Home Robustly Optimal Monetary Policy in a Behavioral Environment
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

Robustly Optimal Monetary Policy in a Behavioral Environment

  • Lahcen Bounader EMAIL logo and Guido Traficante
Published/Copyright: September 13, 2022

Abstract

This paper studies robustly optimal monetary policy with myopic agents in a behavioral New Keynesian model. The central bank is assumed to have Knightian uncertainty about the degree of myopia and the degree of price stickiness. We show that, under uncertainty about myopia, the Brainard’s attenuation principle holds under commitment and discretion, while, under uncertainty on price stickiness, alone or in addition to myopia, monetary policy becomes more aggressive. Welfare evaluation shows significant gains from a robust conduct of monetary policy when the model is distorted.

JEL Classification: E31; E52

Corresponding author: Lahcen Bounader, International Monetary Fund, Washington D.C., USA, E-mail:

Acknowledgements

We thank the editor Arpad Abraham, two anonymous referees, Jonathan Benchimol, Pompeo Della Posta, Domenico Delli Gatti, Thomas Lubik, Andrea Venegoni, all the participants at the WEAI Conference, the WEHIA October 2021 workshop, the 62nd Annual Conference of the Italian Economic Association, and at the ASSA 2022 Virtual Annual Meeting. Financial support from the European University of Rome is gratefully acknowledged. This paper does not represent the views of the IMF, its executive Board, or its Management. Any remaining errors are our own.

  1. Research funding: This work was supported by European University of Rome.

Appendix A: Phillips Curve Derivations

The problem of the behavioral firm is then to maximize

(32) k = 0 θ k E t BR Λ t , t + k P t * Y t + k | t Ψ t + k Y t + k | t

subject to the sequence of demand constraints

(33) Y t + k | t = P t * P t + k ε Y t + k

where Λ t , t + k = β k C t + k / C t γ P t + k / P t is the stochastic discount factor in nominal terms, Ψ t + k . is the cost function, and Yt+k|t denotes the output in period t + k for a firm that last reset its price in period t.

The FOC of the problem is the following

(34) k = 0 θ k E t BR Λ t , t + k Y t + k | t P t * M ψ t + k | t = 0

where M = ε ε 1 is the desired or frictionless markup.

By dividing Eq. (34) by Pt−1 and defining Π t , t + k = P t + k P t and M C t + k | t = ψ t + k | t P t + k , we obtain the following

(35) k = 0 θ k E t BR Λ t , t + k Y t + k | t P t * P t 1 M M C t + k | t Π t 1 , t + k = 0

We define the steady-state of Λt,t+k as β k , Yt+k|t as Y, P t * P t 1 as 1, MCt+k|t as 1 M , and Πt−1,t+k as 1. These defined steady-states allow us to expand the FOC Eq. (35) as follows

(36) k = 0 β θ k E t BR p t * p t 1 m c ̂ t + k | t + p t + k p t 1 = 0

with small letters denoting the logarithm of capital letters p t = ln P t and hat indicating the deviation with respect to the steady-state m c ̂ t + k | t = m c t + k | t m c , where mct+k|t = ln MCt+k|t, and mc = −μ, where μ = ln M .

By simplifying Eq. (36) we obtain

(37) p t * p t 1 = 1 β θ k = 0 β θ k E t BR m c ̂ t + k | t + p t + k p t 1

By rearranging the terms of Eq. (37), we obtain

(38) p t * = μ + 1 β θ k = 0 β θ k E t BR m c t + k | t + p t + k

The (log) marginal cost can be expressed as

(39) m c t + k | t = m c t + k

We replace Eq. (39) in Eq. (37) and find

(40) p t * p t 1 = 1 β θ k = 0 β θ k E t BR m c ̂ t + k + p t + k p t 1

Rearranging terms leads to the following expression

(41) p t * p t 1 = 1 β θ k = 0 β θ k E t BR m c ̂ t + k + p t + k p t 1

We apply the transition from bounded rationality expectations to objective expectations following Eq. (4)

(42) p t * p t 1 = 1 β θ k = 0 β θ m ̄ k E t m c ̂ t + k + p t + k p t 1

By writing this equation as a difference equation, we find

(43) p t * p t 1 = β θ m ̄ E t p t + 1 * p t + 1 β θ m c ̂ t + π t

We combine Eq. (43) with π t = 1 θ p t * p t 1 and

(44) m c ̂ t = γ + ϕ y t y t n

to obtain the Phillips curve Eq. (9).

Appendix B: Proofs

B.1 Proposition 1

The evil agent’s problem is the following

(45) max m ̄ 1 + κ ϵ 1 + κ ϵ β M f ρ u 2 σ u 2

We compute the FOC with respect to m ̄ obtaining:

(46) L m ̄ = 2 ( 1 + κ ϵ ) β ρ u M f m ̄ 1 + κ ϵ β M f ρ u 3 σ u 2

where

(47) M f m ̄ = θ + ( 1 β θ ) ( 1 θ ) 1 β θ m ̄ + β θ m ̄ ( 1 β θ ) ( 1 θ ) ( 1 β θ m ̄ ) 2

It is easy to verify that M f m ̄ > 0 . Moreover, since the denominator is surely positive (βM f ρ u is the product of three positive parameters less than one) we can conclude L m ̄ > 0 .

B.2 Proposition 2

The evil agent’s problem in this case is the following

(48) max θ 1 + κ ϵ 1 + κ ϵ β M f ρ u 2 σ u 2

The parameter θ enters in coefficient κ, hence the derivative of the loss function (17) with respect to θ will be

(49) L θ = 2 1 + κ ϵ ϵ κ θ β ρ u M f θ 1 β M f ρ u + κ ϵ 3 + 1 + ϵ κ θ 1 β M f ρ u + κ ϵ 2 σ u 2

which can be simplified as follows

(50) L θ = 1 + β M f ρ u + κ ϵ ϵ κ θ + 2 1 + κ ϵ β ρ u M f θ + 1 β M f ρ u + κ ϵ 1 β M f ρ u + κ ϵ 3 σ u 2

Now we write down the expression for derivatives inside

(51) κ θ = β θ 2 1 θ 2 ( γ + ϕ ) < 0

and,

(52) M f θ = 1 + m ̄ β m ̄ ( β θ ) 2 m ̄ + 2 β θ β 1 1 β θ m ̄ 2

By working on (52), we can show that the derivative is positive if

β θ 2 m ̄ 2 θ + 1 > 0

which occurs for values of θ < 2 4 4 β m ̄ 2 β m ̄ , while the other analytical condition that implies a positive sign for the inequation, i.e. θ > 2 + 4 4 β m ̄ 2 β m ̄ is ruled out because this second root is always larger than one.

Therefore, in this case, the sign of the loss function derivative is unclear. The whole denominator should be evaluated. By replacing (51) and (52) in (66) and simplifying, we obtain

L θ 1 + β M f ρ u + κ ϵ ϵ β θ 2 1 γ + ϕ 1 β θ m ̄ 2 + 2 1 + κ ϵ β ρ u m ̄ θ 2 β m ̄ ( β θ ) 2 m ̄ + 2 β θ β 1 + 1 β M f ρ u + κ ϵ θ 2 1 β θ m ̄ 2

Evaluating each term of the above derivative reveals that L θ > 0 . Thus, we obtain the proposition.

B.3 Proposition 4

The policy problem of the central bank in this setup is the following

(53) t = 0 β t π t 2 + ϑ x t 2

subject to the Phillips curve Eq. (9).

As in the main text, the FOCs of this problem could be expressed as a targeting rule in a single equation

(54) π t = ϑ κ x t + ϑ M f κ x t 1

We replace π t in the Phillips curve Eq. (9), which yields the following difference equation

(55) ϑ κ + β ϑ κ ( M f ) 2 + κ x t = ϑ κ M f x t 1 β M f ϑ κ E t x t + 1 + u t

By changing the notation to α = M f ϑ 2 1 + β ( M f ) 2 + ϑ κ 2 and rearranging, this can be written as

(56) x t = α x t 1 + α β E t x t + 1 α κ ϑ u t

The stationary solution of this equation is

(57) x t = ψ x t 1 κ ψ ϑ ( 1 β ψ ρ u ) u t

where ψ = 1 1 4 β α 2 2 α β .

Plaguing this expression to the Phillips curve yields

(58) π t = ψ π t 1 + ψ 1 β ψ ρ u ( u t u t 1 )

Solving the IS Eq. (5) for the interest rate, we obtain

i t = 1 σ ( x t M E t x t + 1 ) + E t π t + 1 + r t e

We now replace the expressions for x and π Eqs. (57) and (58) in the interest rate equation above, which completes the proof of this proposition.

Appendix C: Alternative Specification of the Phillips Curve

In this Appendix, we derive the paper’s results using an alternative specification of the Phillips Curve (PC) following Benchimol and Bounader (2019). The PC is specified as follows

(59) π t = β M f E t π t + 1 + κ x t + u t

with M f = m ̄ and κ is defined as before.

The loss function of the central bank is defined as earlier, with the only exception that M f = m ̄ . Applying the first-order conditions we arrive, as in the main text, at the following expression where M f takes the value defined in (59):

(60) L = 1 + κ ϵ 1 β M f ρ u + κ ϵ 2 σ u 2

The robustly optimal monetary policy is derived by considering the worst-case scenario of the loss function with respect to uncertain parameters

Proposition 5

If the policy maker is uncertain about:

  1. m ̄ , a robust policy should be based on m ̄ = m ̄ max .

  2. θ, a robust policy should be based on θ =θmax.

  3. m ̄ and θ, jointly, a robust policy should be based on m ̄ = m ̄ max and θ =θmax.

Proof

The evil agent’s problem is the following when there is uncertainty about m ̄

(61) max m ̄ 1 + κ ϵ 1 + κ ϵ β M f ρ u 2 σ u 2

We compute the FOC with respect to m ̄ obtaining:

(62) L m ̄ = 2 ( 1 + κ ϵ ) β ρ u M f m ̄ 1 + κ ϵ β M f ρ u 3 σ u 2

where

(63) M f m ̄ = 1 > 0

Since the denominator is surely positive (βM f ρ u is the product of three positive parameters less than one), we can conclude L m ̄ > 0 .

The evil agent’s problem is the following when there is uncertainty about θ

(64) max θ 1 + κ ϵ 1 + κ ϵ β M f ρ u 2 σ u 2
(65) L θ = 2 1 + κ ϵ ϵ κ θ β ρ u M f θ 1 β M f ρ u + κ ϵ 3 + 1 + ϵ κ θ 1 β M f ρ u + κ ϵ 2 σ u 2

which can be simplified, given that M f θ = 0 , as follows

(66) L θ = 1 + β M f ρ u + κ ϵ ϵ κ θ + 1 β M f ρ u + κ ϵ 1 β M f ρ u + κ ϵ 3 σ u 2

Now we write down the expression for derivatives inside

(67) κ θ = β θ 2 1 θ 2 ( γ + ϕ ) < 0

Since κ θ < 0 , it is easy to check that L θ > 0 , an thus θ =θmax.

The proof of the last bullet is straightforward given L θ > 0 and L m ̄ > 0 .

Determinacy region under robustness Under passive monetary policy, the equilibrium is determinate if the below condition is satisfied

(68) 1 β M f ( 1 M ) κ σ > 1

Under uncertainty with respect to θ, we differentiate the determinacy condition with respect to θ

(69) 1 β m ̄ κ 2 σ β κ M f θ = 0 + 1 β M f κ θ < 0

Uncertainty on price rigidity increases the determinacy area for any policy that does not respond at all to inflation. This result is quite straightforward under the current specification than the one derived in the core of the paper, since the derivative is undoubtedly positive.

References

André, M. C., and M. Dai. 2018. “Learning, Robust Monetary Policy and the Merit of Precaution.” The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 18 (2): 20160236, https://doi.org/10.1515/bejm-2016-0236.Search in Google Scholar

Barlevy, G. 2011. “Robustness and Macroeconomic Policy.” Annual Review of Economics 3 (1): 1–24. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-061109-080355.Search in Google Scholar

Benchimol, J., and L. Bounader. 2019. Optimal Monetary Policy Under Bounded Rationality. USA: International Monetary Fund.10.2139/ssrn.3442880Search in Google Scholar

Bils, M., and P. J. Klenow. 2004. “Some Evidence on the Importance of Sticky Prices.” Journal of Political Economy 112 (5): 947–85. https://doi.org/10.1086/422559.Search in Google Scholar

Brainard, W. C. 1967. “Uncertainty and the Effectiveness of Policy.” The American Economic Review 57 (2): 411–25.Search in Google Scholar

Clarida, R., J. Gali, and M. Gertler. 1999. “The Science of Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian Perspective.” Journal of Economic Literature 37 (4): 1661–707. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.37.4.1661.Search in Google Scholar

Evans, G. W., and S. Honkapohja. 2009. “Learning and Macroeconomics.” Annual Review of Economics 1 (1): 421–49. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.economics.050708.142927.Search in Google Scholar

Friedman, M. 1953. “The Effects of a Full-Employment Policy on Economic Stability: A Formal Analysis.” In Essays in Positive Economics, 117–32. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Search in Google Scholar

Gabaix, X. 2014. “A Sparsity-Based Model of Bounded Rationality.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (4): 1661–710. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qju024.Search in Google Scholar

Gabaix, X. 2020. “A Behavioral New Keynesian Model.” The American Economic Review 110 (8): 2271–327. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20162005.Search in Google Scholar

Galí, J. 2015. Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the New Keynesian Framework and Its Applications. UK: Princeton University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Galí, J., and M. Gertler. 1999. “Inflation Dynamics: A Structural Econometric Analysis.” Journal of Monetary Economics 44 (2): 195–222. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0304-3932(99)00023-9.Search in Google Scholar

Giannoni, M. P. 2002. “Does Model Uncertainty Justify Caution? Robust Optimal Monetary Policy in a Forward-Looking Model.” Macroeconomic Dynamics 6 (1): 111. https://doi.org/10.1017/s1365100502027062.Search in Google Scholar

Hansen, L. P., and T. J. Sargent. 2015. “Four Types of Ignorance.” Journal of Monetary Economics 69: 97–113. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2014.12.008.Search in Google Scholar

Hasui, K. 2020. “A Note on Robust Monetary Policy and Non-zero Trend Inflation.” Macroeconomic Dynamics 24 (6): 1574–94. https://doi.org/10.1017/s1365100518000883.Search in Google Scholar

Hasui, K. 2021. “Trend Growth and Robust Monetary Policy.” The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 21 (2): 449–72. https://doi.org/10.1515/bejm-2020-0133.Search in Google Scholar

Ilabaca, F., G. Meggiorini, and F. Milani. 2020. “Bounded Rationality, Monetary Policy, and Macroeconomic Stability.” Economics Letters 186: 108522. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2019.07.007.Search in Google Scholar

Levin, A. T., A. Onatski, J. C. Williams, and N. Williams. 2005. “Monetary Policy under Uncertainty in Micro-founded Macroeconometric Models.” NBER Macroeconomics Annual 20: 229–87. https://doi.org/10.1086/ma.20.3585423.Search in Google Scholar

Levin, A. T., and J. C. Williams. 2003. “Robust Monetary Policy with Competing Reference Models.” Journal of Monetary Economics 50 (5): 945–75. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0304-3932(03)00059-x.Search in Google Scholar

Lubik, T. A., and C. Matthes. 2016. “Indeterminacy and Learning: An Analysis of Monetary Policy in the Great Inflation.” Journal of Monetary Economics 82: 85–106. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2016.07.006.Search in Google Scholar

Lucas, J. 1976. “Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique.” In The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, edited by K. Brunner, and A. Meltzer. North Holland: Elsevier Science Publishers B.V.Search in Google Scholar

Milani, F. 2008. “Learning, Monetary Policy Rules, and Macroeconomic Stability.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32 (10): 3148–65. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2007.12.004.Search in Google Scholar

Nakamura, E., and J. Steinsson. 2013. “Price Rigidity: Microeconomic Evidence and Macroeconomic Implications.” Annual Review of Economics 5 (1): 133–63. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-061109-080430.Search in Google Scholar

Onatski, A., and J. H. Stock. 2002. “Robust Monetary Policy under Model Uncertainty in a Small Model of the Us Economy.” Macroeconomic Dynamics 6 (1): 85–110. https://doi.org/10.1017/s1365100502027050.Search in Google Scholar

Onatski, A., and N. Williams. 2003. “Modeling Model Uncertainty.” Journal of the European Economic Association 1 (5): 1087–122. https://doi.org/10.1162/154247603770383406.Search in Google Scholar

Orphanides, A. 2001. “Monetary Policy Rules Based on Real-Time Data.” The American Economic Review 91 (4): 964–85. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.91.4.964.Search in Google Scholar

Orphanides, A. 2003a. “Historical Monetary Policy Analysis and the Taylor Rule.” Journal of Monetary Economics 50 (5): 983–1022. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0304-3932(03)00065-5.Search in Google Scholar

Orphanides, A. 2003b. “The Quest for Prosperity without Inflation.” Journal of Monetary Economics 50 (3): 633–63. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0304-3932(03)00028-x.Search in Google Scholar

Pellegrino, G., E. Castelnuovo, and G. Caggiano. 2020. “Uncertainty and Monetary Policy during Extreme Events.” CAMA Working Paper No. 80/2020. Also available at https://ssrn.com/abstract=3684962 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3684962.10.2139/ssrn.3699241Search in Google Scholar

Poloz, S. S. 2020. “Monetary Policy in Unknowable Times,” a speech in Eric J. Hanson Memorial Lecture, University of Alberta.Search in Google Scholar

Taylor, J. B. 1993. “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice.” In Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39, 195–214. Elsevier. https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/016722319390009L.10.1016/0167-2231(93)90009-LSearch in Google Scholar

Tillmann, P. 2009. “Optimal Monetary Policy with an Uncertain Cost Channel.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 41 (5): 885–906. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1538-4616.2009.00237.x.Search in Google Scholar

Traficante, G. 2013. “Monetary Policy, Parameter Uncertainty and Welfare.” Journal of Macroeconomics 35: 73–80. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2012.11.005.Search in Google Scholar

Walsh, C. E. 2005. “Endogenous Objectives and the Evaluation of Targeting Rules for Monetary Policy.” Journal of Monetary Economics 52 (5): 889–911. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.07.003.Search in Google Scholar

Received: 2022-01-27
Accepted: 2022-08-28
Published Online: 2022-09-13

© 2022 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 30.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejm-2022-0031/html
Scroll to top button