Home Malliavin method for optimal investment in financial markets with memory
Article Open Access

Malliavin method for optimal investment in financial markets with memory

  • Qiguang An , Guoqing Zhao and Gaofeng Zong EMAIL logo
Published/Copyright: May 19, 2016

Abstract

We consider a financial market with memory effects in which wealth processes are driven by mean-field stochastic Volterra equations. In this financial market, the classical dynamic programming method can not be used to study the optimal investment problem, because the solution of mean-field stochastic Volterra equation is not a Markov process. In this paper, a new method through Malliavin calculus introduced in [1], can be used to obtain the optimal investment in a Volterra type financial market. We show a sufficient and necessary condition for the optimal investment in this financial market with memory by mean-field stochastic maximum principle.

MSC 2010: 60H20; 60H30; 35K60

1 Models and introduction

Suppose we have a financial market with memory, in which there are two following investment opportunities:

  1. A risk-free asset with unit price S0 (t) = 1; It ≥ 1,

  2. A risky asset, in which investments have memory effects (or long term effects) and an infinite number of rational agents are in competition, in the following sense:

An investor can decide at time t ∈ [0, T] what amount u(t) of the current wealth X(t) to invest in the risky asset. The wealth process X(t) = Xu(t) at time t is described by the following controlled mean-field stochastic Volterra equation:

(1)X(t)=x+0tb(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s),ω)ds+0tσ(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s),ω)dB(s),

where B(t) denotes a standard Brownian motion in a probability space (Ω, 𝓕, P) with the natural filtration (𝓕t)t≥0, here P is the probability measure. Suppose that

b(t,s,x,x,u,ω):[0,T]×[0,T]×××𝕌×Ω

and

σ(t,s,x,x,u,ω):[0,T]×[0,T]×××𝕌×Ω

be 𝓕-adapted with respect to the second variable s for all t, x, x′, u and continuously differentiable with respect to the first variable t, with partial derivatives in L2([0, T]×[0, T]×ℝ×ℝ×Ω). Udenotes a given open set containing all possible admissible investment values u(t, ω) for (t, ω) ∈ ([0, T] × Ω, u ∈ 𝓤(x). Here suppose 𝓤 be a given family of (𝓖t)t≥0-predictable admissible investment, where 𝓖t ⊆ 𝓕t for all t ∈ ([0, T]. The introduction of 𝓤t illustrates that the admissible investment amount u is decided based on only partial information available to the investor, for instance, delayed information flow.

We rewrite the controlled mean-field stochastic Volterra equation above in the following differential form

(2)dX(t)=b(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))dt+(0tbt(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))ds)dt+σ(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))dB(t)+(0tσt(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))dB(s))dt.

From this differential form, we see that this mean-field stochastic Volterra equation differs from the mean-field stochastic differential equation, because of the two integral terms on the right hand side in (2). These terms represent memory effects of the investment u(·).

The mean-field investment performance functional is given by

(3)J(u)=E[0Tf(s,X(s),E[X(s)],u)(s))ds+g(X(T),E[X(T)])];u𝓤(x).

In contrast to the standard investment performance functional, the performance functional in this paper involves the mean of functions of the state variable, i.e. the mean-field term E([X(·)].

The optimal investment problem is to maximize the performance functional J(u) over all admissible investments, that is to find u * ∈ 𝓤(x) such that

(4)J(u)=supuUJ(u).

Given an initial wealth value x, we say that u* ∈ 𝓤(x) is an optimal investment if (4) holds.

Many papers have been devoted to the optimal investment problems. The seminal papers of [2, 3] considered the financial market modeled by a classical stochastic differential equation. Since then there have been many works concerning this subject. We refer to [4-6], for the complete market situation, to [7, 8] for constrained portfolios; to [9-13] for transactions costs; and to [14-17] for general incomplete markets.

However, to our knowledge, in all of these works, the financial markets have only one rational agent and the solutions of stochastic differential equations are Markov processes. The most natural framework to model the financial markets with an infinite number of rational agents in competition is the mean-field framework, which arise naturally in many applications. The systematic study of these problems was started, in the mathematical community by [18], and independently around the same time in the engineering community by [19, 20]. The well-known framework to model such non-Markov type solutions would be the stochastic Volterra equations where its solutions are not Markov processes. But this typically non-Markov property leads to invalidation of some methods, for instant, dynamic programming principle. In view of this, it is important to find good methods to solve the optimal investment problems for this type stochastic Volterra equations.

A good method to solve this optimal investment problem is Malliavin calculus, which has been firstly introduced in [1]. We refer to [21] for Malliavin calculus applied to optimal control of stochastic partial differential equations with jumps, and to [22] for Malliavin calculus applied to optimal control of stochastic Volterra equations but without the mean-field framework.

In the present paper following the idea of [22] we study the optimal investment problem in a finance market modeled by mean-field stochastic Volterra equation, in which both the financial market with an infinite number of rational agents in competition and non-Markov type solutions are all taken into account. The method of Malliavin calculus to solve this optimal investment problem in this paper is still adopted.

We present both a sufficient condition and a necessary condition for this optimal investment problem by mean-field stochastic maximum principle. Since the performance functional in this paper involves the mean-field term, in the proving process, we mainly use a new type of backward stochastic Volterra equations (BSVE), which is firstly studied in [23], and we refer the reader to [24, 25] for more discussions about this issue. The terminal condition and generator of this type of BSVE in this paper evolve into more complex forms because of the appearance of the mean-field term in the investment performance functional.

This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 recalls some definitions and properties about Malliavin calculus for Brownian motion. Section 3 is divided into two main parts: a sufficient and necessary conditions for optimal investment problem. An example is given in Section 4.

2 Malliavin calculus for Brownian motion

For reader’s convenience, we recall the basic definition and properties of Malliavin calculus for Brownian motion. For more details about Malliavin calculus see [26, 27]. A natural starting point is the Wiener-Itô chaos expansion theorem, which states that any ξ ∈ L2(𝓕 P) can be written as

ξ=n=0In(fn),

for a unique sequence of symmetric deterministic functions fnL2(Xn), where λ is a Lebesgue measure on [0; T] and

In(fn)=n!0T0tn0t2fn(t1,t2,,tn)dB(t1)dB(t2)dB(tn)

(the n-times iterated integral of fn with respect to B(·)) for n = 1; 2; … and I0(f0) = f0 when f0 is a constant.

Moreover, we have the isometry

E[ξ2]=ξL2(P)2=n=0n!fnL2(λn)2.

We first present the Malliavin derivative Dtξ with respect to Brownian motion B(·) at t of a given Malliavin differentiable random variable ξ(ω);ω ∈ Ω, and then we present some basic properties about Malliavin derivative related to this paper.

Let 𝔻 denote the set of all random variables which are Malliavin differentiable with respect to Brownian motion B(·), precisely, let 𝔻 be the space of all ξL2(𝓕, P) such that its chaos expansion satisfies

ξD2=n=1nn!fnL2(λn)2<.
Definition 2.1

For any ξ ∈𝔻, define the Malliavin derivative Dt(ξ) of ξ at t, t ∈ [0; T] with respect to Brownian motion B(·) as

Dt(ξ)=n=1nIn1(fn(,t)),
where the notation In–1(fn, t)) means that we apply the (n – 1)-times iterated integral to the first n – 1 variables t1, t2, …, tn–1of fn(t1, t2, , tn) and keep the last variable tn = t as a parameter.

It is easy to check that

E[0TDt(ξ)2dt]=n=1nn!fnL2(λn)2=ξD2,

so (t, ω) → Dtξ(ω) belongs to L2(λ × P).

Some basic properties of the Malliavin derivative Dt are the following (a) chain rule and (b) duality formula.

  1. Suppose ξ1, …, ξm ∈𝔻 and that f : ℝm → ℝ is C1 with bounded partial derivatives. Then f(ξ1, …, ξm) ∈𝔻 and

    Dtf(ξ1,,ξm)=i=1mfxi(ξ1,,ξm)Dt(ξi).
  2. Suppose φ(t) is (𝓕t)t≥0-adapted with

    E[0Tφ2(t)dt]<

    and let ξ ∈𝔻. Then

    E[ξ0Tφ(t)dBt]=E[0Tφ(t)Dt(ξ)dt].

3 Main results

It is well-known that the investment performance functional (3) is related to a Hamiltonian functional. For this, we define the Hamiltonian functional

(5)H(t,x,x,u,p,q)=f(t,x,x,u)+b(t,t,x,x,u)p+tTbs(s,t,x,x,u)p(s)ds + σ(t,t,x,x,u)q+tTσs(s,t,x,x,u)Dtp(s)ds,

here, both p(·) and q(·) are (𝓕t)t≥0-adapted processes and p (s) is assumed to be Malliavin differentiable for every s.

Define the adjoint mean-field BSDE for (p(t), q(t)) by

(6){dp(t)=E[Hx(t)+Hx(t)|𝓕t]dt+q(t)dB(t),0tT;p(T)=(gx+gx)(X(T),E[X(T)]),

where

Hx(t):=Hx(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t),p(t),p(t))

and

Hx(t):=Hx(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t),p(t),p(t)).

From now on we suppose that the controlled mean-field stochastic Volterra equation (1) and the corresponding adjoint mean-field BSDE (6) have corresponding solutions Xu(·) and (pu(·), qu(·)), respectively, for any u ∈ 𝓤.

Based on the Hamiltonian functional, in this section we study two mean-field stochastic maximum principles. The first principle gives a sufficient condition for the optimal investment under the concavity of the Hamiltonian function. The second condition is a necessary maximum principle under the condition of the existence of derivative process of the wealth process X.

3.1 A sufficient condition for optimal investment

Theorem 3.1

Assume that the function g(x, x') is concave with respect to (x, x') and H(t, x, x', u, p, q) is concave with respect to (x, x', u) for all (t, p, q)( Moreover, for all t

(7)supu𝕌E[H(t,X*(t),E[X*(t),  u,  p*(t),  q*(t))|𝓖t]=E[H(t,X*(t),E[X*(t)],u*(t),p*(t),q*(t))|𝓖t].

Then u* is an optimal investment.

Proof. Let u ∈ 𝓤 (or u* ∈ 𝓤) with corresponding solutions X(t) := Xu(t) (or X*(t) := Xu*(t)) of the controlled mean-field stochastic Volterra equation (2). Because of the definition of mean-field investment performance functional J(u), we have

(8)J(u)J(u*)=E[0T[f(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))f(t,X*(t),E[X*(t)],u*(t))]dt]+E[g(X(T),E[X(T)])g(X(T),E[X(T)])].

Firstly, we deal with the first term in the right hand side in the above equation (8). By the definition of the Hamiltonian functional, we get

(9)E0T[f(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))f(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))]dt=E0TH(t),X(t),E[X(t)],u(t),p(t),q(t))H(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t),p(t),q(t))b(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t)b(t,t,X(t),E[X(t),u(t))p(t)tTbs(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))bs(s,t,,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))p(s)dsσ(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))σ(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))q(t)tTσs(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))σs(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))Dtp(s)dsdt.

Secondly, we deal with the second term in the right hand side in the above equation (8). By the concavity of the function g(x, x') with respect to (x, x'), we get

E[g(X(T),E[X(T)])g(X*(T),E[X*(T)])]E[gx(X*(T),E[X*(T)])(X(T)X*(T))+gx(X*(T),E[X*(T)])(E[X(T)]E[X*(T)])]=[(gx(X*(T),E[X*(T)])+gx(X*(T),E[X*(T)]))(X(T)X*(T))]

Since (gx+gx)(X*(T),E[X*(T)])=p*(T) in the adjoint mean-field BSDE, we obtain

E[g(X(T),E[X(T)])g(X*(T),E[X*(T)])]E[p*(T)(X(T)X*(T))].

Now, applying Itô formula to p*(t)(X(t) – X*(t)) between 0 and T, in connection with the first identity in equation (6), we obtain

E[g(X(T),E[X(T)])g(X*(T),E[X*(T)])]
(10)E0Tp(t)b(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))b(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))+p(t)0tbt(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))bt(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))ds+p(t)0tσt(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))σt(t,s,,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))dB(s)EHx(t)+Hx(t)Ft(X(t)X(t))+q(t)σ(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))σ(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))dt,

where

H*x(t):=Hx(t,X*(t),E[X*(t)],u*(t),p*(t),q*(t))

and

H*x(t):=Hx(t,X*(t),E[X*(t)],u*(t),p*(t),q*(t)).

Next, using Fubini’s theorem, the fact that p* (t) is Malliavin differentiable for every t in connection with the duality formula for the Malliavin derivative Dt and Fubin’s theorem again all in this order, we have

(11)E[0T{p*(t)[0tσt(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))dB(s)]dt]=0TE[p*(t)0tσt(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))dB(s)]dt=0TE[0tσt(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))Dsp*(t)ds]dt=E[0TsTσt(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))Dsp*(t)dtds]=E[0TtTσt(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))Dtp*(s)dsdt].

Using Fubini’s theorem again, we have

(12)E[0Tp*(t)[0tbt(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))ds]dt]=E[0T[sTp*(t)bt(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))ds]dt]=E[0T[tTp*(s)bt(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))ds]dt]

Combining (10), (11) and (12), we arrive at

(13)E[g(X(T),E[X(T)])g(X(T),E[X(T)])]E[0T{p(t)[b(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))b(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))]+[tTp(t)[bs(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))bs(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))]ds]+tT[σs(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))σs(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))]Dtp(s)dsE[Hx(t)+Hx(t)|Ft](X(t)X(t))+q(t)[σ(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))σ(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))]}dt].

Finally, substituting (9) and (13) into (8) we get

(14)J(u)J(u)E[0T{[H(t),X(t),E[X(t)],u(t),p(t),q(t))H(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t),p(t),q(t))][b(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))b(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))]p(t)tT[bs(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))bs(s,t,,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))]p(s)ds[σ(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))σ(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))]q(t)tT[σs(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))σs(s,t,,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))]Dtp(s)ds}dt+E[0T{p(t)[b(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))b(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))]+[tTp(s)[bs(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))bs(s,t,,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))]ds]+tT[σs(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))σs(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))]Dtp(s)dsE[Hx(t)+Hx(t)|Ft](X(t)X(t))+q(t)[σ(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))σ(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))]}dt]=E[0T{[H(t),X(t),E[X(t)],u(t),p(t),q(t))H(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t),p(t),q(t))]E[Hx(t)+Hx(t)|Ft](X(t)X(t))}dt].

Now, introduce the notion:

H*u(t):=Hu(t,X*(t),E[X*(t)],u*(t),p*(t),q*(t)).

Hence, by the concavity of the function H(t, x, x', u, p, q) with respect to (x, x', u) for all (t, p, q), we obtain

(15)J(u)J(u*)E[0TH*u(t)[u(t)u*(t)]dt]=E[0TE[H*u(t)[u(t)u*(t)]|𝓖t]dt]=E[0TE[H*u(t)|𝓖t][u(t)u*(t)]]dt].

By the assumption (7) we have E[0TE[H*u(t)|𝓖t][u(t)u*(t)]dt]=0. Therefore, we conclude that for all u ∈ 𝓤, J(u) ≤ J(u*), and this completes the proof. □

3.2 A necessary condition for optimal investment: mean-field maximum principle

In this subsection we will assume both the coefficients b, σ of SDE and performance functions f are continuously differentiable with respect to (x, x', u) and g is continuously differentiable with respect to (x, x').

For any t ∈ [0, T], let α = αt be any bounded 𝓖t-measurable random variable and taking β(s) + αI[t,t+h] (s), s ∈ [0, T]( Assume that u + α ∈ 𝓤 for all such α and all u ∈ 𝓤.

Define the derivative process Y(t) by

Y(t):=ddλX(u+λβ)(t)|λ=0

and suppose this derivative process exists.

From (1), after some simple computation, we have

(16)Y(t)=0t[bx(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))Y(s)+bx(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))E[Y(s)]+bu(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))β(s)]ds+0t[σx(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))Y(s)+σx(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))E[Y(s)]+σu(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))β(s)]dB(s).

We can rewrite the derivative process (16) in differential form, for which it is convenient for us to apply Itô formula, as following:

(17)dY(t)=[bx(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))Y(t)+0t(2btx(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))Y(s)ds+bx(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))E[Y(t)]+0t(2btx(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))E[Y(s)]ds+bu(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))β(t)+0t(2btu(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))β(s)ds+0t(σtx(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))Y(s)dB(s)+0t(σtx(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))E[Y(s)]dB(s)+0t(σtu(t,s,X(s),E[X(s)],u(s))β(s)dB(s)]dt+σx(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))Y(t)dB(t)+σx(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))E[Y(t)]dB(t)++σu(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))β(t)dB(t)=:[Σ(t)]dt+[σx(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))Y(t)+σx(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))E[Y(t)]+σu(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))Y(t)β(t)]dB(t).

We now establish the mean-field stochastic maximum principle for mean-field stochastic Volterra equations with corresponding adjoint mean-field BSDE.

Theorem 3.2

Suppose that u ∈ 𝓤 satisfies that for all α,

(18)ddλJ(u+λβ)|λ=0=0.
Then
(19)E[Hu(t)|𝓖t]u=u*(t)=0,
where
Hu(t):=Hu(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t),p(t),q(t)),
and we adopt analogous notations forHx(t)andHx(t). Conversely, if (19) holds, then (18) holds.

Proof. By the definition of the performance functional J(u), we can compute the derivative

(20)ddλJ(u+λβ)|λ=0=E[0T(fx(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))Y(t)+fx(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))E[Y(t)]+fu(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))β(t))dt+gx(X(T),E[X(T)]Y(T)+gx(X(T),E[X(T)]E[Y(T)]]=E[0T(fx(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))Y(t)+fx(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t)E[Y(t)]+fu(t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))β(t))dt+p(T)Y(T)],

where the last equality results from p(T)=(gx+gx)(X(T),E[X(T)]).

Now, using Itô formula to p(t)Y(t), we find

(21)E[P(T)Y(T)]=E[0Tp(t)[Σ(t)]dt0TY(t)[EHx(t)+Hx(t)|𝓕t]dt+0Tq(t)[σx(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))E[Y(t)+σx(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))E[Y(t)]+σu(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))β(t)]dt].

Similarly to (11) and (12), we obtain

(22)E[0Tp(t)[Σ(t)]dt]=E[0TY(t)(bx(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))p(t)tT(2bsx(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))p(s)+2bsx(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))Dtp(s))ds)dt]+E[0TE[Y(t)](bx(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))p(t)+tT(2bsx(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))p(s)+2σsx(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))Dtp(s))ds)dt]+E[0Tβ(t)(bu(t,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))p(t)+tT(2bsu(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))p(s)+2σsu(s,t,X(t),E[X(t)],u(t))Dtp(s))ds)dt]

Combining (20), (21), (22) with the constructions of Hx(t)andHx(t), we have

(23)ddλJ(u+λβ)|λ=0=E[0THu(t)β(t)dt]=E[αtt+hHu(t)dt].

If (18) holds, then after differentiating the right hand side of (23)at h = 0, we now obtain

E[αHu(t)]=0.

Since this equality holds for all 𝓖t-measurable bounded α, we conclude that

(24)E[Hu(t)|𝓖t]=0.

Conversely, if we assume that (24) holds, then we obtain (18), since (23) holds. This completes the proof.

4 An example

Consider the following linear mean-field stochastic Volterra dynamic system, for 0 ≤ tT,

(25)X(t)=x+0tb(t,s,E[X(s)],u(s))X(s)ds+0tσ(t,s,E[X(s)],u(s))X(s)dB(s);

here, for simplicity, let the coefficient terms be

b(t,s,E[X(s)],u(s))=E[X(s)]u(s).

and

σ(t,s,E[X(s)],u(s))=tE[X(s)]u(s).

Hence the linear mean-field stochastic Volterra equation (25) given by

X(t)=x+0tE[X(s)]u(s)X(s)ds+0ttE[X(s)]u(s)X(s)dB(s);0tT

or, in differential form,

(26)dX(t)=E[X(t)]u(t)X(t)dt+tE[X(t)]u(t)X(t)dB(t)+0tE[X(s)]u(s)X(s)dB(s)dt.

From (26) above, we can get

(27)X(t)=xexp{0tsE[X(s)]u(s)dB(s)+0tE[X(s)]u(s)ds+0t(0sE[X(r)]u(r)X(r)dB(r)12(E[X(s)]su(s))2)ds}.

Here, the stochastic integral term 0sE[X(r)]u(r)X(r)dB(r) in (27) be generated from the form of Volterra equation and represents memory effects of the investment u(·). But there is no stochastic integral term 0sE[X(r)]u(r)X(r)dB(r) in classical Black-Scholes formula. If we assume the initial wealth value x be positive strictly, it follows that, from (27),

X(t)>0,Pa.s..

The invest performance functional is given by

J(u)=E[X(T)].

Obviously, the functions b, σ and g satisfy the conditions of Theorem 3.1 and Theorem 3.2, so, we can directly apply the results of Theorem 3.1 and Theorem 3.2.

Suppose there exists an optimal investment u* with corresponding processes (X*, p*, q*), then we have

E[Hu(t,X*(t),E[X*(t)],u(t),p*(t),q*(t))|Ft]u=u*=0.

From the definition of the Hamiltonian

H(t,x,x,u,p,q)=E[X(t)]u(t)X(t)p(t)+tE[X(t)]u(t)X(t)q(t)+tTE[X(t)]u(t)X(t)Dtp(s)ds

and X(t) > 0, for all t ∈ [0, T], we can get

(28)p*(t)+tq*(t)+E[tTDtp*(s)ds|𝓕t]=0.

From this, after some computation, we find that the adjoint BSDE given by

dp*(t)=q*(t)dB(t)

and the terminal condition

p*(T)=12X*(T)=:ξ(T).

Obviously, this BSDE has the unique solution

(29)p*(t)=E[ξ(T)|Ft]and  q*(t)=Dtp*(t).

Combining (28) with (29), we have

E[ξ(T)|Ft]+E[tDt(ξ(T))+tTtDt(ξ(T))ds|Ft]=0

that is

E[ξ(T)|Ft]+TDt(E[ξ(T)|Ft])=0.

Since X(t) > 0 and E[ξ(T)|𝓕t]is a martingale, so, we can deduce from the equation above that

E[ξ(T)|Ft]=E[ξ(T)]exp{B(t)Tt2T2}.

Obviously, ξ(Τ)=Ε[ξ(Τ)]exp{B(T)T12T}, so we get

(30)X*(T)=14E[ξ(T)]2exp{2B(T)T1T}.

Now, we define

Z*(s):=E[X*(s)]u*(s)X*(s)

and from (25), we get the following mean-field backward stochastic Volterra equation

(31)X*(t)=14E[ξ(T)]2exp{2B(T)T1T}tTZ*(s)dstTtZ*(s)dB(s).

From the existence and uniqueness of mean-field backward stochastic Volterra equation, see [24], we known that the above equation has unique solution (X*, Z*).

Taking the expectation on the above equation for t = 0, we obtain

x=14E[ξ(T)]2e3T0TE[Z*(s)]ds.

So, we have

E[ξ(T)]=(4e3Tx+4e3T0TE[Z*(s)]ds)12.

Combining this with (30), we conclude that the optimal investment in the financial market modeled by a linear mean-field stochastic Volterra equation (25), is:

u*(s)=Z*(s)(x+0TE[Z*(s)]ds)E[X*(s)]exp{2B(T)T2T},

here, (X*, Z*) be the solution of (31).

Acknowledgement

The authors would like to thank the referee for very helpful comments, particularly for his suggestions concerning the treatment of an example in Section 4. This work is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No. 11501325, 11501330, 11301303), Social science planning and research project in Shandong Province (No. 14AWTJ01-17), CPSF (No. 2015M582071), Academy of Humanities and Social Science Research Plan Project of Higher Education in Shandong Province (No. J14WF61) and was partially supported by National Social Science Foundation of China (Grant No. 15BJY007), Humanities and Social Sciences Project of the Ministry Education of China (Grant No. 14YJA630088, Grant No. 13YJC630150), Foundation of Shandong Province of China (Grant No. ZR2013AQ021, No. ZR2014GQ014).

References

[1] Meyer-Brandis, T., Øksendal, B., Zhou, X.: A mean-field stochastic maximum principle via Malliavin calculus, Stochastics An International Journal of Probability and Stochastic Processes, 84:5-6, 643-666 (2012)10.1080/17442508.2011.651619Search in Google Scholar

[2] Merton, R. C.: Lifetime Portfolio Selection Under Uncertainty: The Continuous-Time Model, Rev. Econ. Statist. 51, 247-257 (1969)10.2307/1926560Search in Google Scholar

[3] Merton, R. C.: Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous-Time Model, J. Econ. Theory 3, 373-413 (1971)10.1016/0022-0531(71)90038-XSearch in Google Scholar

[4] Pliska, S. R.: A Stochastic Calculus Model of Continuous Trading: Optimal Portfolios, Math. Oper. Res. 11, 371-382 (1986)10.1287/moor.11.2.371Search in Google Scholar

[5] Cox, J., Huang, C. F.: Optimal Consumption and Portfolio Policies When Asset Prices Follow a Diffusion Process, J. Econ. Theory 49, 33-83. (1989)10.1016/0022-0531(89)90067-7Search in Google Scholar

[6] Karatzas, I., Lehoczky, J. P., Shreve, S. E.: Optimal Portfolio and Consumption Decisions for a Small Investor on a Finite Horizon, SIAM J. Control Optim. 25, 1557-1586 (1987)10.1137/0325086Search in Google Scholar

[7] Cvitanic, J., Karatzas, I.: Convex Duality in Constrained Portfolio Optimization, Ann. Appl. Probab. 2, 767-818. (1992)10.1214/aoap/1177005576Search in Google Scholar

[8] Zariphopoulou, T.: Consumption-Investment Models with Constraints, SIAM J. Control Optim. 32(1), 59-85 (1994)10.1109/CDC.1991.261600Search in Google Scholar

[9] Constantinides, G. M., Magill, M. J. P.: Portfolio Selection with Transaction Costs, J. Econ. Theory 13, 245-263. (1976)10.1016/0022-0531(76)90018-1Search in Google Scholar

[10] Davis, M. H. A., Norman, A. R.: Portfolio Selection with Transaction Costs, Math. Oper. Res. 15(4), 676-713. (1990)10.1287/moor.15.4.676Search in Google Scholar

[11] Shreve, S. E., Soner, H. M.: Optimal Investment and Consumption with Transaction Costs, Ann. Appl. Probab. 4, 609-692 (1994)10.1214/aoap/1177004966Search in Google Scholar

[12] Duffie, D., Sun, T.: Transaction Costs and Portfolio Choice in a Discrete-Continuous-Time Setting, J. Econ. Dyn. Control 14, 35-51. (1990)10.1016/0165-1889(90)90004-ZSearch in Google Scholar

[13] Akian, M., Menaldi, J.L., Sulem, A.: Multi-Asset Portfolio Selection Problem with Transaction Costs. Probabilités Numériques (Paris, 1992), Math. Comput. Simul. 38, 163-172. (1995)10.1016/0378-4754(93)E0079-KSearch in Google Scholar

[14] Karatzas, I., Lehoczky, J. P., Shreve, S. E., Xu, G. : Martingale and Duality Methods for Utility Maximization in an Incomplete Market, SIAM J. Control Optim. 29, 702-730 (1991)10.1137/0329039Search in Google Scholar

[15] Kramkov, D., Schachermayer, W.: The Condition on the Asymptotic Elasticity of Utility Functions and Optimal Investment in Incomplete Markets, Ann. Appl. Probab. 9, 904-950 (1999)10.1214/aoap/1029962818Search in Google Scholar

[16] Kramkov, D., Schachermayer, W.: Necessary and Sufficient Conditions in the Problem of Optimal Investment in Incomplete Markets, Ann. Appl. Probab. 13(4), 1504-1516 (2003)10.1214/aoap/1069786508Search in Google Scholar

[17] Kramkov, D., Sirbu, M.: On the Two-Times Differentiability of the Value Functions in the Problem of Optimal Investment in Incomplete Markets, Ann. Appl. Probab. 16(3), 1352-1384 (2006)10.1214/105051606000000259Search in Google Scholar

[18] Lasry, J.M, Lions P.L: Mean field games. Jpn J Math 2(1):229-260 (2007)10.1007/s11537-007-0657-8Search in Google Scholar

[19] Huang, M., Malhamé, R. P., Caines, P.: Large population stochastic dynamic games: closed-loop McKean-Vlasov systems and the Nash certainty equivalence principle. Commun Inf Syst 6(3):221-251 (2006)10.4310/CIS.2006.v6.n3.a5Search in Google Scholar

[20] Huang, M., Caines, P., Malhamé, R. P.: Large-population cost-coupled LQG problems with nonuniform agents: individual-mass behavior and decentralized _-Nash equilibria. IEEE Trans Autom Control 52(9):1560-1571 (2007)10.1109/TAC.2007.904450Search in Google Scholar

[21] Pamen, O., Meyer-Brandis, T., Proske, F., Salleh, H.: Malliavin calculus applied to optimal control of stochastic partial differential equations with jumps, Stochastics An International Journal of Probability and Stochastic Processes, 85:3, 431-463 (2013)10.1080/17442508.2011.652964Search in Google Scholar

[22] Agram, Nacira, and Bernt Øksendal. Malliavin calculus and optimal control of stochastic Volterra equations. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications 167, 1070-1094. (2015)10.1007/s10957-015-0753-5Search in Google Scholar

[23] Yong, J.: Backward stochastic Volterra integral equations and some related problems. Stochastic Proc. Appl. 116: 779-795 (2006)10.1016/j.spa.2006.01.005Search in Google Scholar

[24] Shi, Y., Wang, T., Yong, J.: Mean-field backward stochastic Volterra integral equations. Discrete and Continuous Dynamical Systems Series B 18, 1929-1967 (2013)10.3934/dcdsb.2013.18.1929Search in Google Scholar

[25] Wang, T., Zhu, Q., Shi, Y.: Necessary and sufficient conditions of optimality for stochastic integral systems with partial information. Proceedings of the 30th Chinese Control Conference. July 22-24, Yantai, China (2011)Search in Google Scholar

[26] Di Nunno, G., Øksendal, B., Proske, F.: Malliavin Calculus for Lévy Processes with Applications to Finance, Universitext Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. (2008)10.1007/978-3-540-78572-9Search in Google Scholar

[27] Nualart, D.,: The Malliavin Calculus and Related Topics, 2nd ed., Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg, New York (2006)Search in Google Scholar

Received: 2015-9-8
Accepted: 2015-12-28
Published Online: 2016-5-19
Published in Print: 2016-1-1

© 2016 An et al., published by De Gruyter Open

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 3.0 License.

Articles in the same Issue

  1. Regular Article
  2. A metric graph satisfying w41=1 that cannot be lifted to a curve satisfying dim(W41)=1
  3. Regular Article
  4. On the Riemann-Hilbert problem in multiply connected domains
  5. Regular Article
  6. Hamilton cycles in almost distance-hereditary graphs
  7. Regular Article
  8. Locally adequate semigroup algebras
  9. Regular Article
  10. Parabolic oblique derivative problem with discontinuous coefficients in generalized weighted Morrey spaces
  11. Corrigendum
  12. Corrigendum to: parabolic oblique derivative problem with discontinuous coefficients in generalized weighted Morrey spaces
  13. Regular Article
  14. Some new bounds of the minimum eigenvalue for the Hadamard product of an M-matrix and an inverse M-matrix
  15. Regular Article
  16. Integral inequalities involving generalized Erdélyi-Kober fractional integral operators
  17. Regular Article
  18. Results on the deficiencies of some differential-difference polynomials of meromorphic functions
  19. Regular Article
  20. General numerical radius inequalities for matrices of operators
  21. Regular Article
  22. The best uniform quadratic approximation of circular arcs with high accuracy
  23. Regular Article
  24. Multiple gcd-closed sets and determinants of matrices associated with arithmetic functions
  25. Regular Article
  26. A note on the rate of convergence for Chebyshev-Lobatto and Radau systems
  27. Regular Article
  28. On the weakly(α, ψ, ξ)-contractive condition for multi-valued operators in metric spaces and related fixed point results
  29. Regular Article
  30. Existence of a common solution for a system of nonlinear integral equations via fixed point methods in b-metric spaces
  31. Regular Article
  32. Bounds for the Z-eigenpair of general nonnegative tensors
  33. Regular Article
  34. Subsymmetry and asymmetry models for multiway square contingency tables with ordered categories
  35. Regular Article
  36. End-regular and End-orthodox generalized lexicographic products of bipartite graphs
  37. Regular Article
  38. Refinement of the Jensen integral inequality
  39. Regular Article
  40. New iterative codes for 𝓗-tensors and an application
  41. Regular Article
  42. A result for O2-convergence to be topological in posets
  43. Regular Article
  44. A fixed point approach to the Mittag-Leffler-Hyers-Ulam stability of a fractional integral equation
  45. Regular Article
  46. Uncertainty orders on the sublinear expectation space
  47. Regular Article
  48. Generalized derivations of Lie triple systems
  49. Regular Article
  50. The BV solution of the parabolic equation with degeneracy on the boundary
  51. Regular Article
  52. Malliavin method for optimal investment in financial markets with memory
  53. Regular Article
  54. Parabolic sublinear operators with rough kernel generated by parabolic calderön-zygmund operators and parabolic local campanato space estimates for their commutators on the parabolic generalized local morrey spaces
  55. Regular Article
  56. On annihilators in BL-algebras
  57. Regular Article
  58. On derivations of quantales
  59. Regular Article
  60. On the closed subfields of Q¯~p
  61. Regular Article
  62. A class of tridiagonal operators associated to some subshifts
  63. Regular Article
  64. Some notes to existence and stability of the positive periodic solutions for a delayed nonlinear differential equations
  65. Regular Article
  66. Weighted fractional differential equations with infinite delay in Banach spaces
  67. Regular Article
  68. Laplace-Stieltjes transform of the system mean lifetime via geometric process model
  69. Regular Article
  70. Various limit theorems for ratios from the uniform distribution
  71. Regular Article
  72. On α-almost Artinian modules
  73. Regular Article
  74. Limit theorems for the weights and the degrees in anN-interactions random graph model
  75. Regular Article
  76. An analysis on the stability of a state dependent delay differential equation
  77. Regular Article
  78. The hybrid mean value of Dedekind sums and two-term exponential sums
  79. Regular Article
  80. New modification of Maheshwari’s method with optimal eighth order convergence for solving nonlinear equations
  81. Regular Article
  82. On the concept of general solution for impulsive differential equations of fractional-order q ∈ (2,3)
  83. Regular Article
  84. A Riesz representation theory for completely regular Hausdorff spaces and its applications
  85. Regular Article
  86. Oscillation of impulsive conformable fractional differential equations
  87. Regular Article
  88. Dynamics of doubly stochastic quadratic operators on a finite-dimensional simplex
  89. Regular Article
  90. Homoclinic solutions of 2nth-order difference equations containing both advance and retardation
  91. Regular Article
  92. When do L-fuzzy ideals of a ring generate a distributive lattice?
  93. Regular Article
  94. Fully degenerate poly-Bernoulli numbers and polynomials
  95. Commentary
  96. Commentary to: Generalized derivations of Lie triple systems
  97. Regular Article
  98. Simple sufficient conditions for starlikeness and convexity for meromorphic functions
  99. Regular Article
  100. Global stability analysis and control of leptospirosis
  101. Regular Article
  102. Random attractors for stochastic two-compartment Gray-Scott equations with a multiplicative noise
  103. Regular Article
  104. The fuzzy metric space based on fuzzy measure
  105. Regular Article
  106. A classification of low dimensional multiplicative Hom-Lie superalgebras
  107. Regular Article
  108. Structures of W(2.2) Lie conformal algebra
  109. Regular Article
  110. On the number of spanning trees, the Laplacian eigenvalues, and the Laplacian Estrada index of subdivided-line graphs
  111. Regular Article
  112. Parabolic Marcinkiewicz integrals on product spaces and extrapolation
  113. Regular Article
  114. Prime, weakly prime and almost prime elements in multiplication lattice modules
  115. Regular Article
  116. Pochhammer symbol with negative indices. A new rule for the method of brackets
  117. Regular Article
  118. Outcome space range reduction method for global optimization of sum of affine ratios problem
  119. Regular Article
  120. Factorization theorems for strong maps between matroids of arbitrary cardinality
  121. Regular Article
  122. A convergence analysis of SOR iterative methods for linear systems with weak H-matrices
  123. Regular Article
  124. Existence theory for sequential fractional differential equations with anti-periodic type boundary conditions
  125. Regular Article
  126. Some congruences for 3-component multipartitions
  127. Regular Article
  128. Bound for the largest singular value of nonnegative rectangular tensors
  129. Regular Article
  130. Convolutions of harmonic right half-plane mappings
  131. Regular Article
  132. On homological classification of pomonoids by GP-po-flatness of S-posets
  133. Regular Article
  134. On CSQ-normal subgroups of finite groups
  135. Regular Article
  136. The homogeneous balance of undetermined coefficients method and its application
  137. Regular Article
  138. On the saturated numerical semigroups
  139. Regular Article
  140. The Bruhat rank of a binary symmetric staircase pattern
  141. Regular Article
  142. Fixed point theorems for cyclic contractive mappings via altering distance functions in metric-like spaces
  143. Regular Article
  144. Singularities of lightcone pedals of spacelike curves in Lorentz-Minkowski 3-space
  145. Regular Article
  146. An S-type upper bound for the largest singular value of nonnegative rectangular tensors
  147. Regular Article
  148. Fuzzy ideals of ordered semigroups with fuzzy orderings
  149. Regular Article
  150. On meromorphic functions for sharing two sets and three sets in m-punctured complex plane
  151. Regular Article
  152. An incremental approach to obtaining attribute reduction for dynamic decision systems
  153. Regular Article
  154. Very true operators on MTL-algebras
  155. Regular Article
  156. Value distribution of meromorphic solutions of homogeneous and non-homogeneous complex linear differential-difference equations
  157. Regular Article
  158. A class of 3-dimensional almost Kenmotsu manifolds with harmonic curvature tensors
  159. Regular Article
  160. Robust dynamic output feedback fault-tolerant control for Takagi-Sugeno fuzzy systems with interval time-varying delay via improved delay partitioning approach
  161. Regular Article
  162. New bounds for the minimum eigenvalue of M-matrices
  163. Regular Article
  164. Semi-quotient mappings and spaces
  165. Regular Article
  166. Fractional multilinear integrals with rough kernels on generalized weighted Morrey spaces
  167. Regular Article
  168. A family of singular functions and its relation to harmonic fractal analysis and fuzzy logic
  169. Regular Article
  170. Solution to Fredholm integral inclusions via (F, δb)-contractions
  171. Regular Article
  172. An Ulam stability result on quasi-b-metric-like spaces
  173. Regular Article
  174. On the arrowhead-Fibonacci numbers
  175. Regular Article
  176. Rough semigroups and rough fuzzy semigroups based on fuzzy ideals
  177. Regular Article
  178. The general solution of impulsive systems with Riemann-Liouville fractional derivatives
  179. Regular Article
  180. A remark on local fractional calculus and ordinary derivatives
  181. Regular Article
  182. Elastic Sturmian spirals in the Lorentz-Minkowski plane
  183. Topical Issue: Metaheuristics: Methods and Applications
  184. Bias-variance decomposition in Genetic Programming
  185. Topical Issue: Metaheuristics: Methods and Applications
  186. A novel generalized oppositional biogeography-based optimization algorithm: application to peak to average power ratio reduction in OFDM systems
  187. Special Issue on Recent Developments in Differential Equations
  188. Modeling of vibration for functionally graded beams
  189. Special Issue on Recent Developments in Differential Equations
  190. Decomposition of a second-order linear time-varying differential system as the series connection of two first order commutative pairs
  191. Special Issue on Recent Developments in Differential Equations
  192. Differential equations associated with generalized Bell polynomials and their zeros
  193. Special Issue on Recent Developments in Differential Equations
  194. Differential equations for p, q-Touchard polynomials
  195. Special Issue on Recent Developments in Differential Equations
  196. A new approach to nonlinear singular integral operators depending on three parameters
  197. Special Issue on Recent Developments in Differential Equations
  198. Performance and stochastic stability of the adaptive fading extended Kalman filter with the matrix forgetting factor
  199. Special Issue on Recent Developments in Differential Equations
  200. On new characterization of inextensible flows of space-like curves in de Sitter space
  201. Special Issue on Recent Developments in Differential Equations
  202. Convergence theorems for a family of multivalued nonexpansive mappings in hyperbolic spaces
  203. Special Issue on Recent Developments in Differential Equations
  204. Fractional virus epidemic model on financial networks
  205. Special Issue on Recent Developments in Differential Equations
  206. Reductions and conservation laws for BBM and modified BBM equations
  207. Special Issue on Recent Developments in Differential Equations
  208. Extinction of a two species non-autonomous competitive system with Beddington-DeAngelis functional response and the effect of toxic substances
Downloaded on 17.10.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/math-2016-0027/html
Scroll to top button