Holland: Elsevier.10.1016/S1574-0684(05)01009-9Search in Google Scholar
Casey, E., & O’Toole, C. M. (2014). Bank lending constraints, trade credit and alternative financing during the financial crisis: Evidence from European SMEs. Journal of Corporate Finance, 27, 173–193.10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2014.05.001Search in Google Scholar
Cecchetti, S. G., & Kharroubi, E. (2019). Why does credit growth crowd out real economic growth?. The Manchester School, 87, 1–28.10.1111/manc.12295Search in Google Scholar
Cecchetti, S. G., Mohanty, M. S., & Zampolli, F. (2011). Achieving growth amid fiscal imbalances: The real effects of debt. Proceedings - Economic Policy Symposium - Jackson Hole (pp. 145–196). Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.Search in Google Scholar
Cette, G., Fernald, J., & Mojon, B. (2016). The pre-great recession slowdown in productivity. European Economic Review, 88, 3–20.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2016.03.012Search in Google Scholar
Checherita-Westphal, C., & Rother, P. (2012). The impact of high government debt on economic growth and its channels: An empirical investigation for the Euro Area. European Economic Review, 56, 1392–1405.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2012.06.007Search in Google Scholar
Chinn, M. D., & Ito, H. (2006). What matters for financial development? Capital controls, institutions, and interactions. Journal of Development Economics, 81, 163–192.10.1016/j.jdeveco.2005.05.010Search in Google Scholar
Chudik, A., Mohaddes, K., Pesaran, M. H., & Raissi, M. (2017). Is there a debt-threshold effect on output growth?. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 99, 135–150.10.1162/REST_a_00593Search in Google Scholar
De Loecker, J., & Warzynski, F. (2012). Markups and firm-level export status. American Economic Review, 102, 2437–2471.10.1257/aer.102.6.2437Search in Google Scholar
Deng, J., & Liu, Q. (2024). Good finance, bad finance, and resource misallocation: Evidence from China. Journal of Banking and Finance, 159, 107078.10.1016/j.jbankfin.2023.107078Search in Google Scholar
Deng, G., Zhou, C., Wang, D., & Zhou, W. (2023). Local government debt, resource misallocation, and green total factor productivity in China. Frontiers in Environmental Science, 11, 1257912.10.3389/fenvs.2023.1257912Search in Google Scholar
Dias, D. A., Marques, C. R., & Richmond, C. (2020). A tale of two sectors: Why is misallocation higher in services than in manufacturing?. The Review of Income and Wealth, 66, 361–393.10.1111/roiw.12416Search in Google Scholar
D’Ignazio, A., & Menon, C. (2020). Causal effect of credit guarantees for small‐ and medium‐sized enterprises: Evidence from Italy. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 122, 191–218.10.1111/sjoe.12332Search in Google Scholar
Doerr, S. (2020). Housing booms, reallocation and productivity. BIS Working Papers 904. Bank for International Settlements.Search in Google Scholar
Driscoll, J. C., & Kraay, A. C. (1998). Consistent covariance matrix estimation with spatially dependent panel data. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 80, 549–560.10.1162/003465398557825Search in Google Scholar
Durnev, A. (2010). The real effects of political uncertainty: Elections and investment sensitivity to stock prices. SSRN Electronic Journal. https://ssrn.com/abstract=1549714.10.2139/ssrn.1549714Search in Google Scholar
Edmond, C., Midrigan, V., & Xu, D. Y. (2015). Competition, markups, and the gains from international trade. American Economic Review, 105, 3183–3221.10.1257/aer.20120549Search in Google Scholar
Fauceglia, D. (2015). Credit constraints, firm exports and financial development: Evidence from developing countries. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 55, 53–66.10.1016/j.qref.2014.08.003Search in Google Scholar
Franco, G. (2018). Misallocation and the credit cycle: Evidence from Europe. SSRN Electronic Journal. https://ssrn.com/abstract=3140282.10.2139/ssrn.3140282Search in Google Scholar
Gamberoni, E., Giordano, C., & Lopez-Garcia, P. (2016). Capital and labour (Mis)allocation in the Euro Area: Some stylized facts and determinants. ECB Working Paper Series 1981.10.2139/ssrn.2910947Search in Google Scholar
Gilchrist, S., Sim, J. W., & Zakrajsek, E. (2013). Misallocation and financial market frictions: Some direct evidence from the dispersion in borrowing costs. Review of Economic Dynamics, 16, 159–176.10.1016/j.red.2012.11.001Search in Google Scholar
Gomis, R. M., & Khatiwada, S. (2017). Debt and productivity: Evidence from firm-level data (No. HEIDWP04-2017). The Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies, Working Paper.Search in Google Scholar
Gopinath, G., Kalemli-Özcan, Ş., Karabarbounis, L., & Villegas-Sanchez, C. (2017). Capital allocation and productivity in South Europe. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 132, 1915–1967.10.1093/qje/qjx024Search in Google Scholar
Hall, R. E., & Jones, C. I. (1999). Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others?. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 83–116.10.1162/003355399555954Search in Google Scholar
Haltiwanger, J., Kulick, R., & Syverson, C. (2018). Misallocation measures: The distortion that ate the residual. NBER Working Papers 24199.10.3386/w24199Search in Google Scholar
Hassan, T. A., Hollander, S., Van Lent, L., & Tahoun, A. (2019). Firm-level political risk: Measurement and effects. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 134, 2135–2202.10.1093/qje/qjz021Search in Google Scholar
Herndon, T., Ash, M., & Pollin, R. (2014). Does high public debt consistently stifle economic growth? A critique of Reinhart and Rogoff. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 38, 257–279.10.1093/cje/bet075Search in Google Scholar
Hoechle, D. (2007). Robust standard errors for panel regressions with cross-sectional dependence. The Stata Journal, 7, 281–312.10.1177/1536867X0700700301Search in Google Scholar
Holtz-Eakin, D., Newey, W., & Rosen, H. S. (1988). Estimating vector autoregressions with panel data. Econometrica, 56, 1371–1395.10.2307/1913103Search in Google Scholar
Hsieh, C., & Klenow, P. J. (2009). Misallocation and manufacturing TFP in China and India. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124, 1403–1448.10.1162/qjec.2009.124.4.1403Search in Google Scholar
Hsieh, C., & Klenow, P. J. (2010). Development accounting. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2, 207–223.10.1257/mac.2.1.207Search in Google Scholar
Huang, H., & Lin, S. (2009). Non-linear finance–growth nexus. A threshold with instrumental variable approach. Economics of Transition, 17, 439–466.10.1111/j.1468-0351.2009.00360.xSearch in Google Scholar
Jackowicz, K., & Kozłowski, Ł. (2019). Social ties between SME managers and bank employees: Financial consequences vs SME managers’ perceptions. Emerging Markets Review, 40, 100619.10.1016/j.ememar.2019.05.004Search in Google Scholar
Jordà, Ò., Schularick, M., & Taylor, A. M. (2011). Financial crises, credit booms, and external imbalances: 140 years of lessons. IMF Economic Review, 59, 340–378.10.1057/imfer.2011.8Search in Google Scholar
Jordà, Ò., Schularick, M., & Taylor, A. M. (2013). When credit bites back. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 45, 3–28.10.1111/jmcb.12069Search in Google Scholar
Jordà, Ò., Schularick, M., & Taylor, A. M. (2015a). Betting the house. Journal of International Economics, 96, 2–18.10.1016/j.jinteco.2014.12.011Search in Google Scholar
Jordà, Ò., Schularick, M., & Taylor, A. M. (2015b). Sovereigns versus banks: Credit, crises, and consequences. Journal of the European Economic Association, 14, 45–79.10.1111/jeea.12144Search in Google Scholar
Karadam, D. Y. (2018). An investigation of nonlinear effects of debt on growth. The Journal of Economic Asymmetries, 18, e00097.10.1016/j.jeca.2018.e00097Search in Google Scholar
Kay, N., Murphy, G., O’Toole, C., Siedschlag, I., & O’Connell, B. (2014). Do all firms have equal access to external financing?. VOX – CEPR Policy Portal. https://voxeu.org/article/financial-markets-and-sme-investment-dearth.Search in Google Scholar
Kehrig, M. (2015). The cyclical nature of the productivity distribution. SSRN Electronic Journal. https://ssrn.com/abstract=1854401.Search in Google Scholar
Kim, M., & Maksimovic, V. (1990). Debt and input misallocation. The Journal of Finance, 45, 795–816.10.1111/j.1540-6261.1990.tb05106.xSearch in Google Scholar
Kim, H., Mathur, V., Shin, J. K., & Subramanian, C. (2023). Misallocation of debt and aggregate productivity. Journal of Corporate Finance, 83, 102493.10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2023.102493Search in Google Scholar
King, R. G., & Levine, R. (1993). Finance and growth: Schumpeter might be right. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 717–737.10.2307/2118406Search in Google Scholar
Klenow, P., & Rodriguez-Clare, A. (1997). The neoclassical revival in growth economics: Has it gone too far?. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 12, 73–114.10.2307/3585220Search in Google Scholar
Kobayashi, K., & Shirai, D. (2018). Debt-ridden borrowers and economic slowdown. The Canon Institute for Global Studies Working Paper Series 18-003E.Search in Google Scholar
Kumar, R. (2017). Targeted SME financing and employment effects: What do we know and what can we do differently?. Jobs Working Paper 3. World Bank Group.Search in Google Scholar
Larrain, M., & Stumpner, S. (2017). Capital account liberalization and aggregate productivity: The role of firm capital allocation. The Journal of Finance, 72, 1825–1858.10.1111/jofi.12497Search in Google Scholar
Law, S. H., & Singh, N. (2014). Does too much finance harm economic growth?. Journal of Banking and Finance, 41, 36–44.10.1016/j.jbankfin.2013.12.020Search in Google Scholar
León-Ledesma, M. A., & Christopoulos, D. (2016). Misallocation, access to finance, and public credit: Firm-level evidence. Asian Development Review, 33, 119–143.10.1162/ADEV_a_00075Search in Google Scholar
Levine, R., Loayza, N., & Beck, T. (2000). Financial intermediation and growth: Causality and causes. Journal of Monetary Economics, 46, 31–77.10.1016/S0304-3932(00)00017-9Search in Google Scholar
Levinsohn, J., & Petrin, A. (2003). Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables. Review of Economic Studies, 70, 317–341.10.1111/1467-937X.00246Search in Google Scholar
Lopez-Garcia, P., Di Mauro, F. (2015). Assessing European competitiveness: The new CompNet micro-based database. ECB Working Paper 1764.10.2139/ssrn.2578954Search in Google Scholar
Marconi, D., & Upper, C. (2017). Capital misallocation and financial development: A sector-level analysis. BIS Working Papers 671.10.2139/ssrn.3066694Search in Google Scholar
McNabb, K. (2018). Tax structures and economic growth: New evidence from the government revenue dataset. Journal of International Development, 30, 173–205.10.1002/jid.3345Search in Google Scholar
Mian, A., & Sufi, A. (2010). Household leverage and the recession of 2007–09. IMF Economic Review, 58, 74–117.10.1057/imfer.2010.2Search in Google Scholar
Mian, A., Sufi, A., & Verner, E. (2017). Household debt and business cycles worldwide. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 132, 1755–1817.10.1093/qje/qjx017Search in Google Scholar
Miao, J., & Wang, P. (2014). Sectoral bubbles, misallocation, and endogenous growth. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 53, 153–163.10.1016/j.jmateco.2013.12.003Search in Google Scholar
Midrigan, V., & Xu, D. Y. (2014). Finance and misallocation: Evidence from plant-level data. American Economic Review, 104, 422–458.10.1257/aer.104.2.422Search in Google Scholar
Moll, B. (2014). Productivity losses from financial frictions: Can self-financing undo capital misallocation?. American Economic Review, 104, 3186–3221.10.1257/aer.104.10.3186Search in Google Scholar
Monacelli, T., & Sala, L. (2018). Real interest rates and productivity in small open economies. CEPR Discussion Papers 12808.10.2139/ssrn.3308438Search in Google Scholar
Olley, G. S., & Pakes, A. (1996). The dynamics of productivity in the telecommunications equipment industry. Econometrica, 64, 1263–1297.10.2307/2171831Search in Google Scholar
Panizza, U., & Presbitero, A. F. (2014). Public debt and economic growth: Is there a causal effect?. Journal of Macroeconomics, 41, 21–41.10.1016/j.jmacro.2014.03.009Search in Google Scholar
Pannella, P. (2020). Credit bubbles and misallocation. Mimeo, São Paulo School of Economics.Search in Google Scholar
Pesaran, M. H. (2004). General diagnostic tests for cross section dependence in panels. Cambridge Working Papers in Economics 0435. Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge.10.2139/ssrn.572504Search in Google Scholar
Rajan, R. G., & Zingales, L. (1998). Financial dependence and growth. American Economic Review, 88, 559–586.Search in Google Scholar
Ramey, V. A., & Shapiro, M. D. (1998). Costly capital reallocation and the effects of government spending. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 48, 145–194.10.1016/S0167-2231(98)00020-7Search in Google Scholar
Reinhart, C. M., Reinhart, V. R., & Rogoff, K. S. (2012). Public debt overhangs: Advanced-economy episodes since 1800. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26, 69–86.10.1257/jep.26.3.69Search in Google Scholar
Reinhart, C. M., & Rogoff, K. S. (2009). This time is different. Eight centuries of financial folly. Princeton University Press.10.1515/9781400831722Search in Google Scholar
Reinhart, C. M., & Rogoff, K. S. (2010). Growth in a time of debt. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 100, 573–578.10.1257/aer.100.2.573Search in Google Scholar
Reinhart, C. M., & Rogoff, K. S. (2011). A decade of debt. Peterson Institute for International Economics, Policy Analyses in International Economics, 95.10.3386/w16827Search in Google Scholar
Restuccia, D., & Rogerson, R. (2008). Policy distortions and aggregate productivity with heterogeneous establishments. Review of Economic Dynamics, 11, 707–720.10.1016/j.red.2008.05.002Search in Google Scholar
Restuccia, D., & Rogerson, R. (2017). The causes and costs of misallocation. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 31, 151–174.10.1257/jep.31.3.151Search in Google Scholar
Roodman, D. (2009). A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71, 135–158.10.1111/j.1468-0084.2008.00542.xSearch in Google Scholar
Rousseau, P. L., & Wachtel, P. (2011). What is happening to the impact of financial deepening on economic growth. Economic Inquiry, 49, 276–288.10.1111/j.1465-7295.2009.00197.xSearch in Google Scholar
Salotti, S., & Trecroci, C. (2016). The impact of government debt, expenditure and taxes on aggregate investment and productivity growth. Economica, 83, 356–384.10.1111/ecca.12175Search in Google Scholar
Schularick, M., & Taylor, A. M. (2012). Credit booms gone bust: Monetary policy, leverage cycles, and financial crises, 1870–2008. American Economic Review, 102, 1029–1061.10.1257/aer.102.2.1029Search in Google Scholar
Shen, C., & Lee, C. (2006). Same financial development yet different economic growth – Why?. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 38, 1907–1944.10.1353/mcb.2006.0095Search in Google Scholar
Woo, J., & Kumar, M. S. (2015). Public debt and growth. Economica, 82, 705–739.10.1111/ecca.12138Search in Google Scholar
Wooldridge, J. M. (2009). On estimating firm-level production functions using proxy variables to control for unobservables. Economics Letters, 104, 112–114.10.1016/j.econlet.2009.04.026Search in Google Scholar
Yang, L., & Su, J. (2018). Debt and growth: Is there a constant tipping point?. Journal of International Money and Finance, 87, 133–143.10.1016/j.jimonfin.2018.06.002Search in Google Scholar
© 2025 the author(s), published by De Gruyter
This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.
Articles in the same Issue
- Research Articles
- Research on the Coupled Coordination of the Digital Economy and Environmental Quality
- Optimal Consumption and Portfolio Choices with Housing Dynamics
- Regional Space–time Differences and Dynamic Evolution Law of Real Estate Financial Risk in China
- Financial Inclusion, Financial Depth, and Macroeconomic Fluctuations
- Harnessing the Digital Economy for Sustainable Energy Efficiency: An Empirical Analysis of China’s Yangtze River Delta
- Estimating the Size of Fiscal Multipliers in the WAEMU Area
- Impact of Green Credit on the Performance of Commercial Banks: Evidence from 42 Chinese Listed Banks
- Rethinking the Theoretical Foundation of Economics II: Core Themes of the Multilevel Paradigm
- Spillover Nexus among Green Cryptocurrency, Sectoral Renewable Energy Equity Stock and Agricultural Commodity: Implications for Portfolio Diversification
- Cultural Catalysts of FinTech: Baring Long-Term Orientation and Indulgent Cultures in OECD Countries
- Loan Loss Provisions and Bank Value in the United States: A Moderation Analysis of Economic Policy Uncertainty
- Collaboration Dynamics in Legislative Co-Sponsorship Networks: Evidence from Korea
- Does Fintech Improve the Risk-Taking Capacity of Commercial Banks? Empirical Evidence from China
- Multidimensional Poverty in Rural China: Human Capital vs Social Capital
- Property Registration and Economic Growth: Evidence from Colonial Korea
- More Philanthropy, More Consistency? Examining the Impact of Corporate Charitable Donations on ESG Rating Uncertainty
- Can Urban “Gold Signboards” Yield Carbon Reduction Dividends? A Quasi-Natural Experiment Based on the “National Civilized City” Selection
- How GVC Embeddedness Affects Firms’ Innovation Level: Evidence from Chinese Listed Companies
- The Measurement and Decomposition Analysis of Inequality of Opportunity in China’s Educational Outcomes
- The Role of Technology Intensity in Shaping Skilled Labor Demand Through Imports: The Case of Türkiye
- Legacy of the Past: Evaluating the Long-Term Impact of Historical Trade Ports on Contemporary Industrial Agglomeration in China
- Unveiling Ecological Unequal Exchange: The Role of Biophysical Flows as an Indicator of Ecological Exploitation in the North-South Relations
- Exchange Rate Pass-Through to Domestic Prices: Evidence Analysis of a Periphery Country
- Private Debt, Public Debt, and Capital Misallocation
- Impact of External Shocks on Global Major Stock Market Interdependence: Insights from Vine-Copula Modeling
- Informal Finance and Enterprise Digital Transformation
- Wealth Effect of Asset Securitization in Real Estate and Infrastructure Sectors: Evidence from China
- Consumer Perception of Carbon Labels on Cross-Border E-Commerce Products and its Influencing Factors: An Empirical Study in Hangzhou
- Redefining Workplace Integration: Socio-Economic Synergies in Adaptive Career Ecosystems and Stress Resilience – Institutional Innovation for Empowering Newcomers Through Social Capital and Human-Centric Automation
- Review Article
- Bank Syndication – A Premise for Increasing Bank Performance or Diversifying Risks?
- Special Issue: The Economics of Green Innovation: Financing And Response To Climate Change
- A Bibliometric Analysis of Digital Financial Inclusion: Current Trends and Future Directions
- Targeted Poverty Alleviation and Enterprise Innovation: The Mediating Effect of Talent and Financing Constraints
- Special Issue: EMI 2025
- Digital Transformation of the Accounting Profession at the Intersection of Artificial Intelligence and Ethics
- The Role of Generative Artificial Intelligence in Shaping Business Innovation: Insights from End Users’ Perspectives and Practices
- Special Issue: The Path to Sustainable And Acceptable Transportation
- Factors Influencing Environmentally Friendly Air Travel: A Systematic, Mixed-Method Review
Articles in the same Issue
- Research Articles
- Research on the Coupled Coordination of the Digital Economy and Environmental Quality
- Optimal Consumption and Portfolio Choices with Housing Dynamics
- Regional Space–time Differences and Dynamic Evolution Law of Real Estate Financial Risk in China
- Financial Inclusion, Financial Depth, and Macroeconomic Fluctuations
- Harnessing the Digital Economy for Sustainable Energy Efficiency: An Empirical Analysis of China’s Yangtze River Delta
- Estimating the Size of Fiscal Multipliers in the WAEMU Area
- Impact of Green Credit on the Performance of Commercial Banks: Evidence from 42 Chinese Listed Banks
- Rethinking the Theoretical Foundation of Economics II: Core Themes of the Multilevel Paradigm
- Spillover Nexus among Green Cryptocurrency, Sectoral Renewable Energy Equity Stock and Agricultural Commodity: Implications for Portfolio Diversification
- Cultural Catalysts of FinTech: Baring Long-Term Orientation and Indulgent Cultures in OECD Countries
- Loan Loss Provisions and Bank Value in the United States: A Moderation Analysis of Economic Policy Uncertainty
- Collaboration Dynamics in Legislative Co-Sponsorship Networks: Evidence from Korea
- Does Fintech Improve the Risk-Taking Capacity of Commercial Banks? Empirical Evidence from China
- Multidimensional Poverty in Rural China: Human Capital vs Social Capital
- Property Registration and Economic Growth: Evidence from Colonial Korea
- More Philanthropy, More Consistency? Examining the Impact of Corporate Charitable Donations on ESG Rating Uncertainty
- Can Urban “Gold Signboards” Yield Carbon Reduction Dividends? A Quasi-Natural Experiment Based on the “National Civilized City” Selection
- How GVC Embeddedness Affects Firms’ Innovation Level: Evidence from Chinese Listed Companies
- The Measurement and Decomposition Analysis of Inequality of Opportunity in China’s Educational Outcomes
- The Role of Technology Intensity in Shaping Skilled Labor Demand Through Imports: The Case of Türkiye
- Legacy of the Past: Evaluating the Long-Term Impact of Historical Trade Ports on Contemporary Industrial Agglomeration in China
- Unveiling Ecological Unequal Exchange: The Role of Biophysical Flows as an Indicator of Ecological Exploitation in the North-South Relations
- Exchange Rate Pass-Through to Domestic Prices: Evidence Analysis of a Periphery Country
- Private Debt, Public Debt, and Capital Misallocation
- Impact of External Shocks on Global Major Stock Market Interdependence: Insights from Vine-Copula Modeling
- Informal Finance and Enterprise Digital Transformation
- Wealth Effect of Asset Securitization in Real Estate and Infrastructure Sectors: Evidence from China
- Consumer Perception of Carbon Labels on Cross-Border E-Commerce Products and its Influencing Factors: An Empirical Study in Hangzhou
- Redefining Workplace Integration: Socio-Economic Synergies in Adaptive Career Ecosystems and Stress Resilience – Institutional Innovation for Empowering Newcomers Through Social Capital and Human-Centric Automation
- Review Article
- Bank Syndication – A Premise for Increasing Bank Performance or Diversifying Risks?
- Special Issue: The Economics of Green Innovation: Financing And Response To Climate Change
- A Bibliometric Analysis of Digital Financial Inclusion: Current Trends and Future Directions
- Targeted Poverty Alleviation and Enterprise Innovation: The Mediating Effect of Talent and Financing Constraints
- Special Issue: EMI 2025
- Digital Transformation of the Accounting Profession at the Intersection of Artificial Intelligence and Ethics
- The Role of Generative Artificial Intelligence in Shaping Business Innovation: Insights from End Users’ Perspectives and Practices
- Special Issue: The Path to Sustainable And Acceptable Transportation
- Factors Influencing Environmentally Friendly Air Travel: A Systematic, Mixed-Method Review