Startseite Filtering Persistent and Asymmetric Cycles
Artikel
Lizenziert
Nicht lizenziert Erfordert eine Authentifizierung

Filtering Persistent and Asymmetric Cycles

  • Luiggi Donayre ORCID logo EMAIL logo
Veröffentlicht/Copyright: 15. August 2022

Abstract

This paper evaluates the ability of the trend-cycle decomposition approach of Hamilton (2018. “Why You Should Never Use the Hodrick-Prescott Filter.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 100 (5): 831–43) to adequately characterize linear and (a)symmetric nonlinear business cycles fluctuations that are known to be persistent. This ability is contrasted to that of the Hodrick–Prescott filter. By means of Monte Carlo simulations, the results indicate that neither filter is able to preserve the cyclical properties of the data-generating process nor reproduce U.S. business cycles features, although this inability is exacerbated for the decomposition of Hamilton (2018. “Why You Should Never Use the Hodrick–Prescott Filter.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 100 (5): 831–43). Based on these findings, caution is called into question when this approach is applied to linear or nonlinear processes that are thought to exhibit persistence.

JEL Classification: C15; C22; E32

Corresponding author: Luiggi Donayre, Department of Economics, University of Minnesota - Duluth, 1318 Kirby Dr., Duluth, MN 55812, USA, E-mail: .

Acknowledgements

Helpful comments from two anonymous referees, Yunjong Eo, Ronald Miranda, Tara Sinclair and the participants at the 2020 MERG Annual Meeting, INFER 2020 Annual Conference, 2021 WEAI International Conference, the 2021 Asian Meeting of the Econometric Society, the 2021 Latin American Meeting of the Econometric Society, the 15th International Conference in Computational and Financial Econometrics and the University of Minnesota - Duluth are gratefully acknowledged. All errors are my own.

Appendix A: Stationarity Conditions for Hamilton (2018)’s Decomposition Approach

The main result in Hamilton (2018), that the residuals in Eq. (3) mimic the stationary component of any series y t , hinges on the assumption that the dth difference of y t , Δ d y t , is stationary for some d ≥ 1. The series Δ d y t = z t is stationary if it has a fixed mean z ̄ and satisfies a functional central limit theorem. This requires that the sample mean and the mean of z t using only Tr observations for 0 < r ≤ 1, follow a normal distribution as T → ∞. Formally,

(A-1) T 1 / 2 s = 1 Tr z t z ̄ p ω ̃ W ( r )

where . is the floor function, which provides the largest integer less than or equal to the argument, ω ̃ W ( r ) is a standard Brownian motion and p denotes weak convergence in probability. Stock (1994, p. 2749) demonstrates that a sufficient condition that implies (A-1) is given by:

(A-2) z t = z ̄ + j = 0 ψ j η j

where η j is a martingale difference sequence with variance σ η 2 and finite fourth moment, ψ1 ≠ 0, and j = 0 j ψ j < , in which case ω ̃ in Eq. (A-1) is given by σ η ψ1.

To ensure that the model (1a)(1c) fulfills this stationarity requirement, note that any UC model with a stationary cycle admits an equivalent, univariate autoregressive integrated moving average (ARIMA) process.[16] Substituting Eqs. (1b) and (1c) into (1a) and taking first differences yield:

(A-3) ϕ p ( L ) Δ y t = ϕ p ( 1 ) μ + ϕ p ( L ) v t + θ q ( L ) e t

where L is the lag operator, ϕ p ( L ) and θ q ( L ) are lag polynomials, μ is the drift of the permanent component, and v t and e t are defined in Eqs. (1a)–(1c). Because the right-hand side of Eq. (A-3) will have non-zero autocovariances through lag q * = max ( p , q + 1 ) , Granger’s lemma (Granger and Newbold 1986, p. 29) implies that the univariate representation of a stationary UC model is given by:

(A-4) ϕ p ( L ) Δ y t = μ * + θ q * ( L ) u t

where u t is a function of v t and e t and μ* is a function of μ and the autoregressive parameters ϕ p ( 1 ) . It can be shown that Eq. (A-4) fulfills the sufficient condition for stationarity given in (A-2).

A.1 UC-AR(1) model

For the UC model (1a) and (1b) with a linear AR(1) process for the transitory component (1c), used in the main Monte Carlo analysis of Section 3, Eq. (A-4) becomes

(A-5) 1 ϕ L Δ y t = μ * + v t ϕ v t 1 + e t e t 1 = μ * + u t θ * u t 1

where μ* = (1 − ϕ)μ, u t = v t + e t with u t N 0 , σ u 2 and θ* is a function of the autoregressive coefficient ϕ. Therefore, its reduced-form is a restricted ARIMA(1,1,1) process. That is, Δ d y t I(0) with d = 1. From Eq. (A-5), it follows that:

(A-6) 1 ϕ L Δ y t = μ * + u t θ * u t 1 Δ y t = μ * 1 ϕ L + 1 1 ϕ L u t θ * 1 ϕ L u t 1 = μ * 1 ϕ L + λ ( L ) 1 θ * L u t = μ * 1 ϕ L + j = 0 λ j 1 θ * L u j

where the third equality follows from the stationarity condition ϕ < 1 , which implies that λ ( L ) = 1 ϕ L 1 = i = 0 ϕ i L i and that λ ( L ) 1 θ * L is finite. Therefore, the coefficients λ j are convolutions of θ* and ϕ such that limj→∞λ j = 0. Since u t is a martingale sequence, 1 θ * L u t is a martingale difference sequence. Further, 1 θ * L u t has a finite fourth moment since u t i.i.d N 0 , σ u 2 . Finally, λ1 = ϕ ≠ 0, and j = 0 j λ j < . Comparing Eq. (A-2) and (A-6) reveals that Δ d y t satisfies the sufficient condition (A-2) and, therefore, the requirement (A-1) from Hamilton (2018).

A.2 UC-MSAR(1) model

For the case of the UC model (1a) and (1b) with a Markov-switching AR(1) process for the transitory component (1c), Eq. (A-4) involves a first-order regime-switching process:

(A-7) 1 ϕ L Δ y t = μ S t * + v t ϕ v t 1 + e t e t 1 = μ S t * + u t θ * u t 1

where μ S t * = ( 1 ϕ ) μ + ( 1 ϕ L ) ( 1 ϕ ) 1 Δ π S t , with π S t = π 0 1 S t = 0 + π 1 1 S t = 1 and u t N 0 , σ u 2 as in Eq. (A-5). Therefore, the reduced-form of the UC model (1a)(1c), with a Markov-switching AR(1) transitory component, is an ARMA(1,1) process with a regime-switching mean μ S t * .

Note that Eqs. (A-5) and (A-7) are identical, except for the terms μ* and μ S t * . It follows from Eq. (A-7) that Δ d y t will be integrated of order d = 1 and will satisfy the sufficient condition (A-2) if the MSAR(1) cycle is stationary, since μ S t * is a function of the switching intercept π S t . This is also consistent with the MA component in Eq. (A-7) being irrelevant for stationarity (Francq and Zakoïan 2001, p. 345), so that only μ S t * determines stationarity.

Therefore, it suffices to show that the MSAR(1) cycle is stationary. For any ARMA(1,q ) process, Francq and Zakoïan (2001, p. 345–347) show that a sufficient condition for stationarity is:

(A-8) ρ ( P ̃ ) < 1

where ρ( M ) is the spectral radius of any matrix M such that ρ ( M ) = max λ E λ , with E the set of eigenvalues of M ; and P ̃ is a m s K 2 p 2 × m s K 2 p 2 matrix of transition probabilities and autoregressive coefficients, with m s the number of Markov states, K the number of variables and p the number of autoregressive coefficients. In the specific case of the MSAR(1) transitory component of Section 3, m s = 2, K = 1 and p = 1, so P ̃ is a (2 × 2) matrix given by

(A-9) P ̃ = ϕ 2 q ( 1 p ) ( 1 q ) p

where p and q are the transition probabilities defined in Eqs. (2a) and (2b), and ϕ is the autoregressive coefficient. In Section 3, the two values for ϕ considered are 0.5 and 0.9. When ϕ = 0.5, and given p = 0.7 and q = 0.9, it follows that the sufficient condition of Eq. (A-8) becomes ρ ( P ̃ ) = max 0.3 , 0.5 < 1 . When ϕ = 0.9, ρ ( P ̃ ) = max 0.54 , 0.9 < 1 .

Hence, the sufficient condition (A-8) is satisfied for the values of ϕ considered, which proves that the MSAR(1) transitory components of Section 3 are stationary. This shows, subsequently, that the UC-MSAR(1) model satisfies the sufficient condition (A-2) and, consequently, the requirement (A-1) from Hamilton (2018).

Appendix B: Supplemental Material

Table 5:

Maximum likelihood estimates (MLE): asymmetric MSAR(1) transitory component.

Parameter T 200 500
π0π1 0.4 2.0 0.4 2.0
ϕ 0.5 0.9 0.5 0.9 0.5 0.9 0.5 0.9
(a) HD-filtered cycle
π 0 0.971 0.982 0.995 1.135 0.772 0.824 0.849 0.944
π 1 −0.967 −0.971 −1.233 −1.617 −0.745 −0.816 −1.083 −1.466
ϕ 0.697 0.783 0.720 0.805 0.730 0.800 0.747 0.816
σ 2 1.265 1.341 1.464 1.813 1.353 1.408 1.540 1.860
P 0.745 0.803 0.737 0.800 0.788 0.834 0.750 0.811
Q 0.781 0.809 0.812 0.854 0.818 0.838 0.829 0.874
(b) HP-filtered cycle
π 0 0.833 0.801 0.651 0.605 0.777 0.702 0.537 0.535
π 1 −0.823 −0.777 −1.348 −1.296 −0.742 −0.672 −1.270 −1.246
ϕ 0.438 0.613 0.501 0.717 0.472 0.636 0.518 0.728
σ 2 0.971 0.937 1.098 1.080 1.025 0.970 1.136 1.106
P 0.648 0.702 0.573 0.662 0.637 0.710 0.565 0.657
q 0.659 0.700 0.785 0.838 0.648 0.711 0.813 0.850
(c) True cycle
π 0 0.563 0.435 0.018 −0.032 0.485 0.340 0.004 −0.019
π 1 −0.834 −0.823 −2.041 −2.106 −0.739 −0.689 −2.012 −2.047
ϕ 0.418 0.824 0.497 0.887 0.445 0.855 0.496 0.895
σ 2 0.863 0.887 0.977 0.979 0.907 0.936 0.992 0.992
p 0.678 0.771 0.668 0.694 0.691 0.770 0.692 0.696
q 0.712 0.802 0.889 0.896 0.727 0.833 0.895 0.897
  1. Panels (a) and (b): Maximum likelihood (ML) estimates of the MSAR(1) cycle filtered from Eqs. (1a)–(1c) using the HD and HP filters, respectively. Panel (c): ML estimates of the true MSAR(1) cycle. In all cases, p = 0.7, q = 0.9, σ e 2 = 1 and π0 = 0. Estimates are averaged across Monte Carlo repetitions.

Table 6:

Correlations and RSME: asymmetric MSAR(1) transitory component.

Sample size
200 500
π0π1 ϕ 0.5 0.9 0.5 0.9
(a) HD approach
Correlation 0.4 0.492 0.473 0.482 0.453
2.0 0.592 0.504 0.583 0.482
RMSE 0.4 4.414 9.860 4.654 10.067
2.0 6.733 46.357 6.970 46.525
(b) HP filter
Correlation 0.4 0.717 0.588 0.714 0.572
2.0 0.770 0.616 0.768 0.598
RMSE 0.4 1.012 5.126 1.016 5.070
2.0 2.471 37.531 2.452 37.312
  1. Correlations and RMSE between the true MSAR(1) cycle and the cycle from Eqs. (1a)–(1c) using the approach of Hamilton (2018), in panel (a), and the HP filter, in panel (b). Estimates are averaged across Monte Carlo repetitions.

Table 7:

Regression diagnostics: asymmetric MSAR(1) transitory component.

Sample size
200 500
π0π1 ϕ 0.5 0.9 0.5 0.9
δ ̂ 0.4 −0.116 0.019 −0.107 0.022
2.0 −0.043 0.099 −0.043 0.098
Adjusted-R2 0.4 0.050 0.026 0.040 0.011
2.0 0.029 0.025 0.015 0.014
  1. Slope coefficient ( δ ̂ ) and adjusted-R2 from Eq. (5). Estimates are averaged across Monte Carlo repetitions.

References

Ahmad, Y., and L. Donayre. 2016. “Outliers and Persistence in Threshold Autoregressive Processes.” Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics 20 (1): 37–56. https://doi.org/10.1515/snde-2014-0058.Suche in Google Scholar

Andrews, D. W. K. 2000. “Inconsistency of the Bootstrap when a Parameter is on the Boundary of the Parameter Space.” Econometrica 68 (2): 399–405. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00114.Suche in Google Scholar

Balke, N. S. 2000. “Credit and Economic Activity: Credit Regimes and Nonlinear Propagation of Shocks.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 82: 344–9. https://doi.org/10.1162/rest.2000.82.2.344.Suche in Google Scholar

Carrasco, M., L. Hu, and W. Ploberger. 2014. “Optimal Tests for Markov Switching Parameters.” Econometrica 82 (2): 765–84.10.3982/ECTA8609Suche in Google Scholar

Cho, J. S., and H. White. 2007. “Testing for Regime Switching.” Econometrica 75 (6): 1671–720, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0262.2007.00809.Suche in Google Scholar

Cogley, T., and J. M. Nason. 1995. “Effects of the Hodrick-Prescott Filter on Trend and Difference Stationary Time Series: Implications for Business Cycle Research.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 19: 253–78, https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-1889(93)00781.Suche in Google Scholar

Donayre, L. 2015. “Do Monetary Policy Shocks Generate TAR or STAR Dynamics in Output?” Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics 19 (2): 227–47. https://doi.org/10.1515/snde-2013-0038.Suche in Google Scholar

Donayre, L. 2022. “On the Behavior of Okun’s Law Across Business Cycles.” Economic Modelling 112: 105858. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2022.105858.Suche in Google Scholar

Donayre, L., Y. Eo, and J. Morley. 2018. “Improving Likelihood-Ratio-Based Confidence Intervals for Threshold Parameters in Finite Samples.” Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics 22 (1): 1–11. https://doi.org/10.1515/snde-2016-0084.Suche in Google Scholar

Donayre, L., and I. Panovska. 2018. “U.S. Wage Growth and Nonlinearities: The Roles of Inflation and Unemployment.” Economic Modelling 68: 273–92. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2017.07.019.Suche in Google Scholar

Donayre, L., and I. Panovska. 2021. “Recession-specific Recoveries: L’s, U’s and Everything in between.” Economics Letters 209: 110145. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2021.110145.Suche in Google Scholar

Dupraz, S., E. Nakamura, and J. Steinsson. 2022. “A Plucking Model of Business Cycles.” In Working Paper. Berkeley: University of California.Suche in Google Scholar

Eo, Y., and C. J. Kim. 2016. “Markov-Switching Models with Evolving Regime-specific Parameters: Are Postwar Booms or Recessions All Alike?” The Review of Economics and Statistics 98 (5): 940–9. https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_00561.Suche in Google Scholar

Eo, Y., and J. Morley. 2022. “Why Has the U.S. Economy Stagnated since the Great Recession?” The Review of Economics and Statistics 104 (2): 246–58. https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_00957.Suche in Google Scholar

Francq, C., and J.-M. Zakoïan. 2001. “Stationarity of Multivariate Markov-Switching ARMA Models.” Journal of Econometrics 102: 339–64. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0304-4076(01)00057-4.Suche in Google Scholar

Granger, C. W., and P. Newbold. 1986. Forecasting Economic Time Series, 3rd ed. Orlando: Academic Press.Suche in Google Scholar

Guerrón-Quintana, P. A., and R. Jinnai. 2019. “Financial Frictions, Trends, and the Great Recession.” Quantitative Economics 10 (2): 735–73. https://doi.org/10.3982/qe702.Suche in Google Scholar

Hamilton, J. D. 1989. “A New Approach to the Economic Analysis of Nonstationary Time Series and the Business Cycle.” Econometrica 57: 357–84. https://doi.org/10.2307/1912559.Suche in Google Scholar

Hamilton, J. D. 2018. “Why You Should Never Use the Hodrick-Prescott Filter.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 100 (5): 831–43. https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_00706.Suche in Google Scholar

Hodrick, R., and E. C. Prescott. 1997. “Postwar U.S. Business Cycles: An Empirical Investigation.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 29 (1): 1–16. https://doi.org/10.2307/2953682.Suche in Google Scholar

Hodrick, R. J. 2020. “An Exploration of Trend-Cycle Decomposition Methodologies in Simulated Data.” In NBER Working Paper 26750.10.3386/w26750Suche in Google Scholar

Huang, Y.-F., S. Luo, and R. Startz. 2021. “Are Recoveries all the Same: GDP and TFP?” Oxford Bulletin of Economics & Statistics 83 (5): 1111–1129. https://doi.org/10.1111/obes.12439.Suche in Google Scholar

Jönsson, K. 2020. “Cyclical Dynamics and Trend/Cycle Definitions: Comparing the HP and Hamilton Filters.” Journal of Business Cycle Research 16: 151–62. https://doi.org/10.1007/s41549-020-00039-x.Suche in Google Scholar

Kim, C.-J., J. Morley, and J. Piger. 2005. “Nonlinearity and the Permanent Effects of Recessions.” Journal of Applied Econometrics 20: 291–309. https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.831.Suche in Google Scholar

Kim, C.-J., and C. R. Nelson. 1999. “Friedman’s Plucking Model of Business Cycles Fluctuations: Tests and Estimates of Permanent and Transitory Components.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 31 (3): 317–34. https://doi.org/10.2307/2601114.Suche in Google Scholar

Morley, J., and I. Panovska. 2020. “Is Business Cycle Asymmetry Intrinsic in Industrialized Economies?” Macroeconomic Dynamics 24 (6): 1403–36. https://doi.org/10.1017/s1365100518000913.Suche in Google Scholar

Morley, J. C., C. R. Nelson, and E. Zivot. 2003. “Why Are the Beveridge-Nelson and Unobserved-Components Decompositions of GDP so Different?” The Review of Economics and Statistics 85 (2): 235–43. https://doi.org/10.1162/003465303765299765.Suche in Google Scholar

Morley, J. C., and J. Piger. 2008. “Trend/cycle Decomposition of Regime-Switching Processes.” Journal of Econometrics 146: 220–6. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2008.08.009.Suche in Google Scholar

Morley, J. C., and J. Piger. 2012. “The Asymmetric Business Cycle.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 94: 208–21. https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_00169.Suche in Google Scholar

Morley, J. C., J. Piger, and P.-L. Tien. 2013. “Reproducing Business Cycles Features: Are Nonlinear Dynamics a Proxy for Multivariate Information?” Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics 17 (5): 483–98.10.1515/snde-2012-0036Suche in Google Scholar

Morley, J. C., and Z. Rabah. 2014. “Testing for a Markov-Switching Mean in Serially Correlated Data.” In Recent Advances in Estimating Nonlinear Models, edited by J. Ma, and M. Wohar, 85–97. Berlin: Springer.10.1007/978-1-4614-8060-0_5Suche in Google Scholar

Patton, A. J., and A. Timmermann. 2007. “Properties of Optimal Forecasts under Asymmetric Loss and Nonlinearity.” Journal of Econometrics 140: 884–918. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2006.07.018.Suche in Google Scholar

Potter, S. 1995. “A Nonlinear Approach to U.S. GNP.” Journal of Applied Econometrics 10: 109–25. https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.3950100203.Suche in Google Scholar

Qu, Z., and F. Zhuo. 2021. “Likelihood Ratio Based Tests for Markov Regime Switching.” The Review of Economic Studies 88 (2): 937–68. https://doi.org/10.1093/restud/rdaa035.Suche in Google Scholar

Reinhart, C., and K. Rogoff. 2009. “The Aftermath of the Financial Crisis.” The American Economic Review 99 (2): 466–72. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.99.2.466.Suche in Google Scholar

Schüler, Y. S. 2021. “On the Cyclical Properties of Hamilton’s Regression Filter.” In Working Paper.10.2139/ssrn.3559776Suche in Google Scholar

Sinclair, T. 2010. “Asymmetry in the Business Cycle: Friedman’s Plucking Model with Correlated Innovations.” Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics 14 (1): 3. https://doi.org/10.2202/1558-3708.1688.Suche in Google Scholar

Stock, J. H. 1994. “Unit Roots, Structural Breaks, and Trends.” In Handbook of Econometrics, Vol. 4, edited by R. F. Engle, and D. L. McFadden, 2739–841. Amsterdam: Elsevier.10.1016/S1573-4412(05)80015-7Suche in Google Scholar

Received: 2022-05-11
Revised: 2022-07-12
Accepted: 2022-07-20
Published Online: 2022-08-15

© 2022 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Heruntergeladen am 2.10.2025 von https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejm-2022-0091/html
Button zum nach oben scrollen