Home Current Account Balances’ Divergence in the Euro Area: An Appraisal of the Underlying Forces
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

Current Account Balances’ Divergence in the Euro Area: An Appraisal of the Underlying Forces

  • Emmanuelle Faure , Carl Grekou and Valérie Mignon EMAIL logo
Published/Copyright: October 30, 2023

Abstract

This paper revisits the crucial issue of current account imbalances and focuses on the determinants of their gaps between eurozone Member States. We conduct robust estimations of the current account balances for a panel of ten founding euro area economies and construct a measure that allows us to diagnose why some countries have started to diverge from the eurozone mean in the last two decades. Our findings show evidence of remaining differences in countries’ economic development, meaning that real macroeconomic convergence has failed in the zone. Price and cost competitiveness, as well as fiscal balances, have also participated in this growing macroeconomic divergence. Overall, while the European authorities cannot influence the part of the current account gaps due to demographic factors, the role of fiscal redistribution and investment at the euro area level could help achieve macroeconomic convergence and thus reduce current accounts’ divergence in the zone.

JEL Classification: F32; O52; C33

Corresponding author: Valérie Mignon, EconomiX-CNRS, University of Paris Nanterre, 200 Avenue de la République, 92001 Nanterre Cedex, France; and CEPII, Paris, France, E-mail:

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank the editor and two anonymous referees, as well as Thomas Chuffart, Thomas Grjebine, Francisco Serranito, and all the participants at the CEPII and EconomiX-CNRS seminars for their helpful comments and suggestions.

Appendix A: Data

Table A.1:

Data information.

Variables Name Relative to trade partners Construction Data source
Aging growth rate Aging Difference between the old dependency ratio in t + 20 and the old dependency ratio in t UNCTADstat
Capital control (lagged) l.KAOPEN Chinn & Ito
Currency misalignments Mis Real effective exchange rate misalignments EQCHANGE (CEPII)
Current account CA Current account balance expressed in percentage of GDP WEO (IMF)
Expected GDP growth rate Expected_GDPg GDP growth rate in t + 3 WEO (IMF)
Foreign direct investment (lagged) l.FDI Growth of foreign direct investment (net inflows) expressed in percentage of GDP WDI (World Bank)
Government balance (lagged) l.Gov_Bal Cyclically adjusted government balance expressed as a percentage of GDP WEO (IMF)
Market performance of exports on exports weighted imports d.MPerf_Exp AMECO
Net foreign asset position (lagged) l.NFA Net foreign asset position expressed in percentage of GDP Lane & Milesi-Ferretti
Old dependency ratio OADepRatio Ratio of the population exceeded 64 years old and the population between 15 and 64 UNCTADstat
Output Gap Output_gap Output gap expressed as a percentage of GDP (GDP per capita in PPP, HP filtered) WEO (IMF)
Population growth rate popg Population growth rate UNCTADstat
Private sector debt (lagged) l.d.PrvD Growth of the private sector debt expressed in GDP WDI (World Bank)
Relative income per capita in PPP (lagged) l.GDP_PC Log of the GDP per capita in PPP WEO (IMF)
Tariff rate, applied, simple mean, all products Tariffs WDI (World Bank)
Terms of trade (lagged) l.tot Lagged ratio of export price to import price UNCTADstat
Total factor productivity (lagged) l.CTFP Total factor productivity at current PPPs Penn World Table
Trade openness (lagged) l.d.Trade Sum of imports and exports divided by GDP WDI (World Bank)
Unit labor cost (lagged) l.d.ULC Nominal unit labor cost in log difference AMECO
VIX d.VIX Chicago VIX index CBOE
  1. Time-varying weights have been used to compute variables in effective terms against 186 trading partners (source: EQCHANGE, CEPII).

Table B.1:

Detailed average contributions: deviations from the eurozone average CA (2000–2018).

Austria Belgium Finland France Germany Greece Italy Netherlands Portugal Spain
Competitiveness −0.93 (0.41) −0.41 (0.48) 0.31 (0.48) 0.44 (0.25) 0.76 (0.50) −3.08 (0.56) −1.02 (0.50) 0.84 (0.36) −2.15 (0.39) −0.48 (0.38)
CTFP −0.66 (0.16) −0.21 (0.14) −0.01 (0.22) 0.52 (0.17) 0.34 (0.34) −2.33 (0.56) −0.79 (0.32) 0.93 (0.28) −1.91 (0.20) −0.20 (0.15)
Mis −0.26 (0.30) −0.16 (0.29) 0.31 (0.27) −0.04 (0.07) 0.35 (0.29) −0.80 (0.36) −0.18 (0.20) −0.03 (0.24) −0.21 (0.14) −0.27 (0.30)
ULC −0.01 (0.16) −0.05 (0.22) 0.02 (0.28) −0.03 (0.11) 0.08 (0.25) 0.05 (0.53) −0.05 (0.16) −0.06 (0.19) −0.03 (0.29) −0.01 (0.34)
Conjuncture 0.04 (0.46) −0.01 (0.45) −0.03 (0.73) −0.03 (0.31) 0.04 (0.64) 0.07 (2.47) −0.01 (0.43) 0.04 (0.57) 0.12 (0.55) −0.10 (1.00)
Demographics −1.79 (0.17) −2.10 (0.28) 0.58 (1.79) −0.53 (0.78) 0.16 (0.45) 1.61 (0.61) 0.57 (0.82) 1.17 (0.47) 1.82 (0.39) −0.48 (2.24)
Aging −0.89 (0.28) −1.61 (0.19) 0.79 (1.73) −0.25 (0.90) −0.32 (0.40) 0.33 (0.25) 0.49 (0.58) 1.24 (0.54) 0.83 (0.53) 0.29 (0.89)
Pop growth −0.90 (0.30) −0.49 (0.44) −0.21 (0.31) −0.28 (0.20) 0.48 (0.71) 1.28 (0.76) 0.09 (0.33) −0.08 (0.20) 0.99 (0.42) −0.77 (1.53)
Development 0.22 (0.30) −1.25 (0.64) 0.06 (0.79) −0.82 (0.23) 1.23 (0.53) −3.20 (1.03) 0.03 (0.88) 2.45 (0.40) −5.52 (0.69) −1.33 (0.54)
Financial conditions 0.40 (0.29) 0.80 (0.67) −0.03 (0.31) −0.06 (0.23) 0.07 (0.17) −0.32 (0.91) −0.43 (0.20) 0.64 (0.42) 0.37 (0.24) −0.18 (0.28)
FDI −0.04 (0.17) 0.30 (0.42) −0.01 (0.11) −0.06 (0.03) −0.05 (0.05) −0.10 (0.04) −0.09 (0.03) 0.56 (0.37) 0.00 (0.09) −0.03 (0.05)
KAOPEN 0.47 (0.17) 0.59 (0.34) 0.09 (0.18) 0.09 (0.04) −0.02 (0.09) 0.05 (0.75) −0.30 (0.07) 0.07 (0.12) 0.41 (0.04) −0.12 (0.11)
Private debt −0.03 (0.14) −0.09 (0.33) −0.11 (0.21) −0.09 (0.22) 0.14 (0.17) −0.27 (0.38) −0.04 (0.16) 0.01 (0.21) −0.04 (0.25) −0.03 (0.35)
Fiscal balance 0.10 (0.32) 0.32 (0.40) 0.81 (0.84) −0.28 (0.21) 0.33 (0.53) −1.27 (0.94) −0.14 (0.29) 0.18 (0.34) −0.65 (0.42) −0.16 (1.09)
Welfare state 0.09 (0.36) 0.11 (0.30) −0.03 (0.45) 0.00 (0.26) 0.07 (0.26) −0.18 (0.76) −0.08 (0.21) 0.16 (0.38) −0.24 (0.60) −0.13 (0.59)
Trade policy 0.70 (0.36) 0.38 (0.34) −0.66 (0.64) 0.11 (0.26) 0.27 (0.33) −0.68 (0.73) −0.36 (0.28) 0.07 (0.26) 0.15 (0.49) −0.51 (0.38)
Market perf. 0.01 (0.23) 0.00 (0.37) −0.04 (0.48) 0.01 (0.26) −0.01 (0.21) −0.07 (0.68) 0.03 (0.28) −0.01 (0.33) 0.03 (0.40) −0.02 (0.38)
Tariffs 0.78 (0.18) 0.42 (0.18) −0.49 (0.48) 0.17 (0.11) 0.16 (0.07) −0.68 (0.24) −0.35 (0.12) 0.06 (0.15) 0.15 (0.26) −0.42 (0.14)
Trade −0.09 (0.26) −0.03 (0.28) −0.13 (0.42) −0.07 (0.19) 0.12 (0.18) 0.07 (0.64) −0.05 (0.22) 0.03 (0.29) −0.02 (0.30) −0.06 (0.30)
Others 0.24 (0.20) 1.42 (0.19) 0.41 (0.75) −0.30 (0.28) 0.09 (0.24) −0.60 (0.33) 0.06 (0.13) 0.37 (0.43) −0.47 (0.25) −0.46 (0.51)
NFA −0.01 (0.13) 0.87 (0.18) −0.22 (0.79) −0.02 (0.17) 0.45 (0.23) −1.04 (0.35) −0.21 (0.13) 0.37 (0.49) −1.23 (0.45) −0.91 (0.39)
TOT 0.25 (0.14) 0.55 (0.26) 0.63 (0.17) −0.28 (0.11) −0.35 (0.09) 0.44 (0.55) 0.27 (0.22) 0.00 (0.22) 0.76 (0.27) 0.46 (0.17)
Unexplained 1.76 (1.32) 0.45 (1.10) −0.82 (2.36) 0.29 (0.74) 0.78 (1.98) −0.38 (1.84) −0.33 (1.67) −0.25 (2.22) −0.68 (3.83) −0.56 (2.02)
  1. Entries correspond to the averages of the contributions over the 2000–2018 period. Standard deviations are reported in parentheses. The average euro area CA is computed —on a yearly basis— as the GDP-weighted average of the considered economies’ CA.

Table C.1:

Posterior inclusion probabilities.

Variable Posterior inclusion probability
Model prior
Uniform Fixed Random
Prior 1 Prior 9 Prior 1 Prior 9
Capital_stock 0.1390 0.0064 0.0492 0.0880 0.1194
dChina 0.0294 0.0010 0.0116 0.0084 0.0297
Demographics 0.9594a 0.3927 0.9685a 0.9227a 0.9628a
dlREER 0.0644 0.0018 0.0195 0.0152 0.0581
dMarket_share 0.0370 0.0018 0.0170 0.0176 0.0350
Expected_GDPg 0.7582a 0.3099 0.6341a 0.5808a 0.7458a
Goods_Exp_pgdp 0.2612 0.1694 0.3203 0.3032a 0.2706
Human_Cap 0.2371 0.0308 0.1032 0.1404 0.2058
Insti 0.0579 0.0495 0.0308 0.0296 0.0577
KAOPEN 0.8855a 0.2489 0.8505a 0.8400a 0.8517a
lCTFP 0.9974a 0.2369 0.9933a 0.9874a 0.9972a
ldFDI 0.0446 0.0026 0.0192 0.0131 0.0451
ldPrivDebt 0.9914a 0.9983a 0.9873a 0.9891a 0.9894a
ldULC 0.0786 0.1191a 0.0504 0.0459 0.0743
lGDP_PC 1.0000a 1.0000a 1.0000a 1.0000a 1.0000a
lGDPg 0.0599 0.0064 0.0423 0.0290 0.0612
lGov_Bal 0.9442a 0.9310a 0.9625a 0.9170a 0.9528a
lInflation 0.4564a 0.0088 0.2634 0.2160a 0.4753a
lNFA 0.9494a 0.1526 0.8888a 0.8595a 0.9136a
Manuf 0.0846 0.0336 0.0255 0.0235 0.0828
Mis 0.8175a 0.4070a 0.7595a 0.7360a 0.7664a
MPerf_Exp 0.6946a 0.0340 0.5226a 0.4344a 0.7040a
NIIP 0.1574 0.0137 0.0617 0.0630 0.1514
Output_gap 0.9995a 0.8627a 0.9991a 0.9995a 0.9996a
Quinn 0.0391 0.0076 0.0200 0.0133 0.0369
Remit 0.1493 0.0199 0.1549 0.1581 0.1370
RTFP 0.0566 0.0034 0.0176 0.0210a 0.0571
Tariffs 1.0000a 0.5730a 0.9987a 0.9964a 1.0000a
TOT 0.9797a 0.1405 0.9052a 0.8739a 0.9773a
Trade 0.7766a 0.0472 0.6308a 0.5971a 0.8027a
Welfare_State 0.9981a 0.8951a 0.9899a 0.9850a 0.9953a
Working_Pop 0.0532 0.0010 0.0199 0.0146 0.0513
  1. The dependent variable is the current account (% of GDP). The results are based on 100,000 burns-ins and 200,000 draws. Simulations made using birth-death MCMC sampler. PIPs higher than 0.5 are displayed in bold. “a” over the PIPs indicates that the variable belongs at least to one of the best three models. “d” (resp. “l”) stands for the difference (resp. lag) operator. The variable transformations obey the stationarity and exogeneity exigencies.

Appendix B: Additional Results

Figure B.1: 
Current accounts: actual and fitted values. The eurozone current account balance is computed as the GDP-weighted average of the countries’ current account balances.
Figure B.1:

Current accounts: actual and fitted values. The eurozone current account balance is computed as the GDP-weighted average of the countries’ current account balances.

Figure B.2: 
Variables’ evolutions (1997–2018).
Figure B.2:

Variables’ evolutions (1997–2018).

Figure B.2: 
(continued)
Figure B.2:

(continued)

Figure B.3: 
Demographic developments.
Figure B.3:

Demographic developments.

Figure B.4: 
Current accounts: actual values and model-based historical decompositions. The bars indicate the contributions of the different factors (in percent of domestic GDP) to the deviations from the eurozone average CA balances. For a given year, the different contributions sum to the CA balance gap relative to the eurozone average (indicated by the solid black line).
Figure B.4:

Current accounts: actual values and model-based historical decompositions. The bars indicate the contributions of the different factors (in percent of domestic GDP) to the deviations from the eurozone average CA balances. For a given year, the different contributions sum to the CA balance gap relative to the eurozone average (indicated by the solid black line).

Figure B.4: 
(continued)
Figure B.4:

(continued)

Figure C.1: 
Model inclusion based on the best 2000 models. The colors reflect the variables’ post mean signs, blue for positive and red for negative.
Figure C.1:

Model inclusion based on the best 2000 models. The colors reflect the variables’ post mean signs, blue for positive and red for negative.

Figure C.2: 
PIPs’ sensitivity to priors’ choice.
Figure C.2:

PIPs’ sensitivity to priors’ choice.

Figure C.3: 
Posterior model probabilities.
Figure C.3:

Posterior model probabilities.

Appendix C: Selecting CA Determinants using BMA: Data and Results

This Appendix is devoted to presenting the results obtained from the Bayesian analysis used to select the CA determinants considered in the paper. We begin with a discussion on the data, and present the results.

C.1 The Data

Taking advantage of the vast literature presented in Sections 1 and 2, we consider a set of 32 potential determinants. Accordingly, the set of fundamental variables is relatively trivial.

Regarding the macroeconomic fundamentals, we retain (i) the net foreign asset position (NFA), (ii) the GDP growth (GDPg), (iii) the expected GDP growth (Expected_GDPg), and (iv) the GDP per capita —in PPP terms— relative to trading partners (GDP_PC) —proxying for the Balassa-Samuelson effect.[35] In addition to this standard set of macroeconomic fundamentals, we also select the net international investment position (NIIP). Looking now at structural fundamentals, demographics come first. Rather than considering the usual three variables —i.e., the population growth, the aging rate, and the dependency ratio— we take advantage of the high correlations between the variables and compute a factor —Demographics— summarizing both the structure and the dynamics of the population.[36] To account for the importance and the multidimensionality of trade, we collect different variables: (i) trade openness (Trade), (ii) exports of goods (Goods_Exp_pgdp), (iii) manufacturing value added (Manuf), (iv) market performance of exports of goods and services on export-weighted imports of goods and services (MPerf_Exp), and (v) a measure of global market share (Market_share).

Policy variables are also considered. To account for the effect of fiscal policy, we consider the cyclically adjusted government balances (Gov_Bal). To gain insights into the nature of the spending and the effect in terms of investment-saving behaviors, we collect data on current transfers, tax revenues, and public services expenditures, and summarize those three variables into a factor, Welfare state. The latter is derived relying on factor analysis, drawing on data on current transfers, tax revenues, and public service expenditures. The only factor retained opposes, on the left side, the government tax revenues, and on the right side, the public service expenditures, and current transfers. Hence, the higher the value of the factor, the higher the level of social security/the lower the level of precautionary savings. Further note that considering both the current transfers and public service expenditures —rather than only health expenditures— allows us to cover a broader range of fiscal policies. Along the same lines, the introduction of tax revenues measures the repercussion scale of those policies on households’ disposable income. Overall, our W. state variable accounts for the level of social security or the extent of precautionary savings. To reflect the financial cycles, we consider data on the private debt and foreign direct investment growth rates (dPrivDebt and dFDI, respectively).[37] As is often the case, capital control measures —proxied here by the Quinn and the KAOPEN indices— accompany the aforementioned set of variables.

Turning now to cyclical factors, we retain (i) the output gap (Output_gap), and (ii) the terms of trade (TOT).

Finally, we consider a set of variables that might prove relevant in explaining the differences in the countries’s current account balances: (i) the currency misalignments (Mis), (ii) the institutional quality (Insti), (iii) the applied tariff rates (Tariffs), (iv) the capital stock (Capital_stock), (v) the inflation rate (Inflation), (vi) the remittances outflows (Remit), (vii) the unit labor cost (ULC), (viii) the real effective exchange rate (REER), (ix) a measure of the evolution of China in international trade (China) —to proxy the China shock, and (x) two measures of the total factor productivity (RTFP and CTFP).[38]

C.2 The Results

Table C.1 presents the results of the estimations (the posterior inclusion probabilities) based on a universe of 232 — i.e. 4,294,967,296— possible models. For comparison purposes, we also report results obtained using alternative model priors.[39]

Overall, the BMA analysis identifies 15 robust determinants with posterior inclusion probability (PIP) higher than 0.50. Among these factors, CTFP, Demographics, the GDP per capita, the government balance, the net foreign asset position, the private debt, the output gap, the tariff rates, the terms of trade (TOT), and Welfare_State display very high PIPs. The middle cohort comprises the expected GDP growth, KAOPEN, currency misalignments, market performance (MPerf_Exp), and Trade. However, in addition to these variables, we also retain the inflation rate, which not only appears with a PIP close to the threshold but also generally belongs to the best three models (see Figure C.1).

As a final remark, it is worth recalling that the above exercise does not purport to provide an extensive and up-to-date analysis of the current account determinants for the selected countries. Hence, variables displaying PIPs below our threshold —and so not retained— should not necessarily be interpreted as not having impacts on the current accounts. These low PIPs could, for instance, reflect low discriminating power owing to the low variance between the selected countries.

References

Almunia, M., P. Antràs, D. Lopez-Rodriguez, and E. Morales. 2021. “Venting Out: Exports during a Domestic Slump.” The American Economic Review 111 (11): 3611–62. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20181853.Search in Google Scholar

Arghyrou, M., and G. Chortareas. 2008. “Current Account Imbalances and Real Exchange Rates in the Euro Area.” Review of International Economics 9: 747–64. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9396.2008.00773.x.Search in Google Scholar

Barnes, S., J. Lawson, and A. Radziwill. 2010. Current Account Imbalances in the Euro Area: A Comparative Perspective. OECD Working Papers No. 826.Search in Google Scholar

Belke, A., and C. Dreger. 2011. Current Account Imbalances in the Euro Area: Catching up or Competitiveness? Discussion Paper of DIW Berlin 1106. Berlin: Deutsches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung.10.2139/ssrn.1776984Search in Google Scholar

Belke, A., and C. Dreger. 2013. “Current Account Imbalances in the Euro Area: Does Catching up Explain the Development?” Review of International Economics 21 (1): 6–17. https://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12016.Search in Google Scholar

Bernheim, B. D. 1988. “Budget Deficits and the Balance of Trade.” Tax Policy and the Economy 2: 1–31. https://doi.org/10.1086/tpe.2.20061771.Search in Google Scholar

Blanchard, O. 1985. “Debt, Deficits and Finite Horizons.” Journal of Political Economy 93 (2): 223–47. https://doi.org/10.1086/261297.Search in Google Scholar

Blanchard, O., and F. Giavazzi. 2002. “Current Account Deficits in the Euro Area: The End of the Feldstein-Horioka Puzzle?” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 33 (2): 147–86. https://doi.org/10.1353/eca.2003.0001.Search in Google Scholar

Blanchard, O., and G. M. Milesi-Ferretti. 2012. “(Why) Should Current Account Balances Be Reduced?” IMF Economic Review 60 (1): 139–50. https://doi.org/10.1057/imfer.2012.2.Search in Google Scholar

Böing, T., and G. Stadtmann. 2016. Competitiveness and Current Account Adjustments in the Euro Area. European University Viadrina Frankfurt (Oder). Discussion Paper No. 382.Search in Google Scholar

Brissimis, S., G. Hondroyyiannis, C. Papazoglou, N. Tsaveas, and M. Vasardani. 2012. “Current Account Determinants and External Sustainability in Periods of Structural Change.” Economic Change and Restructuring 45 (1): 71–95. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-011-9107-y.Search in Google Scholar

Bussière, M., M. Fratzscher, and G. J. Müller. 2005. Productivity Shocks, Budget Deficits And the Current Account. European Central Bank. Working Paper Series No. 509.10.2139/ssrn.750789Search in Google Scholar

Bussière, M., M. Fratzscher, and G. J. Müller. 2010. “Productivity Shocks, Budget Deficits and the Current Account.” Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (8): 1562–79. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2010.05.012.Search in Google Scholar

Ca’ Zorzi, M., A. Chudik, and A. Dieppe. 2012. “Thousands of Models, One Story: Current Account Imbalances in the Global Economy.” Journal of International Money and Finance 31 (6): 1319–38. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2012.02.003.Search in Google Scholar

Ca Zorzi, M., and M. Rubaszek. 2008. On the Empirical Evidence of the Intertemporal Current Account Model for the Euro Area Countries. European Central Bank Working Paper No. 895.10.2139/ssrn.1120701Search in Google Scholar

Calderón, C., A. Chong, and N. Loayza. 2002. “Determinants of Current Account Deficits in Developing Countries.” The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 2 (1): 1–33. https://doi.org/10.2202/1534-6005.1021.Search in Google Scholar

Calderón, C., A. Chong, and L. Zanforlin. 2007. “Current Account Deficits in Africa: Stylized Facts and Basic Determinants.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 56 (1): 191–221. https://doi.org/10.1086/520557.Search in Google Scholar

Chen, R., G. M. Milesi-Ferretti, and T. Tressel. 2012. “External Imbalances in the Euro Area.” Economic Policy 28 (73): 101–42. https://doi.org/10.5089/9781475524673.001.Search in Google Scholar

Cheung, Y. W., M. D. Chinn, and E. Fujii. 2010. “China’s Current Account and Exchange Rate.” In China’s Growing Role in World Trade, 231–71. University of Chicago Press.10.3386/w14673Search in Google Scholar

Cheung, C., D. Furceri, and E. Rusticelli. 2013. “Factors behind Current Account Imbalances.” Review of International Economics 21: 923–44. https://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12080.Search in Google Scholar

Chinn, M., B. Eichengreen, and H. Ito. 2014. “A Forensic Analysis of Global Imbalances.” Oxford Economic Papers 66: 465–90.10.1093/oep/gpt027Search in Google Scholar

Chinn, M. D., and H. Ito. 2007. “Current Account Balances, Financial Development and Institutions: Assaying the World ‘Saving Glut.” Journal of International Money and Finance 26 (4): 546–69. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2007.03.006.Search in Google Scholar

Chinn, M. D., and H. Ito. 2008. “A New Measure of Financial Openness.” Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis 10 (3): 309–22. https://doi.org/10.1080/13876980802231123.Search in Google Scholar

Chinn, M. D., and E. S. Prasad. 2003. “Medium-term Determinants of Current Accounts in Industrial and Developing Countries: An Empirical Exploration.” Journal of International Economics 59 (1): 47–76. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0022-1996(02)00089-2.Search in Google Scholar

Ciocyte, O. 2015. Literature Survey on the Theoretical Explanations and Empirical Determinants of Current Account Balances. Hague: CPB Background Document.Search in Google Scholar

Cooper, R. N. 2008. “Global Imbalances: Globalization, Demography, and Sustainability.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 22 (3): 93–112. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.22.3.93.Search in Google Scholar

Coulibaly, D., B. Gnimassoun, and V. Mignon. 2020. “The Tale of Two International Phenomena: Migration and Global Imbalances.” Journal of Macroeconomics 66. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2020.103241.Search in Google Scholar

Coutinho, L., A. Turrini, and S. Zeugner. 2018. Methodologies for the Assessment of Current Account Benchmarks. European Commission Discussion Paper 086. Directorate General Economic and Financial Affairs (DG ECFIN).Search in Google Scholar

Cova, P., M. Pisani, N. Batini, and A. Rebucci. 2008. “Productivity and Global Imbalances: The Role of Nontradable Total Factor Productivity in Advanced Economies.” IMF Staff Papers 55 (2): 312–25. https://doi.org/10.1057/imfsp.2008.5.Search in Google Scholar

Cubeddu, L., S. Krogstrup, G. Adler, P. Rabanal, M. C. Dao, S. A. Hannan, L. Juvenal, et al.. 2019. The External Balance Assessment Methodology: 2018 Update. IMF Working Paper No. 19/65. International Monetary Fund.10.5089/9781498300933.001Search in Google Scholar

De Gregorio, J., A. Giovannini, and H. C. Wolf. 1994. “International Evidence on Tradables and Nontradables Inflation.” European Economic Review 38 (6): 1225–44. https://doi.org/10.1016/0014-2921(94)90070-1.Search in Google Scholar

Debelle, G., and M. H. Faruqee. 1996. What Determines the Current Account? A Cross-Sectional and Panel Approach. IMF Working Paper No. 1996/058. International Monetary Fund.10.2139/ssrn.882958Search in Google Scholar

Decressin, J., and E. Stavrev. 2009. Current Accounts in a Currency Union. IMF Working Paper No. 2009/127. International Monetary Fund.10.5089/9781451872743.001Search in Google Scholar

ECB. 2012. Competitiveness And External Imbalances within the Euro Area. ECB Occasional Paper Series No. 139. European Central Bank.Search in Google Scholar

Felbermayr, G., C. Fuest, and T. Wollmershäuser. 2017. The German Current Account Surplus: Where Does it Come from, Is it Harmful And Should Germany Do Something About it? EconPol Policy Report 01/2017, Vol. 1.Search in Google Scholar

Fernàndez, C., E. Ley, and M. Steel. 2001a. “Model Uncertainty in Cross-Country Growth Regressions.” Journal of Applied Econometrics 16: 563–76. https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.623.Search in Google Scholar

Fernàndez, C., E. Ley, and M. Steel. 2001b. “Benchmark Priors for Bayesian Model Averaging.” Journal of Econometrics 100: 381–427. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0304-4076(00)00076-2.Search in Google Scholar

Geerolf, F., and T. Grjebine. 2020. Rééquilibrage de la zone euro : plus facile avec le bon diagnostic ! La Lettre du CEPII, 411. Paris, France: CEPII.Search in Google Scholar

Giavazzi, F., and L. Spaventa. 2010. Why the Current Account May Matter in a Monetary Union: Lessons from the Financial Crisis in the Euro Area. CEPR Discussion Paper No 8008.10.1017/CBO9781139044554.015Search in Google Scholar

Gnimassoun, B. 2015. “The Importance of the Exchange Rate Regime in Limiting Current Account Imbalances in Sub-saharan African Countries.” Journal of International Money and Finance 53: 36–74. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2014.12.012.Search in Google Scholar

Gnimassoun, B., and V. Mignon. 2015. “Current-Account Disequilibria.” Review of International Economics 23: 137–59. https://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12161.Search in Google Scholar

Gomes, G., H. Hache, V. Mignon, and A. Paris. 2018. “On the Current Account - Biofuels Link in Emerging and Developing Countries: Do Oil Price Fluctuations Matter?” Energy Policy 116: 60–7. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2018.01.054.Search in Google Scholar

Gros, D. 2012. Macroeconomic Imbalances in the Euro Area: Symptom or Cause of the Crisis? CEPS Policy Brief No. 266, April.Search in Google Scholar

Gruber, J. W., and S. B. Kamin. 2007. “Explaining the Global Pattern of Current Account Imbalances.” Journal of International Money and Finance 26 (4): 500–22. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2007.03.003.Search in Google Scholar

Higgins, M. 1998. “Demography, National Savings, and International Capital Flows.” International Economic Review 39: 343–69.10.2307/2527297Search in Google Scholar

Hoeting, J. A., D. Madigan, and A. E. Raftery. 1997. “Bayesian Model Averaging for Linear Regression Models.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 92: 179–91. https://doi.org/10.1080/01621459.1997.10473615.Search in Google Scholar

Hoeting, J. A., D. Madigan, A. E. Raftery, and C. T. Volinsky. 1999. “Bayesian Model Averaging: A Tutorial.” Statistical Science 14: 382–401.10.1214/ss/1009212519Search in Google Scholar

Honohan, P. 2021. “Is Ireland Really the Most Prosperous Country in Europe?” Central Bank of Ireland Economic Letter 2021 (1).Search in Google Scholar

IMF. 2019. The External Balance Assessment Methodology: 2018 Update. IMF Working Paper No. 2019/065.Search in Google Scholar

Kollmann, R., M. Ratto, W. Roeger, J. In ’t Veld, and L. Vogel. 2015. “What Drives the German Current Account? and How Does it Affect Other EU Member States?” Economic Policy 30 (81): 47–93. https://doi.org/10.1093/epolic/eiu004.Search in Google Scholar

Krugman, P. 2012. European Crisis Realities. New York Times Online.Search in Google Scholar

Lane, P. R. 2010. International Financial Integration And the External Positions of Euro Area Countries. OECD Working Paper No. 830.Search in Google Scholar

Lane, P. R., and G. M. Milesi-Ferretti. 2012. “External Adjustment and the Global Crisis.” Journal of International Economics 882: 252–65. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2011.12.013.Search in Google Scholar

Lane, P. R., and B. Pels. 2012. Current Account Imbalances in Europe. IIIS Discussion Paper No. 397. Trinity College, Dublin.Search in Google Scholar

Le Moigne, M., and X. Ragot. 2015. “France et allemagne : une histoire du désajustement européen.” Revue de l’OFCE 142 (6): 177–231. https://doi.org/10.3917/reof.142.0177.Search in Google Scholar

Lee, J., G. M. Milesi-Ferretti, and L. A. Ricci. 2008. Real Exchange Rates And Fundamentals: A Cross-Country Perspective. IMF Working Paper No. 08/13. International Monetary Fund.10.5089/9781451868753.001Search in Google Scholar

Mano, R., and M. Castillo. 2015. The Level of Productivity in Traded And Non-traded Sectors for a Large Panel of Countries. IMF Working Paper No. 15/48. International Monetary Fund.10.5089/9781484392140.001Search in Google Scholar

Mendoza, E. G., V. Quadrini, and J.-V. Rios-Rull. 2009. “Financial Integration, Financial Development, and Global Imbalances.” Journal of Political Economy 117 (3): 371–416. https://doi.org/10.1086/599706.Search in Google Scholar

Mirdala, R., and J. Ďurčová. 2017. “Current Accounts and Competitiveness Issues in the North and South of the Euro Area.” In Economic Imbalances and Institutional Changes to the Euro and the European Union (International Finance Review, Vol. 18), 243–76. Bingley: Emerald Publishing Limited.10.1108/S1569-376720170000018013Search in Google Scholar

Modigliani, F. 1966. “The Life Cycle Hypothesis of Saving, the Demand for Wealth and the Supply of Capital.” Social Research 33 (2): 160–217.Search in Google Scholar

Moral-Benito, E., and O. Roehn. 2016. “The Impact of Financial Regulation on Current Account Balances.” European Economic Review 81: 148–66. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2015.07.005.Search in Google Scholar

Morvillier, F. 2020. Equilibrium Exchange Rate and Macroeconomic Imbalances. PhD thesis. University of Paris Nanterre.Search in Google Scholar

Obstfeld, M., and K. S. Rogoff. 1996. Foundations of International Macroeconomics, Vol. 30. Cambridge: MIT press.Search in Google Scholar

Phillips, S., L. Catão, L. Ricci, R. Bems, M. Das, J. Di Giovanni, D. Filiz Unsal, et al.. 2013. The External Balance Assessment (EBA) Methodology. IMF Working Paper No. 13/272. International Monetary Fund.10.5089/9781484346686.001Search in Google Scholar

Pierluigi, B., and D. Sondermann. 2018. Macroeconomic Imbalances in the Euro Area: Where Do We Stand? ECB Occasional Paper Series No. 211. European Central Bank.10.2139/ssrn.3204312Search in Google Scholar

Reis, R., and H. Rey. 2012. “Comment to the Euro’s Three Crises by Shambaugh.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity Spring: 212–31, https://doi.org/10.1353/eca.2012.0008.Search in Google Scholar

Roodman, D. 2009. “How to Do Xtabond2: An Introduction to Difference and System GMM in Stata.” STATA Journal 9: 86–136. https://doi.org/10.1177/1536867x0900900106.Search in Google Scholar

Ruppert, K., and N. Stähler. 2022. “What Drives the German Current Account? Household Savings, Capital Investments and Public Policies.” Economic Modelling 108: 105769. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2022.105769.Search in Google Scholar

Shambaugh, J. C. 2012. “The Euro’s Three Crises by Shambaugh.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity Spring: 157–211, https://doi.org/10.1353/eca.2012.0006.Search in Google Scholar

Swanson, D., and R. Verdugo. 2011. “Immigration and its Effects on Demographic Change in Spain.” The Open Demography Journal 4: 22–33. https://doi.org/10.2174/1874918601104010022.Search in Google Scholar

Tressel, T., and S. Wang. 2014. “Rebalancing in the Euro Area and Cyclicality of Current Account Adjustments.” IMF Working Papers 2014/130.10.5089/9781498334426.001Search in Google Scholar

Wagner, M. 2005. The Balassa-Samuelson Effect in ‘East & West’. Differences and Similarities. Economics Series No. 180. Institute for Advanced Studies.Search in Google Scholar

Wollmershäuser, T., and G. Schnabl. 2013. Fiscal Divergence and Current Account Imbalances in Europe. CESifo Working Paper, Vol. 4108.Search in Google Scholar

Wyplosz, C. 2013. “The Eurozone Crisis and the Competitiveness Legend.” Asian Economic Papers 12 (3): 63–81. https://doi.org/10.1162/asep_a_00238.Search in Google Scholar

Zorell, N. 2017. Large Net Foreign Liabilities of Euro Area Countries. ECB Occasional Paper Series No 198. European Central Bank.10.2139/ssrn.3053801Search in Google Scholar

Received: 2023-02-22
Accepted: 2023-10-11
Published Online: 2023-10-30

© 2023 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 7.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejm-2023-0158/html
Scroll to top button