Startseite Credit Resource Misallocation and Macroeconomic Fluctuations in China: From the Perspective of Heterogeneous Financial Frictions
Artikel Öffentlich zugänglich

Credit Resource Misallocation and Macroeconomic Fluctuations in China: From the Perspective of Heterogeneous Financial Frictions

  • Jian Zhou ORCID logo EMAIL logo , Zhipeng Zhang ORCID logo und Yu Shao ORCID logo
Veröffentlicht/Copyright: 25. Dezember 2023

Abstract

In China, state-owned firms exhibit easier access to external credit but have lower productivity than private firms. We construct a dynamic general equilibrium model incorporating heterogeneous financial frictions to investigate their impact on credit resource misallocation and macroeconomic fluctuations in the Chinese economy. A calibration of our model suggests that heterogeneity in financial frictions can reduce macroeconomic volatility. The mechanism is that heterogeneity in financial frictions induces the procyclicality of credit resource misallocation within entrepreneurs, thus the procyclicality of productivity loss. The stabilization effect depends on the relative magnitude of the impact of the shock on credit resource misallocation within entrepreneurs compared to its impact on the output. In addition, we show that the cost of the stabilization effect of heterogeneity in financial frictions is that it reduces the economy’s aggregate TFP and output at the steady state. Our results imply that neglecting heterogeneity may overestimate the impact of financial frictions on economic volatility in previous studies.

JEL Classification: E44; E52; G28

1 Introduction

How do financial frictions affect an economy’s fluctuations? A standard view is that it amplifies shocks to the macroeconomy. In particular, the dynamic interaction between credit limits that depend on the value of collateral and asset prices turns out to be an amplification transmission mechanism, such as the mechanism of Bernanke and Gertler (1999) and Kiyotaki and Moore (1997). The research on the amplification effects of financial friction is mainly based on representative financial friction, which means that all borrowers face the same type of financial friction. However, some recent studies have found that financial friction has heterogeneity among borrowers, which is more significant in developing countries (Ordoñez 2013; Ottonello and Winberry 2020). How does heterogeneity in financial frictions affect this amplification mechanism?

In this paper, we argue that heterogeneity in financial frictions in China can reduce macroeconomic volatility by inducing procyclicality in credit resource misallocation within entrepreneurs. We introduce collateral constraints consistent with Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) to model financial frictions. To illustrate the impact of heterogeneous financial frictions that are consistent with the characteristics of the Chinese economy on the transmission mechanism of shocks, we extend the research framework of Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) to incorporate two key aspects of heterogeneity.

First, different types of enterprises face different financial frictions. The Chinese government guarantees state-owned enterprises (SOEs), so SOEs face weaker financial frictions (Song, Storesletten, and Zilibotti 2011). By contrast, financing is relatively difficult for private-owned enterprises (POEs), especially for small and medium-sized private enterprises (Beck and Demirguc-Kunt 2006).[1] While SOEs can obtain financing through commercial banks’ on-balance-sheet operations, POEs are more likely to obtain financing from commercial banks’ off-balance-sheet operations or “shadow banking” (Lu et al. 2015).

Second, there is heterogeneity in productivity across enterprises, with SOEs having lower productivity than private firms, as estimated by empirical research (Brandt, Van Biesebroeck, and Zhang 2012; Hsieh and Klenow 2009). In addition, there is accumulating evidence that can account for the low productivity of SOEs, such as over-employment or over-investment (Bai et al. 2000; Chen et al. 2011), high agency cost (Huang et al. 2017), or lack of competition (Li, Liu, and Wang 2015).

We identify these two key aspects of firms’ heterogeneity in China by exploiting two empirical strategies and firm-level data. First, to identify that different types of enterprises face different financial frictions, we use differences in the response of firm debt size to total credit supply to identify differences in financial frictions faced by different types of firms. Second, we use three methods to measure firms’ productivity and illustrate that SOEs are less productive than POEs. Our empirical findings from firm-level microdata are consistent with several findings based on macroeconomic data (Chang et al. 2019; Song, Storesletten, and Zilibotti 2011).

To illustrate the implications of heterogeneity in financial frictions, we solve the model using calibrated parameters such that the model can match China’s economy. The characterization of steady states and dynamics allows us to derive several important implications.

First, we find that heterogeneity in financial frictions can reduce macroeconomic volatility. As heterogeneity in financial frictions becomes larger, the volatility of output becomes smaller. Therefore, heterogeneity in financial frictions plays a stabilizing role in the business cycle. The role of stabilizing the economy is related to the type of shock. For TFP shock and net worth shock, heterogeneity in financial frictions reduces output fluctuations by no more than 2 %, but for preference shock, can reduce output fluctuations by more than 20 %. In addition, heterogeneity in financial frictions has a nonlinear effect, such that the increase in heterogeneity will lead to an increasing decrease in output volatility.

Second, the mechanism by which heterogeneity in financial frictions reduces the macroeconomic volatility is the procyclical credit resources misallocation within entrepreneurs. Specifically, a positive shock leads to a procyclical increase of misallocation within entrepreneurs, then a procyclical increase of productivity loss and, therefore, lower output volatility.

Third, the extent to which heterogeneous financial frictions can mitigate economic volatility depends on the relative magnitude of the impact of the shock on the credit resource misallocation within entrepreneurs and the output. A larger magnitude of the impact of the shock on the credit resource misallocation within entrepreneurs implies a greater degree of procyclicality of productivity loss, which in turn mitigates economic volatility to a greater extent.

Finally, heterogeneity in financial frictions leads to credit resource misallocation within entrepreneurs in the steady state, which reduces the economy’s aggregate TFP and output in the steady state. However, the impact of heterogeneity in financial frictions on social welfare depends on the economy’s sensitivity to the level and volatility of consumption.

The robustness of our findings about heterogeneity in financial frictions depends on the plausibility of our calibrated parameters and model setup. We evaluate the findings’ plausibility by investigating the sensitivity of parameters and extensions. First, we compare the result of our baseline model with models calibrated to several different parameters, and the conclusion still holds. Second, our model’s implications are robust to three alternative specifications related to credit resource allocation or firms’ heterogeneity in China’s economy: household heterogeneity, supply chain structure, and earning-based borrowing constraints.

Our work is related to three strands of literature. First, our paper contributes to several theoretical studies about financial frictions, which are developed from two perspectives. One type of study emphasizes the information asymmetry between banks and firms, which leads to constraints on the financing of firms due to the possibility of firm default (Bernanke and Gertler 1999; Kiyotaki and Moore 1997); the other type emphasizes the information asymmetry between banks and savers, which leads to constraints on the amount of savings due to the possibility of bank default (Gertler and Karadi 2011; Gertler and Kiyotaki 2010). The theory of financial frictions is widely used to explain the large economic fluctuations during each crisis and the slow recovery process after the crisis (Arellano, Bai, and Kehoe 2018; Bianchi 2020; Buera and Shin 2013; Cai 2021). This paper is consistent with Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), which assumes that firms face information asymmetries with banks, that the credit constraint depends on the net worth of firms. However, heterogeneity in financial frictions may have important implications that have received less attention in the literature (Buera, Kaboski, and Shin 2015). In contrast to Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), we emphasize the impact of heterogeneity in financial frictions on the allocation of credit resources across different types of entrepreneurs.

The second strand of related literature provides an empirical analysis of the impact of financial frictions. At the macro level, financial frictions delay the post-crisis recovery by limiting information, exacerbate the business cycle asymmetry (Ordoñez 2013), and are an important transmission mechanism for the economic impact of cross-border capital flows (Gallego and Tessada 2012). At the micro level, financial frictions are associated with firm size (Buera, Kaboski, and Shin 2011), productivity (McKenzie and Woodruff 2006; Moll 2014), and industry (Hurst and Pugsley 2011), with firms facing greater financial frictions choosing to self-finance (Moll 2014; Pawasutipaisit and Townsend 2011). On the one hand, the findings of a series of empirical analyses provide empirical evidence to establish the micro-foundations of heterogeneous financial frictions; on the other hand, our model provides a new perspective to explain the macroeconomic impact of financial frictions.

The third strand of literature related to this paper concerns the characteristics and differences between SOEs and POEs. SOEs have easier access to loans from on-balance-sheet banking operations and lower financing costs than private firms, which rely more on off-balance-sheet loans from “shadow banks” (Chang et al. 2019; Elliott, Kroeber, and Qiao 2015; Lu et al. 2015). In terms of profitability and leverage, SOEs have higher leverage and lower profitability than POEs (DeWenter and Malatesta 2001; Hsieh and Klenow 2009). In addition, empirical evidence suggests that firm leverage is positively related to firm size (Katagiri 2014). Differences in firm leverage and changes in leverage may have important implications for the structural transformation of the economy and the business cycle, and a number of studies have analyzed this feature in a general equilibrium framework (Campbell and Cocco 2007; Jensen et al. 2020; Mian, Sufi, and Verner 2017; Verner and Gyöngyösi 2020). In this paper, we combine heterogeneous firms with the framework of Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), where heterogeneity in different types of entrepreneurs arises from differences in credit constraints and productivity, and thus, different types of firms have different leverage ratios in equilibrium.

The rest of this paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents the stylized facts about firms’ heterogeneity. Section 3 presents the theoretical model. Section 4 determines the parameter values and then shows the quantitative results. Section 5 presents the robustness analysis and some extensions. Section 6 concludes.

2 Firms’ Heterogeneity in China: Stylized Facts

This section describes two characteristics of China’s economy that have emerged in recent years, which form the basis for constructing our theoretical model. On the one hand, there is heterogeneity in the financial frictions faced by firms, with SOEs receiving preferential credit treatment; on the other hand, there is heterogeneity in the productivity across firms, with SOEs having lower productivity than POEs. Unlike the approach in related literature that uses macroeconomic data to show the relevant facts, we reveal these facts through microdata.

2.1 Data

While much macroeconomic data indicates a negative relationship between productivity and financial frictions, it is difficult to eliminate confounding factors, and we explore the empirical evidence of these stylized facts using microdata. We use firm-level data from the Chinese Industrial Enterprises Database, which contains basic information and financial data of firms covering the period from 1998 to 2015 (2010 data are excluded due to severe missing data). More than 90 % of the industrial enterprises in this database are manufacturing enterprises, including all SOEs and non-SOEs above the designated size.[2] We further screened the sample according to the following criteria: (1) removing samples with missing variables, e.g. removing samples with missing industrial output value, fixed assets, number of employees, etc.; (2) defining SOEs as “state-controlled” and “collectively-controlled” enterprises, and deleting the sample of foreign- or Hong Kong-, Macao-, and Taiwan-held enterprises; (3) winsorizing the data at 1st and 99th percentile. Meanwhile, we use the annual new loan data by province to measure the change in total credit supply faced by firms, obtained from the CEIC database.

2.2 Measurement of Productivity

We measured the firm’s productivity using three methods: the OP method (Olley and Pakes 1996), the LP method (Levinsohn and Petrin 2003), and the capital efficiency method (Chen and Song 2013). The first two methods assume that the firm’s production function is of the Cobb–Douglas form

(1) y t = a 0 + a l l t + a k k t + a m m t + ω t + η t ,

where y t denotes the logarithm of the firm’s output, l t , k t and m t denote the labor, capital and intermediate goods inputs required for production, respectively, ω t denotes the TFP observable when the firm decides on the amount of inputs, but ω t is not observed by econometricians, and η t denotes a random factor unrelated to the firm’s decision. On the one hand, for the econometricians, the error term contains both ω t and η t , and direct use of OLS regressions will yield biased and inconsistent estimates, i.e. a simultaneity bias is generated. On the other hand, firms will choose to continue their business or exit the market based on their current capital stock or productivity, and what is observed in the data is only those firms that choose to continue their business, thus generating a sample selection bias.

Olley and Pakes (1996) solved the simultaneity bias by controlling for the correlation between the level of factor inputs and the productivity of the firm, using investment as a proxy variable for the TFP ω t , and solved the sample selection bias by estimating the survival probability of the firm. It is assumed that the firm’s objective is to maximize the discounted value of future profits so that the firm forms an understanding of the future market structure based on the currently available information, and then makes entry and exit decisions and investment size decisions. Assuming that ω t obeys the first-order Markov process and defining x t as the variable measuring whether a firm exits the market and i t as the firm’s investment size, the optimization problem is as follows:

x t = 1 , i f ω t > ω ̲ t k t 0 , otherwise ,

and

i t = i t ω t , k t .

Assuming that the size of a firm’s investment is strictly increasing with respect to productivity, productivity can be expressed as a function of investment and capital

(2) ω t = h i t , k t .

Therefore, the simultaneity bias can be corrected by controlling the investment size. Substituting (2) into (1), it is thus possible to use the OLS method to estimate

(3) y t = a l l t + a m m t + ϕ i t , k t + η t ,

where ϕ i t , k t = a 0 + a k k t + h i t , k t is a second-order polynomial in investment i t and capital k t , and denote ϕ ̂ t as its estimate. The expectation for both sides of equation (3) yields

(4) E y t | i t , k t = a l E l t | i t , k t + a m E m t | i t , k t + ϕ i t , k t .

Combining equations (3) and (4) yields

(5) y t E y t | i t , k t = a l l t E l t | i t , k t + a m m t E m t | i t , k t + η t

The estimation of equation (5) yields the consistent estimates a l ̂ and a m ̂ for a l and a m . Therefore,

(6) y t a l ̂ l t a m ̂ m t = ϕ i t , k t + η t = a 0 + a k k t + h i t , k t + η t ,

where h i t , k t = ϕ i t , k t a 0 a k k t can be expressed as a function of ϕ and k, i.e. h i t , k t = g ϕ t 1 a 0 a k k t 1 + ξ t . Then equation (6) can be rewritten as

(7) y t a l ̂ l t a m ̂ m t = a 0 + a k k t + g ϕ t 1 a 0 a k k t 1 + η t + ξ t

The parameters a k can be identified using nonlinear least squares (NLS) estimation for equation (7). To avoid the sample selection bias, we need to estimate the firm’s survival probability P t , and denote P ̂ t as the fitted value obtained by building a Probit model of x t with respect to investment i t and capital k t . Then we can use NLS to estimate the following equation

y t a l ̂ l t a m ̂ m t = a k k t + g ϕ ̂ t 1 a k k t , P ̂ t + η t + ξ t ,

where g can be approximated by a second-order polynomial with respect to ϕ ̂ t 1 a k k t and P ̂ t . Thus, the OP method estimation of TFP results in

ω t ̂ = y t a 0 ̂ a l ̂ l t a k ̂ k t a m ̂ m t .

However, due to the intermittent investment by many firms, a large amount of data with an investment size of 0 is excluded from the estimation. The LP method addresses this problem by using intermediate goods inputs as a proxy variable for the TFP ω t . Given a firm’s capital size, it is assumed that the marginal output of intermediate goods will increase as the firm’s productivity increases, and thus the firm will increase its input of intermediate goods, further increasing output. The demand function for intermediate goods is

m t = m t ω t , k t .

Under the monotonicity assumption, productivity can be written as a function of intermediate goods m t and capital k t

ω t = h m t , k t .

Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) argue that the sample selection bias is negligible, and a large number of firms have zero investment. Therefore, consistent estimates of TFP can be obtained using intermediate goods inputs as a proxy variable.

To further verify the robustness of the findings, we also use the capital productivity (KP) from Chen and Song (2013) to measure firms’ productivity, which is defined as

K P t = outpu t t wag e t capita l t

2.3 Heterogeneity in Financial Frictions and Productivity

2.3.1 Heterogeneity in Financial Frictions

Many factors influence the size of a firm’s debt. For example, firms with more land holdings have more liabilities because they can obtain financing through land mortgage (Liu, Wang, and Zha 2013). In addition, firm size, profitability, and tangible assets affect the firm’s capital structure and influence the trade-off between equity financing and debt financing (Katagiri 2014). Here, we focus on the differences in firms’ debt sizes caused by differences in financial frictions. We use differences in the response of firm debt size to total credit supply to identify the different financial frictions faced by different types of firms. We build the following regression model

(8) L i a b i l i t i e s ijt = α 0 + α 1 L o a n S u p p l y j t + γ W ijt + μ i t + ϵ ijt ,

where Liabilities ijt denotes the logarithm of the liabilities of firm i located in province j in year t; LoanSupply jt is the logarithm of the total credit supply of province j in year t; W ijt is a set of control variables at the firm level; μ it is a firm and industry fixed effect; and ϵ ijt is a disturbance term. The regression model (8) largely avoids the reverse causality problem because changes in the size of individual firms’ liabilities hardly affect the credit supply decision in a given province. When credit supply increases exogenously, firms facing weaker financial frictions can rapidly increase the size of their liabilities, while firms facing stronger financial frictions have to face stricter scrutiny to obtain new loans. Thus, α 1 reflects the degree of financial frictions of firms, and the larger α 1 is, the weaker the financial frictions is.

The estimation results of equation (8) are shown in Table 1. Column (1) of Table 1 is the regression results for the full sample, and columns (2) and (3) are the regression results for the subsamples of SOEs and POEs, respectively. For the full sample, an increase in credit supply significantly raises the size of liabilities. For the subsamples, an increase in credit supply causes a significant increase in the liabilities of SOEs, while a much smaller increase in the liabilities of POEs. In addition, the results in Table 1 are consistent with the literature that POEs have more severe financing constraints compared to SOEs (Bai, Lu, and Tao 2006; Fairlie et al. 2022; Herranz, Krasa, and Villamil 2015; Lu et al. 2015; Zhang et al. 2015).

Table 1:

Firms differ in financial frictions.

(1) Total (2) SOEs (3) POEs
LoanSupply 0.0669c 0.1968c 0.0578c
(0.0012) (0.0040) (0.0013)
Age 0.0070c 0.0029c 0.0086c
(0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001)
ROE −0.8550c −0.8662c −0.8370c
(0.0114) (0.0482) (0.0115)
Lncapital 0.4424c 0.5170c 0.4289c
(0.0007) (0.0018) (0.0007)
Lnlabor 0.4569c 0.4335c 0.4547c
(0.0010) (0.0025) (0.0011)
Constant 2.7480c 1.4651c 2.9273c
(0.0081) (0.0225) (0.0091)
Industry fixed effects Y Y Y
Province fixed effects Y Y Y
Year fixed effects Y Y Y
N 2,456,786 390,137 2,066,649
Adj. R 2 0.5234 0.6649 0.4964
  1. Heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors in parentheses; aSignificant at the 10 percent level; bSignificant at the 5 percent level; cSignificant at the 1 percent level.

2.3.2 Heterogeneity in Productivity

To analyze the heterogeneity in productivity among different types of firms, we develop the following regression model:

(9) T F P ijt = β 0 + β 1 S O E s i + γ W ijt + μ i t + e ijt ,

where SOEs i is a dummy variable, indicating whether firm i is a SOE. The regression results of equation (9) are shown in Table 2, where the dependent variable in column (1) is TFP measured by the LP method, the dependent variable in column (2) is TFP measured by the OP method, and the dependent variable in column (3) is firm productivity measured by capital productivity (KP). Table 2 illustrates that SOEs are less productive than private firms, and the findings are robust to productivity measures.

Table 2:

Firms differ in productivity.

(1) TFP_LP (2) TFP_OP (3) KP
SOEs −0.5178c −0.5204c −1.0109c
(0.0028) (0.0039) (0.0044)
Age −0.0041c −0.0077c −0.0047c
(0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0001)
Lnasset 0.4870c 0.1681c −0.5043c
(0.0005) (0.0007) (0.0011)
Constant 1.4821c 1.7632c 7.6866c
(0.0048) (0.0070) (0.0122)
Industry fixed effects Y Y Y
Province fixed effects Y Y Y
Year fixed effects Y Y Y
N 2,455,483 975,832 2,455,483
Adj. R 2 0.3385 0.1518 0.1735
  1. Heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors in parentheses; aSignificant at the 10 percent level; bSignificant at the 5 percent level; cSignificant at the 1 percent level.

In summary, we find evidence from microdata that SOEs have lower productivity and face weaker financial frictions than POEs, consistent with several findings based on macro data (Chang et al. 2019; Song, Storesletten, and Zilibotti 2011). Later, we will construct a theoretical model based on heterogeneity in firms to explore its impact on economic volatility.

3 Simple Model of Heterogenous Financial Frictions

In our economy, there is a continuum of identical and competitive households. Households lend to intermediate entrepreneurs via financial intermediates. The households’ utility depends on consumption goods and leisure, but the intermediate entrepreneurs’ utility depends on consumption goods only. The intermediate entrepreneurs need external financing for investment spending, which is constrained by the value of capital. Following Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), we assume that the households are more patient than the intermediate entrepreneurs, so the collateral constraint is binding in equilibrium.

3.1 Households

The model is populated by a continuum of identical households. Households maximize their expected utility by choosing the quantity of final goods consumed C h,t , labor hours H t , and saving D t . The representative household’s utility function is given by

(10) U = E 0 t = 0 β t z t ln C h , t Ψ H t 1 η 1 η ,

where E 0 denotes the expectation operator, the parameter β ∈ (0, 1) denotes the subjective discount factor, Ψ > 0 reflects negative utility from labor, and η is the inverse Frisch elasticity of labor supply. The term z t represents a shock to the households’ patience factor that follows the AR(1) process

(11) ln z t = ρ z ln z t 1 + σ z u z , t ,

where ρ z ∈ (0, 1) is the persistence parameter, σ z is the standard deviation of the innovation, and u z,t is an independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.) standard normal process.

Denoting the real wage by W t , the gross real loan rate by R t , the earnings received from capital good firms based on the household’s ownership share by Div t , the flow of funds constraint for the household is given by

(12) C h , t + D t = W t H t + R t 1 D t 1 + D i v t

The household chooses C h,t , H t , and D t to maximize (10) subject to (11) and (12).

3.2 Final Good Firms

The final good for consumption and investment Y t is a composite of intermediate goods given by

Y t = ϕ Y s , t σ 1 σ + 1 ϕ Y p , t σ 1 σ σ σ 1 ,

where Y s,t and Y p,t denote the intermediate products produced by SOEs and POEs, respectively. Denote by P s,t and P p,t the relative price of SOEs’ products and POEs’ products, respectively. The cost-minimization problem of final good firms is

max Y t P s , t Y s , t P p , t Y p , t ,

which implies

Y s , t = ϕ σ P s , t σ Y t ,

Y p , t = 1 ϕ σ P p , t σ Y t .

The zero-profit condition for the final good sector means

ϕ σ P s , t 1 σ + 1 ϕ σ P p 1 σ = 1 .

3.3 Capital Good Firms

Capital good firms produce capital and sell it to the intermediate entrepreneurs. Capital good firms maximize their discounted sum of profits

E 0 t = 0 β t λ t Q t I t 1 Ω 2 ζ t I t I t 1 1 2 I t ,

where λ t is the lagrangian multiplier of households’ budget constraint, Q t is the capital price in consumption units, Ω > 0 is the adjustment cost parameter. Following Christiano, Motto, and Rostagno (2014), we interpret ζ t as the investment-specific shock in producing capital. The investment-specific shock ζ t follows the stochastic process

(13) ln ζ t = ρ ζ ln ζ t 1 + σ ζ u ζ , t .

The parameter ρ ζ ∈ (0, 1) is the persistence parameter, σ ζ is the standard deviation of the innovation, and u ζ,t is an i.i.d. standard normal process.

3.4 The Intermediate Entrepreneurs

Intermediate goods are produced by two types of intermediate entrepreneurs: SOEs (type s) and POEs (type p). The intermediate entrepreneurs have the utility function

(14) E 0 t = 0 β t ln C j , t ,

where C j,t denotes the type j intermediate entrepreneurs’ consumption and β′ < β is the subjective discount factor.

The intermediate entrepreneurs produce intermediate goods using labor and capital as inputs, with the production function

(15) Y j , t = A j , t K j , t 1 1 α H j , t α ,

where A j,t denotes the total factor productivity of type j entrepreneurs, K j,t−1 and H j,t denote the inputs of capital and labor, respectively, and the parameter α ∈ (0, 1) measures the output elasticity of labor. We assume the total factor productivity A j,t is composed of a permanent component A j and a transitory component v t such that A j,t = A j v t , where the transitory component follows the stochastic process

(16) ln v t = ρ v ln v t 1 + σ v u v , t .

The parameter ρ v ∈ (0, 1) is the persistence parameter, σ v is the standard deviation of the innovation, and u v,t is an i.i.d. standard normal process.

The type j entrepreneurs are endowed with K j,−1 units of initial capital stock. Capital accumulation follows the law of motion

(17) K j , t = 1 δ K j , t 1 ω t + I j , t Q t ,

where I j,t denotes the investment of type j entrepreneurs. The net worth shock ω t follows the stochastic process

(18) ln ω t = ρ ω ln ω t 1 + σ ω u ω , t .

The parameter ρ ω ∈ (0, 1) is the persistence parameter, σ ω is the standard deviation of the innovation, and u ω,t is an i.i.d. standard normal process.

The type j entrepreneurs face the flow of funds constraint

(19) C j t + I j , t + B j , t 1 = P j , t Y j , t W t H j , t + B j , t R t ,

where B j,t−1 denotes the amount of matured debt and B j,t denotes the amount of new debt.

The entrepreneurs face the credit constraint

(20) B j , t = m j E t Q t + 1 K j , t .

Heterogeneity in financial frictions is that POEs face tighter credit constraint, i.e. m p < m s . Under heterogeneous financial frictions, the amount that POEs can borrow is less than that of SOEs with the same amount of capital. We interpret this heterogeneity due to different contract enforcement costs: if both types entrepreneurs fail to pay the debt, the creditor can recoup up a larger fraction of the capital value from SOEs. The entrepreneurs choose C jt , H j,t , I j,t , K j,t , and B j,t to maximize (14) subject to (15) through (20).

3.5 Market Clearing and Equilibrium

In a competitive equilibrium, the markets for goods, labor, and bonds all clear. The goods market clearing condition implies

Y t = C h , t + C s , t + C p , t + I t ,

where I t = I s,t + I p,t denotes aggregate investment. The labor market clearing condition implies that labor demand equals labor supply

H t = H s , t + H p , t .

The bond market clearing condition implies that

D t = B s , t + B p , t .

A competitive equilibrium consists of sequence of prices and allocations such that (i) taking the prices as given, the allocations solve the optimizing problems for the households, entrepreneurs, and firms, and (ii) all markets clear.

3.6 TFP Loss, First-best Economy, and Misallocation

We need to define TFP loss due to heterogeneous financial frictions to prepare for analysis. In our baseline model, aggregate TFP is defined as

A y , t = Y t K s , t 1 + K p , t 1 1 α H t α .

The no financial frictions heterogeneity scenario is an economy such that the debt to output ratio D t Y t is equal to that of the baseline model and m s = m p . Denote by A y , t EFF the TFP of the no financial frictions heterogeneity scenario, TFP loss due to heterogeneous financial frictions is

T F P l o s s t = A y , t EFF A y , t A y , t EFF .

We also need to define the first-best allocation to calculate the misallocation. The first-best allocation is the allocation that marginal products of inputs of all intermediate entrepreneurs would be equalized and satisfy

1 α P j , t + 1 Y j , t + 1 K j , t + 1 δ Q t + 1 Q t = R t ,

which equates the return of households’ savings to the marginal products of capital and the resale value of the un-depreciated capital. Denote by D* the savings of households at the first-best allocation, K s * K p * the capital stock ratio of SOEs and POEs at the first-best allocation. The credit resources misallocation between households and entrepreneurs Mis b,t is defined as

M i s b , t = D t D * D * .

The credit resources misallocation within entrepreneurs Mis w,t is defined as

M i s w , t = K s , t K p , t K s * K p * K s * K p * .

Finally, the leverage ratio of the economy is defined as

l e v t = D t K s , t 1 + K p , t 1 .

4 Quantitative Results

To analyze how heterogeneous financial frictions affect macroeconomic volatility, this section calibrates the parameters and then uses the calibrated model to evaluate the results. First, we calibrate our model to match China’s economy. Second, we assess the relationship between heterogeneous financial frictions and macroeconomic volatility. Third, we show the mechanism behind this relationship. Fourth, we analyze how this relationship relates to shocks. Finally, we calculate the cost of heterogeneous financial frictions in the long run.

4.1 Calibration

In the model, a period corresponds to one quarter. The calibrated parameters fall into three categories. The first category includes the parameters related to the household’s optimal decision. The subjective discount factor β is set to 0.9943 for households, implying a risk-free rate of 2.3 %. The negative utility coefficient of labor Ψ is calibrated to normalize the labor supply to 0.4 for households. We set the parameter η = 2, which implies the Fisher labor elasticity is 0.5.

The second category includes the parameters related to the firms’ or the entrepreneurs’ production decisions. The parameter ϕ is calibrated to 0.45, implying the steady-state share of SOEs’ output is 0.24. The elasticity of substitution between POEs’ and SOEs’ intermediate goods σ is calibrated to 3, in line with Chang et al. (2015). The subjective discount factor β′ is set to 0.955 for entrepreneurs, which implies the return on capital is 18.9 %. The labor income share parameter α is set to 0.5, which is estimated by Brandt, Hsieh, and Zhu (2008) based on household data. Consistent with the stylized facts, we normalize SOEs’ TFP to 1 and calibrate POEs’ TFP to 1.42. The capital depreciation rate is set to 0.035. Following Liu, Wang, and Zha (2013), we set the capital adjustment cost parameter Ω to 0.175. The heterogeneous financial frictions parameters m s and m p are set to 0.7 and 0.4, respectively, which implies the total debt-to-asset ratio is 0.49, as in the Chinese data.

The third category of calibrated parameters is those related to stochastic processes. The persistence parameters are calibrated to 0.6 and the standard deviation of the innovation parameters are calibrated to 0.01, which are calibrated following the standard real business cycle literature. These calibrated parameters of our baseline model are summarized in Table 3.

Table 3:

Calibrated parameters for the baseline model.

Parameter Description Value
A. Households
β Subjective discount factor of households 0.9943
Ψ Negative utility coefficient of labor 18
η Inverse Frisch elasticity of labor supply 2
B. Firms and Entrepreneurs
ϕ Share parameter for SOEs output in intermediate good 0.45
σ Elasticity of substitution between SOEs and POEs products 3
β Subjective discount factor of entrepreneurs 0.955
α Labor income share 0.5
A s TFP for SOEs 1
A p TFP for POEs 1.42
δ Capital depreciation rate 0.035
m s The loan-to-value ratio parameter of SOEs 0.7
m p The loan-to-value ratio parameter of POEs 0.4
Ω Capital adjustment cost 0.175
C. Shocks
ρ z , ρ ζ , ρ v , ρ ω The persistence of the innovation 0.6
σ z , σ ζ , σ v , σ ω The standard deviation of the innovation 0.01

4.2 Heterogeneous Financial Frictions and Macroeconomic Volatility

To assess the relationship between heterogeneous financial frictions and macroeconomic volatility, we first describe the comparable models of our baseline model. When SOEs and POEs are considered as a whole, total financial frictions can be measured by the leverage ratio of the economy lev t . Given lev t equals that of our baseline model, there is a one-to-one correspondence between the loan-to-value ratio parameter of SOEs m s and the loan-to-value ratio parameter of POEs m p , as shown in Figure 1. In China’s economy, SOEs receive preferential credit treatment, as we show in Section 2. Therefore, the models with the leverage ratio equal to that of our baseline model and m s > m p are the comparable models. For the comparable models, an increase in m s is associated with a decrease in m p , implying that heterogeneity in financial frictions within entrepreneurs is increasing.

Figure 1: 
The one-to-one correspondence between the Loan-to-value ratio parameter of SOEs m

s
 and the Loan-to-value ratio parameter of POEs m

p
, with the leverage ratio equals that of our baseline model. In the baseline model, we calibrate m

s
 = 0.7 and m

p
 = 0.4; In the model that all entrepreneurs with equal financial frictions (EFF), we have m

s
 = m

p
 = 0.483.
Figure 1:

The one-to-one correspondence between the Loan-to-value ratio parameter of SOEs m s and the Loan-to-value ratio parameter of POEs m p , with the leverage ratio equals that of our baseline model. In the baseline model, we calibrate m s = 0.7 and m p = 0.4; In the model that all entrepreneurs with equal financial frictions (EFF), we have m s = m p = 0.483.

The equal financial frictions (EFF) model is defined as the model in which the leverage ratio equal to that of our baseline model and m s = m p . To analyze the degree of economic fluctuations caused by a shock, we define the output volatility ratio O V R m s as follows

O V R m s = t = 1 T log Y t m s log Y s s m s 2 t = 1 T log Y t EFF log Y s s EFF 2 ,

where Y t m s and Y s s m s denote the response and the steady-state of output in the model given m s , respectively; Y t EFF and Y s s EFF denote the response and the steady-state of output in the EFF model, respectively; the parameter T denotes the total number of response periods in our experiment. An O V R m s less than 1 indicates that heterogeneity in financial frictions can reduce economic volatility.

Figure 2 visualizes the output volatility ratio of four shocks: the preference shock, the net worth shock, the investment efficiency shock, and the TFP shock. We make two observations. First, as m s increases, heterogeneity in financial frictions becomes larger, and the output volatility ratio becomes smaller. Therefore, heterogeneity in financial frictions plays a stabilizing role in the economy. Second, the effect of stabilizing the economy is related to the type of shock. For the TFP shock and net worth shock, heterogeneity in financial frictions reduces output fluctuations by no more than 2 %. However, for the preference shock, it can reduce output fluctuations by more than 20 %. In addition, Figure 2 also shows that heterogeneity in financial frictions has a nonlinear effect on output volatility. The increase in heterogeneity in financial frictions will lead to an increasing decrease in output volatility.

Figure 2: 
The output volatility ratio 


O
V


R




m


s






$OV{R}_{{m}_{s}}$



 under different shocks. This graph plots the relationship between the heterogeneity of financial frictions and the output volatility. The total number of response periods T is set to 30.
Figure 2:

The output volatility ratio O V R m s under different shocks. This graph plots the relationship between the heterogeneity of financial frictions and the output volatility. The total number of response periods T is set to 30.

4.3 The Mechanism

To illustrate the transmission mechanism, we examine the impulse response of several macroeconomic variables following a positive preference shock, displayed in Figure 3.

Figure 3: 
Impulse responses to a positive preference shock. The baseline model: solid lines; the model with equal financial frictions: dashed lines. The horizontal axes show the quarters after the impact period of the shock. The units on the vertical axes are percent deviations from the steady state levels.
Figure 3:

Impulse responses to a positive preference shock. The baseline model: solid lines; the model with equal financial frictions: dashed lines. The horizontal axes show the quarters after the impact period of the shock. The units on the vertical axes are percent deviations from the steady state levels.

In the baseline model, a positive preference shock raises SOEs’ output, POEs’ output, and the total output. The total output response is larger in the EFF model. This result is due to the procyclicality of the credit resources misallocation within entrepreneurs Mis w,t and the TFP loss TFP loss t .

In the EFF model, the marginal productivity of capital for SOEs and POEs is equal because of m s = m p . Therefore, the response of the misallocation within entrepreneurs Mis w,t is always zero in the EFF model. However, in the baseline model, a positive preference shock leads to a procyclical increase of Mis w,t and, therefore, a procyclical increase of TFP loss t .

The credit resource misallocation between households and entrepreneurs Mis b,t may also have an impact on explaining the response difference. However, as shown in Figure 3, the responses of Mis b,t in the baseline model and in the EFF model are slightly different. Meanwhile, the variation of Mis b,t is much smaller than that of Mis w,t .

4.4 How This Mechanism Related to Shocks?

As shown in Figure 2, the stabilization role of heterogeneous financial frictions has a significant difference under different shocks. In this section, we show how the stabilization role is related to the type of shocks. To achieve this goal, we first define the relative credit resources misallocation under a shock

R M R m s = t = 1 T M i s w , t m s M i s s s m s 2 t = 1 T log Y t EFF log Y s s EFF 2 .

For a given m s and output volatility, a larger R M R m s implies that the shock causes greater procyclicality of credit resource misallocation within entrepreneurs, which in turn affects the aggregate TFP to a greater extent. The variation in the value of R M R m s with the parameter m s for different shocks is shown in Figure 4. Figure 4 illustrates that the preference shock has a much greater impact on misallocation within entrepreneurs than on output, which is consistent with Figure 2 that heterogeneity in financial frictions can reduce the economic volatility caused by preference shocks to a greater extent than that caused by other shocks. Meanwhile, the ordering of the R M R m s values of different shocks given the parameter m s is opposite to the ordering of the O V R m s values of different shocks given the parameter m s in Figure 2. Thus, the extent to which heterogeneous financial frictions can mitigate economic volatility depends on the relative magnitude of the impacts of the shock on the credit resources misallocation within entrepreneurs and on the output.

Figure 4: 
The relative credit resources misallocation 


R
M


R




m


s






$RM{R}_{{m}_{s}}$



 under different shocks. This graph plots the relationship between the heterogeneity of financial frictions and the relative misallocation ratio. The total number of response periods T is set to 30.
Figure 4:

The relative credit resources misallocation R M R m s under different shocks. This graph plots the relationship between the heterogeneity of financial frictions and the relative misallocation ratio. The total number of response periods T is set to 30.

4.5 The Cost of Stabilization

Heterogeneous financial frictions can reduce economic volatility by inducing procyclicality in credit resource misallocation within entrepreneurs. However, it cannot be ignored that this stabilizing effect has a cost, i.e. heterogeneity in financial frictions leads to the existence of credit resource misallocation within entrepreneurs at the steady state, which reduces the economy’s aggregate TFP and output at the steady state. Figure 5 illustrates the decline in output and aggregate TFP due to heterogeneous financial frictions.

Figure 5: 
The decline in output and aggregate TFP due to the heterogeneity of financial frictions.
Figure 5:

The decline in output and aggregate TFP due to the heterogeneity of financial frictions.

First, Figure 5 shows that the benchmark model reduces the steady-state output by about 0.5 percent and the steady-state aggregate TFP by about 0.3 percent compared to the EFF model. Second, consistent with Figures 2 and 4, the effect of the degree of heterogeneity in financial frictions on steady-state output and steady-state aggregate TFP is also characterized by significant nonlinearities.

However, the impact of heterogeneity in financial frictions on social welfare has a trade-off: on the one hand, heterogeneity in financial frictions reduces economic volatility, allowing households to smooth consumption to a greater extent and increasing social welfare; on the other hand, heterogeneity in financial frictions leads to lower steady-state output and household consumption, thereby reducing social welfare. Thus, the impact of heterogeneity in financial frictions on social welfare depends on the economy’s sensitivity to the level and volatility of consumption.

5 Robustness Analysis and Extensions

In this section, we explore the sensitivity of the results for China’s economy. First, we explore the sensitivity of results to some key parameters. Second, we explore the sensitivity of results to three extensive models with more realistic structures.

5.1 Sensitivity to Parameters

How would the stabilization effect of heterogeneous financial frictions react to different parameters? To analyze this issue, we compare the result of our baseline model with results of models calibrated to several different parameters: (1) the share parameter for SOEs output in intermediate good, ϕ, (2) the elasticity of substitution between SOEs’ and POEs’ products, σ, (3) the labor income share, α, (4) the TFP for SOEs and POEs, A s and A p , respectively. Results are shown in Table 4.

Table 4:

Sensitivity to parameter values.

Preference Net worth Investment TFP shock
shock shock efficiency shock
Panel A. The correlation of output response and misallocation within entrepreneurs response
Baseline 0.6329 0.6295 0.8308 0.3464
ϕ = 0.35 0.6878 0.8931 0.8876 0.4132
σ = 4 0.591 0.5093 0.7928 0.2795
α = 0.6 0.6899 0.9397 0.8684 0.4438
A s = 0.8; A p = 1.6 0.6663 0.8105 0.8695 0.3891
Panel B. The output volatility ratio O V R m s
Baseline 0.9433 0.9966 0.9877 0.9960
ϕ = 0.35 0.9140 0.9953 0.9832 0.9878
σ = 4 0.9297 0.9963 0.9866 0.9929
α = 0.6 0.9498 0.9904 0.9835 0.9973
A s = 0.8; A p = 1.6 0.9223 0.9954 0.9847 0.9908
  1. This table reports the Pearson correlation coefficient between the degree of misallocation within entrepreneurs and output and the output volatility ratio O V R m s for different perturbation of the parameters. In the baseline model, we set ϕ = 0.45, σ = 3, α = 0.5, A s = 1, and A p = 1.42.

Panel A of Table 4 shows the correlation coefficient between the degree of credit resource misallocation within entrepreneurs and output. For the baseline model, the degree of credit resource misallocation within entrepreneurs shows a procyclical characteristic under different shocks. Similarly, when we adjust the parameter values that may affect the conclusion within a reasonable range, the procyclicality still exists, and the degree of procyclicality does not change much.

Panel B of Table 4 shows how the output volatility ratio O V R m s corresponds to different parameters. The output volatility ratio of the EFF model is O V R m s = 0.483 . For the benchmark model, the volatility ratio under different shocks is less than 1, indicating that heterogeneity in financial frictions can reduce economic volatility. Similarly, when we adjust the parameter values that may affect the conclusion within a reasonable range, the conclusion still holds.

5.2 Extensions

We test the robustness of three important characteristics related to credit resource allocation or enterprises’ heterogeneity in China’s economy: household heterogeneity, supply chain structure, and earning-based borrowing constraints.

5.2.1 Heterogeneous Households (TA-RBC Model)

Some studies on households’ wealth distribution have shown that a significant fraction of households have near-zero net worth. Following Galí, López-Salido, and Vallés (2007), we introduce heterogeneous households into our baseline model. The model is populated by a continuum of households. It is assumed that a fraction 1 − ι of households is patient or Ricardian (i = r), and a fraction ι of households is impatient or non-Ricardian (i = n). Households maximize their expected utility by choosing the quantity of final goods consumed, labor hours, and bond holdings. The households’ objective function is given by

E 0 t = 0 β t z t ln C i , t Ψ H i , t 1 η 1 η .

The flow of funds constraint for the Ricardian households is given by

C r , t + D t = W t H r , t + R t 1 D t 1 + D i v t .

We assume non-Ricardian households do not own any assets nor have any liabilities; they just consume their labor income, which means the flow of funds constraint for the non-Ricardian households is

C n , t = W t H n , t .

We set the parameter ι = 0.3. Table 5 shows the results of the procyclicality of credit resource misallocation within entrepreneurs and the output volatility ratio after introducing household heterogeneity. The introduction of heterogeneous households slightly reduced the correlation coefficient, thereby slightly reducing the degree of credit resource misallocation within entrepreneurs and the countercyclicality. However, the impact of introducing household heterogeneity is not significant.

Table 5:

Sensitivity to extensions.

Preference Net worth Investment TFP shock
shock shock efficiency shock
Panel A. The correlation of output response and misallocation within entrepreneurs response
Baseline 0.6329 0.6295 0.8308 0.3464
TA-RBC model 0.5985 0.1580 0.7020 0.2828
Supply chain model 0.8024 0.8079 0.9204 0.6142
EBC model 0.6298 0.6330 0.8702 0.5080
Panel B. The output volatility ratio O V R m s
Baseline 0.9433 0.9966 0.9877 0.996
TA-RBC model 0.9449 0.9977 0.9911 0.9965
Supply chain model 0.9469 0.9899 0.9816 0.9958
EBC model 0.9430 0.9966 0.9915 0.9965
  1. This table reports the Pearson correlation coefficient between the degree of credit resources misallocation within entrepreneurs and output and the output volatility ratio O V R m s for different extensions. In the baseline model, the households are representative, the entrepreneurs are incomplete substitutes without vertical structure, and the credit constraint is only correlated to the expected value of capital.

5.2.2 Supply Chain Model

In the Chinese economy, some key upstream industries are controlled by the state via SOEs, whereas downstream industries are largely liberalized. Following Li, Liu, and Wang (2015), we introduce vertical structure into our baseline model. The SOEs that produce the intermediate good are in the upstream industry, whereas POEs that produce the final good are in the downstream industry.

The intermediate good is produced by SOEs with the following technology

Y s , t = A s , t K s , t 1 1 α H s , t α .

The final good is produced by POEs with the following technology

Y p , t = A p , t K p , t 1 1 α γ H p , t α Y s , t γ ,

where the parameter γ measure the output elasticities of the intermediate good. Both SOEs and POEs maximize their utility subject to their flow of funds constraint, the law of motion of capital, and the credit constraint (the full model is in Appendix).

We set the parameter γ = 0.2. Table 5 shows the results of the procyclicality of credit resource misallocation within entrepreneurs and the output volatility ratio after the introduction of the industrial chain structure. The introduction of an industrial chain structure has increased the correlation coefficient, thereby enhancing the procyclicality of misallocation of credit resources within entrepreneurs and strengthening the conclusion of this article.

5.2.3 Earning-based Borrowing Constraint (EBC) Model

Some recent studies have shown that earning-based borrowing has an important impact on macro-finance mechanism, such as firms are less vulnerable to collateral damage from asset price decline (Lian and Ma 2021), and the TFP loss from financial frictions shrinks with the pledgeability of earnings (Li 2022). Following Lian and Ma (2021), we introduce the earning-based borrowing constraint into our baseline model. We assume the borrowing capacity of each entrepreneur is a weighted average of earning-based borrowing constraint and collateral constraint:

B j , t = ξ m j E t Q t + 1 K j , t + 1 ξ θ j A j , t K j , t ,

where the parameter ξ measure the weight of the collateral constraint, the parameter θ j measures the borrowing capacity that depend on earnings. To exclude the impact of the steady-state leverage ratio, we set ξ = 0.5 and choose θ j such that firms have the same steady-state leverage with baseline model. The detail of the setup and equilibrium system are presented in Appendix.

We then compare the equilibrium impacts of shocks in the EBC model and the baseline model. Table 5 shows the procyclicality of the credit resources misallocation within entrepreneurs and the output volatility ratio after introducing earning-based borrowing constraints. The introduction of earning-based borrowing constraints has a subtle effect on the correlation coefficient and thus has almost no impact on the conclusion of this paper.

6 Conclusions

Financial frictions are widely regarded as a “financial accelerator” that amplifies and propagates shocks to the macroeconomy, while heterogeneity in financial frictions has received little attention. This paper generalizes the standard financial friction model of Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), which is intended to help clarify the role of heterogeneity in financial frictions in business fluctuations. The model includes two types of entrepreneurs: low-productivity SOEs receive preferential credit treatment, but high-productivity POEs do not.

Based on the calibrated model, the model shows four main results. First, we find that heterogeneity in financial frictions can reduce macroeconomic volatility. Second, the mechanism by which heterogeneity in financial frictions reduces the macroeconomic volatility is that the procyclical credit resources misallocation within entrepreneurs, then a procyclical increase of productivity loss, and therefore lower output volatility. Third, the extent to which heterogeneous financial frictions can mitigate economic volatility depends on the relative magnitude of the impact of the shock on misallocation within entrepreneurs and output. Therefore, the relationship between financial frictions and economic fluctuations may be very different in crisis and non-crisis periods. Finally, we show the cost of the stabilization effect of heterogeneity in financial frictions as it reduces the economy’s TFP and output at the steady state.

We highlight two implications of these results. First, the results imply a new macroprudential policy that adjusts heterogeneity in financial frictions in a countercyclical manner. At certain times, the economy faces frequent small shocks, but these are not small enough to ignore the welfare losses caused by economic fluctuations. Due to the frequent occurrence of these shocks, it is difficult for policymakers to formulate new policies frequently. At the same time, the lag in policy effectiveness also determines that existing policies have difficulty producing timely stabilizing effects. However, heterogeneity in financial frictions demonstrates the automatic stabilizer effect, which provides us with new policy design ideas to cope with frequent small shocks.

Second, there is also an implication for stimulus policy in crisis. If the stimulus policy is expected to have a large one-time effect, it is necessary to analyze whether the policy can improve resource misallocation. If a policy can mitigate credit resource misallocation, it can amplify the effectiveness of the policy. The impetus for monetary policy: If monetary policy can simultaneously reduce intra- and inter-group credit resource misallocation, monetary policy can promote aggregate TFP growth and thus have a long-term impact on the real economy. This is consistent with some recent research, such as Baqaee, Farhi, and Sangani (2024) and Ma and Zimmermann (2023).


Corresponding author: Jian Zhou, The School of Economics, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, 111 Wuchuan Road, Shanghai, China, E-mail:

Award Identifier / Grant number: 71673175

Acknowledgments

Financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation under grant 71673175 is gratefully acknowledged.

  1. Competing interests: The authors declare none.

Appendix A: The Equilibrium Conditions and Steady State

A.1 Euler Equations

Denote by λ t the Lagrangian multiplier for the budget constraint of households. The first-order conditions for the household’s maximization problem are

1 C t = λ t

λ t + β E t λ t + 1 R t = 0

Ψ H t η + W t λ t = 0

Denote by λ j,t the Lagrangian multiplier for the flow of funds constraint, λ j , t k the Lagrangian multiplier for the capital accumulation, λ j , t b the Lagrangian multiplier for the collateral constraint.

The first-order conditions for the intermediate entrepreneurs are given by

1 C j , t = λ j , t

λ j , t k Q t = λ j , t

β E t λ j , t + 1 + λ j , t R j t λ j , t b = 0

W t = α P j , t Y j , t H j , t

β E t λ j , t + 1 1 α P j , t + 1 Y j , t + 1 K j , t + β E t λ j , t + 1 k 1 δ λ j , t k + λ j , t b m j E t Q t + 1 = 0

The first-order conditions for the wholesale goods sector is given by

Y s , t = ϕ σ P s , t σ Y t

Y p , t = 1 ϕ σ P p , t σ Y t

Finally, the first-order conditions for the capital producer is given by

1 = Q t 1 Ω 2 I t I t 1 1 2 Ω I t I t 1 1 I t I t 1 + β Ω E t Q t + 1 λ t + 1 λ t I t + 1 I t 1 I t + 1 I t 2

A.2 Stationary Equilibrium System

We are interested in studying the business cycle around the balanced growth path, which is equivalent to the steady state of our detrended stationary equilibrium system. The stationary equilibrium system is summarized by the following equations:

  1. Households.

1 C t = λ t

λ t + β E t λ t + 1 R t = 0

Ψ H t η + W t λ t = 0

  1. Entrepreneurs (j ∈ {s, p}).

C j t + I j , t + B j , t 1 = P j , t Y j , t W t H j , t + B j , t R j t

Y j , t = A j , t K j , t 1 1 α H j , t α

K j , t = 1 δ K j , t 1 + I j , t Q t

B j , t = m j E t Q t + 1 K j , t

1 C j , t = λ j , t

λ j , t k Q t = λ j , t

β E t λ j , t + 1 + λ j , t R j t λ j , t b = 0

W t = α P j , t Y j , t H j , t

β E t λ j , t + 1 1 α P j , t + 1 Y j , t + 1 K j , t + β E t λ j , t + 1 k 1 δ λ j , t k + λ j , t b m j E t Q t + 1 = 0

  1. Final goods firm and the capital producer.

Y t = ϕ Y s , t σ 1 σ + 1 ϕ Y p , t σ 1 σ σ σ 1

Y s , t = ϕ σ P s , t σ Y t

Y p , t = 1 ϕ σ P p , t σ Y t

1 = Q t 1 Ω 2 I t I t 1 1 2 Ω I t I t 1 1 I t I t 1 + β Ω E t Q t + 1 λ t + 1 λ t I t + 1 I t 1 I t + 1 I t 2

  1. Market clearing.

Y t = C t + C s , t + C p , t + I t

I t = I s , t + I p , t

H t = H s , t + H p , t

D t = B s , t + B p , t

A.3 The Steady State of the Baseline Model

The steady state of the stationary equilibrium system is summarized by the following equations:

1 C = λ ,

λ + β λ R = 0 ,

Ψ H η + W λ = 0 ,

C j + I j + B j = P j Y j W H j + B j R j ,

Y j = A j K j 1 α H j α ,

K j = 1 δ K j + I j Q ,

B j = m j Q K j ,

1 C j = λ j ,

λ j k Q = λ j ,

β λ j + λ j R j t λ j b = 0 ,

W t = α P j , t Y j , t H j , t ,

β λ j 1 α P j Y j K j + β λ j k 1 δ λ j k + λ j b m j Q = 0 ,

Y = ϕ Y s σ 1 σ + 1 ϕ Y p σ 1 σ σ σ 1 ,

Y s = ϕ σ P s , t σ Y ,

Y p = 1 ϕ σ P p σ Y ,

1 = Q ,

Y = C + C s + C p + I ,

I = I s + I p ,

H = H s + H p ,

D = B s + B p .

The steady state value of prices are:

R j = R = 1 β ,

Q = 1 .

By equation W t = α P j , t Y j , t H j , t , we have

W t H j P j Y j = α .

By β λ j + λ j R j t λ j b = 0 , we have

λ j b λ j = β + 1 R j t .

Therefore, together with λ j k Q = λ j and Q = 1,

K j P j Y j = β 1 α 1 m j Q λ j b λ j β 1 δ .

Therefore,

I j P j Y j = δ K j P j Y j ,

and

B j P j Y j = m j K j P j Y j .

Using the intermediate firms’ budget constraint, we get

C j P j Y j = 1 W t H j P j Y j + 1 R j 1 B j P j Y j I j P j Y j .

By the technology of intermediate goods firms, we can get the price ratio of intermediate goods, P s P p ,

Y s Y p = A s A p K s P s Y s K p P p Y p 1 α W t H s P s Y s W t H p P p Y p α P s Y s P p Y p ,

P s P p = A s A p K s P s Y s K p P p Y p 1 α 1 ,

and since the wholesale sector is competitive, we have

ϕ σ P s , t 1 σ + 1 ϕ σ P p 1 σ = 1 .

Therefore, we get P s and P p and the ratio P j Y j Y . Finally, we can solve for the steady-state hours by −ΨH η + = 0.

Appendix B: The Full Model of Extensions

B.1 The Two-agents Model

This section presents a variation of our baseline model by incorporating heterogeneous agents in the household sector.

As the representative households in our baseline model, the Ricardian households (the proportion is 1 − ι) have the utility function

max E 0 t = 0 β t ln C r , t Ψ H r , t 1 η 1 η .

The budget constraint for the Ricardian household is given by

C r , t + D t = W t H r , t + R t 1 D t 1 .

Similarly, the Non-Ricardian households (the proportion is ι) have the utility function

max E 0 t = 0 β t ln C n , t Ψ H n , t 1 η 1 η .

The budget constraint for the Non-Ricardian household is given by

C n , t = W t H n , t .

The intermediate entrepreneurs j ∈ {s, p} have the utility function

max E 0 t = 0 β t ln C j , t .

The flow of funds constraints, the production function, the capital accumulation, and the collateral constraint of the intermediate entrepreneurs are

C j t + I j , t + B j , t 1 = P j , t Y j , t W t H j , t + B j , t R j t ,

Y j , t = A j , t K j , t 1 1 α H j , t α ,

K j , t = 1 δ K j , t 1 + I j , t Q t ,

B j , t = m j E t Q t + 1 K j , t .

The wholesale sector has the production function

Y t = ϕ Y s , t σ 1 σ + 1 ϕ Y p , t σ 1 σ σ σ 1 .

The optimizing problem for the capital producer is given by

max E 0 t = 0 β t Q t I t 1 Ω 2 I t I t 1 1 2 I t .

Finally, the market clearing conditions are

Y t = 1 ι C r , t + ι C n , t + C s , t + C p , t + I t ,

I t = I s , t + I p , t ,

1 ι H r , t + ι H n , t = H s , t + H p , t ,

1 ι D t = B s , t + B p , t .

B.2 The Vertical Structure Model

This section presents a variation of our baseline model by incorporating a vertical structure in the intermediate entrepreneur sector.

The representative households have the utility function

max E 0 t = 0 β t ln C t Ψ H t 1 η 1 η ,

The budget constraint for the households is given by:

C t + D t = W t H t + R t 1 D t 1 .

The upstream state-owned intermediate entrepreneurs (SOEs) (j = s) have the utility function

max E 0 t = 0 β t ln C s , t .

The flow of funds constraints, the production function, the capital accumulation, and the collateral constraint of SOEs are given by

C s , t + I s , t + B s , t 1 = P s , t Y s , t W t H s , t + B s , t R s , t ,

Y s , t = A s , t K s , t 1 1 α H s , t α ,

K s , t = 1 δ K s , t 1 + I s , t Q t ,

B s , t = m s E t Q t + 1 K s , t .

Similarly, the downstream private-owned intermediate entrepreneurs (POEs) (j = p) have the utility function

max E 0 t = 0 β t ln C p , t .

The flow of funds constraints, the production function, the capital accumulation, and the collateral constraint of POEs are given by

C p , t + I p , t + B p , t 1 = Y p , t W t H p , t P s , t Y s , t + B p , t R p , t ,

Y p , t = A p , t K p , t 1 1 α γ H p , t α Y s , t γ ,

K p , t = 1 δ K p , t 1 + I p , t Q t ,

B p , t = m p E t Q t + 1 K p , t .

The final good production function is

Y t = Y p , t .

The optimizing problem for the capital producer is given by

max E 0 t = 0 β t Q t I t 1 Ω 2 I t I t 1 1 2 I t .

Finally, the market clearing conditions are

Y t = C t + C s , t + C p , t + I t .

I t = I s , t + I p , t .

H t = H s , t + H p , t .

D t = B s , t + B p , t .

B.3 Earning-based Borrowing Constraint (EBC) Model

This section presents a variation of our baseline model by incorporating the earning-based borrowing constraint in the intermediate entrepreneur sector.

The representative households have the utility function

max E 0 t = 0 β t ln C t Ψ H t 1 η 1 η .

The budget constraint for the households is given by:

C t + D t = W t H t + R t 1 D t 1 .

The intermediate entrepreneurs j ∈ {s, p} have the utility function

max E 0 t = 0 β t ln C j , t .

The flow of funds constraints, the production function, the capital accumulation, and the credit constraint of the intermediate entrepreneurs are

C j t + I j , t + B j , t 1 = P j , t Y j , t W t H j , t + B j , t R j t ,

Y j , t = A j , t K j , t 1 1 α H j , t α ,

K j , t = 1 δ K j , t 1 + I j , t Q t ,

B j , t = ξ m j E t Q t + 1 K j , t + 1 ξ θ j A j , t K j , t .

The final good sector has the production function

Y t = ϕ Y s , t σ 1 σ + 1 ϕ Y p , t σ 1 σ σ σ 1 .

The optimizing problem for the capital producer is given by

max E 0 t = 0 β t Q t I t 1 Ω 2 I t I t 1 1 2 I t .

Finally, the market clearing conditions are

Y t = C t + C s , t + C p , t + I t ,

I t = I s , t + I p , t ,

H t = H s , t + H p , t ,

D t = B s , t + B p , t .

References

Arellano, C., Y. Bai, and P. J. Kehoe. 2018. “Financial Frictions and Fluctuations in Volatility.” Journal of Political Economy 127 (5): 2049–103. https://doi.org/10.1086/701792.Suche in Google Scholar

Bai, C., D. D. Li, Z. Tao, and Y. Wang. 2000. “A Multitask Theory of State Enterprise Reform.” Journal of Comparative Economics 28 (4): 716–38. https://doi.org/10.1006/jcec.2000.1681.Suche in Google Scholar

Bai, C., J. Lu, and Z. Tao. 2006. “The Multitask Theory of State Enterprise Reform: Empirical Evidence from China.” The American Economic Review 96 (2): 353–7. https://doi.org/10.1257/000282806777212125.Suche in Google Scholar

Baqaee, D., E. Farhi, and K. Sangani. 2024. “The Supply-Side Effects of Monetary Policy.” Journal of Political Economy 132 (4): 1065–1112. https://doi.org/10.1086/727287.Suche in Google Scholar

Beck, T., and A. Demirguc-Kunt. 2006. “Small and Medium-Size Enterprises: Access to Finance as a Growth Constraint.” Journal of Banking & Finance 30 (11): 2931–43. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2006.05.009.Suche in Google Scholar

Bernanke, B. S., M. Gertler, and S. Gilchrist. 1999. The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework: Elsevier. Original Edition. Amsterdam: Elsevier.10.3386/w6455Suche in Google Scholar

Bianchi, F. 2020. “The Great Depression and the Great Recession: A View from Financial Markets.” Journal of Monetary Economics 114: 240–61. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2019.03.010.Suche in Google Scholar

Brandt, L., C. Hsieh, and X. Zhu. 2008. “Growth and Structural Transformation in China.” China’s Great Economic Transformation 683–728, https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511754234.018.Suche in Google Scholar

Brandt, L., J. Van Biesebroeck, and Y. Zhang. 2012. “Creative Accounting or Creative Destruction? Firm-Level Productivity Growth in Chinese Manufacturing.” Journal of Development Economics 97 (2): 339–51. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2011.02.002.Suche in Google Scholar

Buera, F. J., and Y. Shin. 2013. “Financial Frictions and the Persistence of History: A Quantitative Exploration.” Journal of Political Economy 121 (2): 221–72. https://doi.org/10.1086/670271.Suche in Google Scholar

Buera, F. J., J. P. Kaboski, and Y. Shin. 2011. “Finance and Development: A Tale of Two Sectors.” The American Economic Review 101 (5): 1964–2002. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.101.5.1964.Suche in Google Scholar

Buera, F. J., J. P. Kaboski, and Y. Shin. 2015. “Entrepreneurship and Financial Frictions: A Macro-Development Perspective.” In National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No. 21107.10.3386/w21107Suche in Google Scholar

Cai, Z. 2021. “Secular Stagnation, Financial Frictions, and Land Prices.” Journal of Monetary Economics 124: 66–90. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2021.10.001.Suche in Google Scholar

Campbell, J. Y., and J. F. Cocco. 2007. “How Do House Prices Affect Consumption? Evidence from Micro Data.” Journal of Monetary Economics 54 (3): 591–621. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.10.016.Suche in Google Scholar

Chang, C., K. Chen, D. F. Waggoner, and T. Zha. 2015. “Trends and Cycles in China’s Macroeconomy.” In National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No. 21244.10.3386/w21244Suche in Google Scholar

Chang, C., Z. Liu, M. M. Spiegel, and J. Zhang. 2019. “Reserve Requirements and Optimal Chinese Stabilization Policy.” Journal of Monetary Economics 103: 33–51. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2018.08.005.Suche in Google Scholar

Chen, K., and Z. Song. 2013. “Financial Frictions on Capital Allocation: A Transmission Mechanism of TFP Fluctuations.” Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (6): 683–703. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2013.06.001.Suche in Google Scholar

Chen, S., Z. Sun, S. Tang, and D. Wu. 2011. “Government Intervention and Investment Efficiency: Evidence from China.” Journal of Corporate Finance 17 (2): 259–71. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2010.08.004.Suche in Google Scholar

Christiano, L. J., R. Motto, and M. Rostagno. 2014. “Risk Shocks.” The American Economic Review 104 (1): 27–65. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.1.27.Suche in Google Scholar

DeWenter, K. L., and P. H. Malatesta. 2001. “State-Owned and Privately Owned Firms: An Empirical Analysis of Profitability, Leverage, and Labor Intensity.” The American Economic Review 91 (1): 320–34. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.91.1.320.Suche in Google Scholar

Elliott, D., A. Kroeber, and Y. Qiao. 2015. Shadow Banking in China: A Primer. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Suche in Google Scholar

Fairlie, R. W., F. M. Fossen, R. L. Johnsen, and G. Droboniku. 2022. “Were Small Businesses More Likely to Permanently Close in the Pandemic?” In National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No. 30285.10.3386/w30285Suche in Google Scholar

Galí, J., J. D. López-Salido, and J. Vallés. 2007. “Understanding the Effects of Government Spending on Consumption.” Journal of the European Economic Association 5 (1): 227–70. https://doi.org/10.1162/jeea.2007.5.1.227.Suche in Google Scholar

Gallego, F. A., and J. A. Tessada. 2012. “Sudden Stops, Financial Frictions, and Labor Market Flows: Evidence from Latin America.” Journal of Development Economics 97 (2): 257–68. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2011.04.003.Suche in Google Scholar

Gertler, M., and P. Karadi. 2011. “A Model of Unconventional Monetary Policy.” Journal of Monetary Economics 58 (1): 17–34. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2010.10.004.Suche in Google Scholar

Gertler, M., and N. Kiyotaki. 2010. “Chapter 11 – Financial Intermediation and Credit Policy in Business Cycle Analysis.” In Handbook of Monetary Economics, edited by B. M. Friedman, and M. Woodford. Elsevier. Original Edition.10.1016/B978-0-444-53238-1.00011-9Suche in Google Scholar

Herranz, N., S. Krasa, and A. P. Villamil. 2015. “Entrepreneurs, Risk Aversion, and Dynamic Firms.” Journal of Political Economy 123 (5): 1133–76. https://doi.org/10.1086/682678.Suche in Google Scholar

Hsieh, C., and P. J. Klenow. 2009. “Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (4): 1403–48. https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.2009.124.4.1403.Suche in Google Scholar

Huang, Z., L. Li, G. Ma, and L. C. Xu. 2017. “Hayek, Local Information, and Commanding Heights: Decentralizing State-Owned Enterprises in China.” The American Economic Review 107 (8): 2455–78. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20150592.Suche in Google Scholar

Hurst, E., and B. W. Pugsley. 2011. “What Do Small Businesses Do?” In National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No. 17041.10.3386/w17041Suche in Google Scholar

Jensen, H., I. Petrella, S. H. Ravn, and E. Santoro. 2020. “Leverage and Deepening Business-Cycle Skewness.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 12 (1): 245–81. https://doi.org/10.1257/mac.20170319.Suche in Google Scholar

Katagiri, M. 2014. “A Macroeconomic Approach to Corporate Capital Structure.” Journal of Monetary Economics 66: 79–94. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2014.04.003.Suche in Google Scholar

Kiyotaki, N., and J. Moore. 1997. “Credit Cycles.” Journal of Political Economy 105 (2): 211–48. https://doi.org/10.1086/262072.Suche in Google Scholar

Levinsohn, J., and A. Petrin. 2003. “Estimating Production Functions Using Inputs to Control for Unobservables.” The Review of Economic Studies 70 (2): 317–41. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-937x.00246.Suche in Google Scholar

Li, H. 2022. “Leverage and Productivity.” Journal of Development Economics 154: 102752. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2021.102752.Suche in Google Scholar

Li, X., X. Liu, and Y. Wang. 2015. A Model of China’s State Capitalism. Hong Kong: HKUST Institute for Emerging Market Studies.Suche in Google Scholar

Lian, C., and Y. Ma. 2021. “Anatomy of Corporate Borrowing Constraints.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 136 (1): 229–91. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjaa030.Suche in Google Scholar

Liu, Z., P. Wang, and T. Zha. 2013. “Land-Price Dynamics and Macroeconomic Fluctuations.” Econometrica 81 (3): 1147–84.10.3982/ECTA8994Suche in Google Scholar

Lu, Y., H. Guo, E. H. Kao, and H. Fung. 2015. “Shadow Banking and Firm Financing in China.” International Review of Economics & Finance 36: 40–53. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2014.11.006.Suche in Google Scholar

Ma, Y., and K. Zimmermann. 2023. “Monetary Policy and Innovation.” In National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series No. 31698.10.3386/w31698Suche in Google Scholar

McKenzie, D. J., and C. Woodruff. 2006. “Do Entry Costs Provide an Empirical Basis for Poverty Traps? Evidence from Mexican Microenterprises.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 55 (1): 3–42. https://doi.org/10.1086/505725.Suche in Google Scholar

Mian, A., A. Sufi, and E. Verner. 2017. “Household Debt and Business Cycles Worldwide.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 132 (4): 1755–817. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjx017.Suche in Google Scholar

Moll, B. 2014. “Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-Financing Undo Capital Misallocation?” The American Economic Review 104 (10): 3186–221. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.10.3186.Suche in Google Scholar

Olley, G. S., and A. Pakes. 1996. “The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telecommunications Equipment Industry.” Econometrica 64 (6): 1263–97.10.2307/2171831Suche in Google Scholar

Ordoñez, G. 2013. “The Asymmetric Effects of Financial Frictions.” Journal of Political Economy 121 (5): 844–95. https://doi.org/10.1086/673886.Suche in Google Scholar

Ottonello, P., and T. Winberry. 2020. “Financial Heterogeneity and the Investment Channel of Monetary Policy.” Econometrica 88 (6): 2473–502. https://doi.org/10.3982/ecta15949.Suche in Google Scholar

Pawasutipaisit, A., and R. M. Townsend. 2011. “Wealth Accumulation and Factors Accounting for Success.” Journal of Econometrics 161 (1): 56–81. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2010.09.007.Suche in Google Scholar

Song, Z., K. Storesletten, and F. Zilibotti. 2011. “Growing like China.” The American Economic Review 101 (1): 196–233. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.101.1.196.Suche in Google Scholar

Verner, E., and G. Gyöngyösi. 2020. “Household Debt Revaluation and the Real Economy: Evidence from a Foreign Currency Debt Crisis.” The American Economic Review 110 (9): 2667–702. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20181585.Suche in Google Scholar

Zhang, W., G. Han, B. Ng, and S. Chan. 2015. “Corporate Leverage in China: Why has it Increased Fast in Recent Years and Where do the Risks Lie?” In Hong Kong Institute for Monetary and Financial Research (HKIMR) Research Paper WP No. 10/2015.10.2139/ssrn.2597451Suche in Google Scholar

Received: 2023-05-07
Accepted: 2023-12-09
Published Online: 2023-12-25

© 2023 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Heruntergeladen am 6.9.2025 von https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejm-2023-0188/html
Button zum nach oben scrollen