Abstract
It is well known that the protectionist view for tariff protection can be justified if the tariff induced international technology licensing benefits the consumers. We show that this view may not hold true if the domestic firm lobbies for tariff protection. If lobbying determines tariff following the “tariff-function formation” approach, lobbying reduces consumer surplus by reducing the incentive for licensing. However, if lobbying determines tariff following the “political contribution” approach, lobbying increases the incentive for licensing but creates an ambiguous effect on consumer surplus. Hence, whether the protectionist view for tariff protection can be justified under international technology licensing depends on the way the tariff rates are determined.
1 Introduction
The text book view suggests that tariff protection makes the domestic consumers worse off by distorting the firms’ choice of outputs. However, in an interesting paper, Kabiraj and Marjit (2003) argued that tariff protection may benefit the domestic consumers by attracting superior foreign technologies through international technology licensing.[1] Hence, they suggest that the protectionist view for tariff protection can be justified if the tariff induced international technology licensing benefits the consumers.[2] We show that this conclusion may not hold true if the tariff rate is influenced by lobbying by the domestic firm. Hence, whether the protectionist view for tariff protection can be justified under international technology licensing depends on the way the tariff rates are determined.
While the literature on international technology licensing under endogenous tariff protection provides important insights, it is restrictive due to its attention on welfare-maximising governments.[3] It is widely recognised that trade policies are often influenced by many special interest groups (Bhagwati 2000; Cai and Li 2014; Findlay and Wellisz 1982; Gawande, Krishna, and Olarreaga 2012; Grossman and Helpman 1994; Hillman 1989; Kayalica and Lahiri 2007; Long and Soubeyran 1996; Magee, Brock, and Young 1989; Mayer 1984; Mitra 1999; Weymouth 2012, to name a few) and domestic firms often lobby for tariff protection. Given this background, we examine how lobbying for tariff protection by the domestic firm affects international technology licensing and the corresponding consumer surplus.
To show the implications of lobbying by the domestic firm for tariff protection, we consider the non-committed tariff game of Kabiraj and Marjit (2003), where they consider the following situation.[4] There is a technologically superior[5] foreign firm and a technologically inferior domestic firm competing in the domestic country. At stage 1, the foreign firms decides whether to license its technology to the domestic firm against a fixed-fee.[6] At stage 2, the domestic government imposes a per-unit tariff on the foreign firm’s output to maximise welfare of the domestic country. At stage 3, they compete in the product market like Cournot duopolists.
The motivation for considering the non-committed tariff game comes from the time inconsistency problem. As Staiger and Tabellini (1987) mentioned, governments with some degree of discretion in policy may find it difficult to commit. The time inconsistency problem is considered in many contexts, such as in trade and industrial policy (Kabiraj and Marjit 2003; Mukherjee and Pennings 2006; Neary and Leahy 2000), investment subsidies (Harstad 2020), environment policy (García, Leal, and Lee 2018; Iida and Mukherjee 2020), monetary policy (Barro and Gordon 1983; Berlemann 2005; Kydland and Prescott 1977; Minford 1995), euro crisis (Willett and Srisorn 2014), utility regulation (Lim and Yurukoglu 2018), bank closure (Acharya and Yorulmazer 2007) and consumer’s preference (Sayman and Öncüler 2009). In our context, even if the domestic firm can lobby before the licensing contract, its opportunistic behaviour ex-post licensing to gain a higher market share may create the motivation for the non-committed policy. As the welfare maximising government in Kabiraj and Marjit (2003) has the incentive for changing the tariff rate ex-post licensing, the domestic firm in our analysis can change the lobbying effort ex-post licensing to raise the tariff rate for extracting a higher market share from the foreign firm.
Although we consider the non-committed tariff game like Kabiraj and Marjit (2003), we differ from them in the way the tariff rate is determined. Unlike their paper, which considers welfare-maximising tariff rate, we consider that the tariff rate is influenced by lobbying by the domestic firm.[7] Lobbying by the domestic firm only can be justified by Kayalica and Lahiri (2007) and Bandyopadhyay, Lahiri, and Wall (2012), which suggest that in many countries, it is legal for political parties to accept political contributions from the nationals of that country, but it is illegal to accept foreign contributions, and it is illegal in some countries to bribe abroad.
We consider two separate political economy models of lobbying – first, the “tariff-function formation” approach of Findlay and Wellisz (1982) and Long and Soubeyran (1996), and second, the widely used “political contribution” approach of Grossman and Helpman (1994). The first approach does not give consideration to welfare. Hence, it considers tariff formation in a way that is significantly different from the welfare-maximising tariff protection considered by Kabiraj and Marjit (2003). Thus, this model helps us to show the importance of the process of tariff formation in the simplest way. The second approach cares both welfare and political contribution, thus showing the implications of lobbying when the government also cares about domestic welfare.
We derive the following results. Whether we consider the “tariff-function formation” approach or the “political contribution” approach, the tariff rate is higher under licensing compared to no licensing. However, these models have different effects on the incentive for licensing and consumer surplus. The incentive for licensing is lower under lobbying compared to no lobbying under the “tariff-function formation” approach, while it is higher under the “political contribution” approach. While lobbying (compared to no lobbying) reduces consumer surplus under the “tariff-function formation” approach, the effect is ambiguous under the “political economy” approach. Hence, lobbying and the way it affects tariff protection may play an important role in determining the incentive for licensing and the corresponding consumer surplus.
Our results are strikingly different from Kabiraj and Marjit (2003). They show that welfare-maximising tariff protection benefits the consumers in the importing country by inducing technology licensing, thus suggesting that if free trade cannot attract foreign technologies, restrictive trade policies help to attract foreign technologies and benefits the consumers. In contrast, we show that tariff protection through lobbying may reduce the incentive for technology licensing and consumer surplus. Even if tariff protection through lobbying increases technology licensing, it may still reduce consumer surplus. Hence, if technology licensing does not occur under free trade, it is not necessary that tariff protection will induce international technology licensing and will improve consumer surplus. Therefore, one needs to be more cautious about the way tariff is determined when considering the effect of tariff induced international technology licensing.
When tariff protection induces technology licensing in our paper, the mechanism is different from Kabiraj and Marjit (2003). Technology licensing in their analysis reduces the tariff rate and therefore, benefits the foreign licenser by reducing its tariff inclusive cost. In contrast, tariff protection in our paper increases the incentive for licensing when it is higher under licensing. Higher tariff protection under licensing helps to increase the competitiveness and the profit of the domestic firm and the foreign firm can use the licensing fee to extract this benefit from the domestic firm.
To the best of our knowledge, there is no empirical research analysing how lobbying for tariff protection affects product-market competition and international technology licensing. Our results provide testable hypothesis for future empirical research on international technology licensing in the presence of lobbying for tariff protection.
The remainder of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 describes the model and considers licensing under free trade. Section 3 considers licensing under the tariff-formation function approach of lobbying. Section 4 considers licensing under the political contribution approach of lobbying. Section 5 concludes.
2 The Model and the Results
Assume that there are two firms, a foreign firm (firm F) and a domestic firm (firm D). The foreign firm exports to the domestic country from the foreign country and the firms compete in the domestic country like Cournot duopolists with homogeneous goods. Assume that the constant marginal costs of productions for the domestic and foreign firms are c
d
and
Assume that the inverse market demand function is
where P is price and q is the total output. We assume that
2.1 Licensing under Free Trade
Under free trade, implying that there is neither any lobbying nor any welfare-maximizing tariff policy, we consider the following game. At stage 1, the foreign firm decides whether to license the technology. If it decides to license the technology, like Kabiraj and Marjit (2003), it charges an up-front non-negative[8] fixed fee for the technology. At stage 2, the domestic firm decides whether to accept the licensing contract. The domestic firm accepts the licensing contract if it is not worse off compared to the situation with no licensing. At stage 3, the firms compete like Cournot duopolists and the profits are realised. We solve the game through backward induction.
If there is no licensing, firms D and F respectively maximise the following expressions to maximise their outputs:
where q = q
d
+ q
f
. We get the equilibrium outputs of firms D and F under no licensing as
If there is licensing, we get the equilibrium values by considering c = 0 in the above-mentioned expressions. The equilibrium outputs and profits of firms D and F are respectively
Licensing is profitable if it does not make any of these firms worse off but makes at least one of them better off compared to no licensing. Hence, licensing is profitable if
We get that licensing is profitable if Ω
l
= π
d,ft,l
+ π
f,ft,l
> π
d,ft,n
+ π
f,ft,n
= Ω
n
or
The above discussion gives the following result immediately.
Proposition 1
If there is no lobbying, technology licensing with a non-negative fixed-fee is profitable, meaning none of these firms is worse off and at least one of them is better off under licensing compared to no licensing, if
On the one hand, licensing increases production efficiency in the industry, but on the other hand, it increases product-market competition by making the licensee more competitive. If the cost difference between the firms is very high, it creates a near monopoly of the licenser under no licensing, and makes licensing unprofitable by reducing the industry profit. However, if the initial technologies of the firms are very similar, licensing increases production efficiency in the industry sufficiently to make it profitable.
3 Licensing under Lobbying: Tariff-Formation Function Approach
Now consider lobbying by the domestic firm for tariff protection. In this section, we consider the tariff-formation function approach, as in Findlay and Wellisz (1982) and Long and Soubeyran (1996), where a tariff level is determined as a stable function of the resources committed to the political process by the interest group. This approach follows Findlay and Wellisz (1982) and Long and Soubeyran (1996), and as mentioned above, it helps to show the implications of lobbying by ignoring welfare-maximising tariff, thus considering tariff formation in a way that is significantly different from Kabiraj and Marjit (2003). We will consider the political contribution approach of Grossman and Helpman (1994) in Section 4.
Assume that the foreign firm faces a tariff t(e) per unit of its output where e is the domestic firm’s lobbying expenditure with t(0) = 0, t′ > 0, and t″ ≤ 0. Hence, the domestic government supports free-trade in the absence of lobbying. However, lobbying is costly and the domestic firm has to incur a cost R(e) for lobbying with R(0) = 0, R′ > 0 and R″ > 0. This formulation is similar to Long and Soubeyran (1996).
The reason for a convex lobbying cost can be attributable to the loss of resources, such as labour force, for productive activities, as in Findlay and Wellisz (1982). Labour could be used for lobbying and other productive activities. If the domestic firm increases lobbying, it needs more labour for that activity, implying that it has less labour for other productive activities. As the domestic firm uses more and more labour for lobbying, it has less and less labour for other productive activities, which reduces other activities at an increasing rate due to the diminishing marginal productivities of labour in other activities, thus increasing the cost of lobbying at an increasing rate. In other words, as the labour for lobbying increases, the opportunity cost of lobbying increases at an increasing rate.
The property of t(e) could be explained in the following way. As the domestic firm increases lobbying, it may not change the government official’s incentive for imposing further tariff, implying that the rate of change of tariff following lobbying remains constant in this situation. Alternatively, the domestic firm may find it harder to convince the government official for increasing the tariff rate when it already increased the tariff rate following lobbying; in this situation, the rate of change of tariff following lobbying reduces.
It is worth mentioning that our result will hold with different assumptions for t″ and R″, as long as the second order condition for the domestic firm’s profit maximising lobbying effort holds.
We consider the following game in this section. At stage 1, the foreign firm decides whether to license the technology. At stage 2, the domestic firm decides whether to accept the licensing contract. The domestic firm accepts the licensing contract if it is not worse off compared to the situation with no licensing. At stage 3, the domestic firm lobbies for tariff on the foreign firm’s output. At stage 4, the firms compete like Cournot duopolists and the profits are realised. We solve the above game through backward induction.
We consider a situation where the domestic firm lobbies after the technology licensing decision. It is a reasonable sequence to consider since, after the licensing decision, the domestic firm has the incentive to increase its profit by making the foreign firm less competitive by lobbying for a tariff protection.[9]
First, consider the game under no licensing. Given the tariff rate created by the lobbying expenditure, firms D and F maximise the following expressions to determine the respective outputs in stage 4:
We get the equilibrium outputs of firms D and F under no licensing as
At stage 3, the domestic firm chooses the lobbying expenditure to maximize the following expression:
The equilibrium lobbying expenditure is given by
Assume that the second order condition for maximization is satisfied, i.e.
The equilibrium profits of the domestic and foreign firms under no licensing are respectively
Next, consider the situation under licensing. If both firms produce positive outputs under licensing, the equilibrium outputs and profits under licensing can be found by setting c = 0 in the equilibrium values under no licensing. The equilibrium outputs of the domestic and foreign firms are
Proposition 2
If both firms produce positive outputs, the domestic firm’s lobbying expenditure and the tariff rate are higher under licensing compared to no licensing.
Proof
Differentiating (7) with respect to c gives
If the marginal cost of production of the domestic firm decreases, it gives the domestic firm a higher market share and, therefore, higher profit for any given lobbying expenditure, which, in turn, induces the domestic firm to increase the lobbying expenditure. Hence, licensing increases the equilibrium lobbying expenditure and the equilibrium tariff rate compared to no licensing by reducing the marginal cost of the domestic firm.
For a clear exposition with the closed form solutions, we take the lobbying function and the cost of lobbying as
Hence, B = 0 will replicate the situation under no lobbying.
We assume B > 0 and
Given the functions in (10), the equilibrium tariff rates and the lobbying expenditures under no licensing and licensing are respectively
Therefore, the costs of lobbying under no licensing and licensing are respectively
The equilibrium outputs of firms D and F under no licensing are respectively
The equilibrium outputs of firms D and F under licensing are respectively
Due to the reason mentioned in subsection 2.1, technology licensing is profitable if Ω lo,l > Ω lo,n ,[11] or
where c″ < c′,[12] implying that lobbying reduces the incentive for licensing when both firms produce positive outputs under no licensing and licensing, which gives the following result immediately.
Proposition 3
Given the demand function, cost function,
The reason for the above result is as follows. There are two opposing effects of lobbying on the incentive for licensing compared to free trade that occurs under no lobbying in this section. First, if the foreign firm faces the same tariff rate irrespective of the licensing decision, it increases the possibility of licensing by reducing the cost difference between the firms.[13] This is similar to Kabiraj and Marjit (2003). Second, higher lobbying effort and higher tariff rate under licensing compared to no licensing tends to reduce the benefit from licensing. On the balance, the second effect dominates the first effect and lobbying reduces the incentive for licensing.
3.1 The Implications of Lobbying on the Consumers
It is easy to understand that if licensing occurs either irrespective of lobbying or only without lobbying, lobbying reduces consumer surplus compared to no lobbying since lobbying reduces the industry output by imposing a tariff.
The following proposition is immediate from the above discussion.
Proposition 4
The consumers are worse off under lobbying compared to no lobbying, irrespective of the effects of lobbying on licensing.
Although lobbying reduces consumer surplus compared to no lobbying, it can be shown that lobbying may increase domestic welfare compared to no lobbying. The tariff revenue earned by the domestic government plays an important role for it. As an example, consider the case where a = A = B = 1 and licensing occurs under both no lobbying and lobbying. Considering that the foreign firm can extract the entire gain from licensing, i.e. ensuring that the domestic firm’s profit under licensing is equal to its profit under no licensing, we get the domestic welfare under no lobbying as
It can be shown also that lobbying increases welfare compared to no lobbying even if licensing occurs only under no lobbying.
4 Licensing under Lobbying: Political Contribution Approach
We considered in Section 3 a situation where tariff determination through lobbying did not care about welfare. Although it helped to show that the implications of tariff on technology licensing and consumer surplus can differ significantly when tariff is not determined to maximise welfare, a more general framework may need to focus also on welfare when lobbying by the domestic firm influences the tariff rate. To do this, we consider in this section the widely used political contribution approach of Grossman and Helpman (1994), where the government maximises the tariff rate by giving weights on both welfare and political contributions.
Following Grossman and Helpman (1994), we consider that the domestic government maximises
where W = (π d,lo + CS + T), L is the domestic firm’s political contribution, π d,lo is the domestic firm’s gross profit (i.e. profit including the political contribution), CS is domestic consumer surplus and T is the tariff revenue.[14] We assume α > 2 to ensure that both firms produce positive outputs irrespective of licensing.[15]
Following Grossman and Helpman (1994), we consider feasible and coalition-proof truthful political contribution by the domestic firm, implying that the domestic firm’s political contribution is non-negative and can’t be more than its profit, and it satisfies the following two conditions:
where (L* + αW*) is the maximum value of (L + αW) with respect to t and
As suggested in Grossman and Helpman (1994), condition (17) suggests that, given the political contribution of the domestic firm, the government policy must maximise the joint welfare of the domestic firm and the government, because, if that is not the case, the domestic firm can adjust its contribution to induce the government to choose the jointly optimal tariff and can appropriate some of the surplus generated from the switch in government policy.
Condition (18) suggests that to induce the government to change the policy by accepting the domestic firm’s contribution, in equilibrium, the domestic firm needs to give the government at least the same level of utility that the government could get if it did not accept the domestic firm’s contribution and determined the tariff to maximise αW.
Maximising (16) we get
Consider the following game in this section. At stage 1, the foreign firm decides whether to license the technology. At stage 2, the domestic firm decides whether to accept the licensing contract. The domestic firm accepts the licensing contract if it is not worse off compared to the situation with no licensing. At stage 3, the domestic firm decides on the political contribution. At stage 4, the domestic government determines the tariff on the foreign firm’s output. At stage 5, the firms compete like Cournot duopolists and the profits are realised. We solve the above game through backward induction.
First consider the case under no licensing. If there is no licensing, at stage 5, given the political contribution and the tariff rate, firms D and F maximise the following expressions to determine the respective outputs:
We get the equilibrium outputs of firms D and F under no licensing as
At stage 4, the government determines the tariff rate by maximising the following expression:
subject to
The equilibrium tariff rate is
Given the equilibrium tariff rate, the equilibrium outputs and profits are respectively
We get
The equilibrium political contribution of the domestic firm is given by
Hence, we get
The equilibrium industry profits under no licensing is
Now consider the case under licensing, which can be found by considering c = 0 in the above-mentioned values.
The equilibrium tariff rate and the domestic firm’s political contribution under licensing are respectively
We get the following result immediately from (22), (25), (27) and (28).
Proposition 5
If both firms produce positive outputs, the domestic firm’s equilibrium political contribution and the equilibrium tariff rate are higher under licensing compared to no licensing.
The intuition for Proposition 5 is similar to that of under Proposition 2.
The equilibrium outputs and profits under licensing are respectively
The equilibrium industry profits under licensing is
Now we are in a position to consider when licensing is profitable. Due to the reason mentioned in subsection 2.1, licensing will be profitable if Ω
lo,l
− Ω
lo,n
> 0. We get from (26) and (29) that
The following result is immediate from the above discussion.
Proposition 6
If both firms produce positive outputs under no licensing and licensing, technology licensing with a non-negative fixed-fee occurs for
Proposition 6 is different from Proposition 3. Like the previous section, which considered tariff-function formation approach, the domestic firm’s cost of lobbying (the political contribution in this situation) and the tariff rate increase also in this section, where we consider the political contribution model. However, lobbying in this section increases the incentive for licensing.
Like the previous section, lobbying creates two opposing effects also in this section compared to free trade.[17] First, like Kabiraj and Marjit (2003), if the foreign firm faces the same tariff rate irrespective of the licensing decision, it increases the possibility of licensing by reducing the cost difference between the firms. Second, higher lobbying effort and higher tariff rate under licensing compared to no licensing tends to reduce the benefit from licensing. We find in this section that the first effect dominates the second effect and lobbying increases the possibility of licensing compared to free trade.
There is a difference between lobbying under the tariff-function formation approach, considered in the previous section, and the political contribution model, considered in this section. Under the tariff-function formation approach, the domestic firm’s lobbying effort is entirely responsible for the tariff rate. In contrast, under the political contribution model, the domestic government determines the tariff rate, which is influenced by the domestic firm’s political contribution, which needs to ensure that the domestic welfare is not lower due to lobbying (as suggested by (18)). Hence, with α > 2, i.e.
4.1 The Implications of Lobbying on the Consumers
Now we want to see the implications of lobbying on the consumer surplus. Since consumer surplus is
It is immediate that if c < c′ and licensing occurs under all these three situations – free trade, tariff under lobbying and the welfare-maximising tariff – consumer surplus is maximum under free trade and minimum under lobbying, since there is no tariff under free trade and the tariff rate is maximum under lobbying.
Now compare the situation under “free trade and no licensing” to that of under “lobbying and licensing”, which occurs if c ∈ (c′, c
max).[18] The equilibrium outputs are
where
Since we are considering a situation where c ∈ (c′, c
max), we get from the above discussion that c‴ ∈ (c′, c
max) if
The following result is immediate from the above discussion.
Proposition 7
(a) If licensing occurs under lobbying but not under free trade, the consumers are better (worse) off under lobbying compared to free trade if either
Figure 1 shows Proposition 7(a).
![Figure 1:
q
f
t
,
n
*
−
q
l
o
,
l
*
${q}_{ft,n}^{{\ast}}-{q}_{lo,l}^{{\ast}}$
for c ∈ (c′, c
max) and α ∈ [2, 10] with a = 1](/document/doi/10.1515/bejeap-2022-0259/asset/graphic/j_bejeap-2022-0259_fig_001.jpg)
We plot in Figure 1
Proposition 7(a) contrasts both the result of Kabiraj and Marjit (2003) and Proposition 4 of the previous section. In contrast to Kabiraj and Marjit (2003), it shows that consumer surplus may reduce under tariff protection through lobbying compared to free trade when licensing occurs only under tariff protection. This happens if the government’s weight on welfare is relatively low. On the other hand, in contrast to Proposition 4, Proposition 7(a) shows that consumer surplus may be higher under lobbying and licensing compared to free trade, if either the government’s weight on welfare is sufficiently high or the cost difference between the firms is sufficiently large.
The reasons for the above-mentioned differences are as follows. First compare with Kabiraj and Marjit (2003). They showed that if the welfare-maximising tariff attracts licensing, it always increases consumer surplus compared to free trade with no licensing. This happens because the benefit from licensing dominates the distortion due to tariff. In our analysis, lobbying increases the tariff rate compared to the welfare-maximising tariff, thus increasing the distortion due to tariff. Further, the tariff rate under lobbying increases as α falls, i.e. as the government’s relative weight on the political contribution increases. On the other hand, a relatively lower c tends to increase the consumer surplus under free trade with no licensing. Hence, if both α and c are relatively low, consumer surplus under free trade with no licensing is higher compared to consumer surplus under lobbying and licensing.
Now compare Proposition 7(a) and Proposition 4. In Section 3, lobbying imposes tariff and also reduces the possibility of licensing compared to the free trade. Both these adverse effects of lobbying reduce consumer surplus under lobbying compared to free trade. In contrast, lobbying in this section imposes tariff but increases the possibility of licensing. This benefit from licensing can outweigh the adverse effect of tariff, and consumer surplus may be higher under lobbying compared to free trade.
5 Conclusions
It is argued that tariff protection can benefit the consumers since it helps to attract superior foreign technologies through international technology licensing. Hence, the protectionist view for tariff protection can be justified if the tariff induced international technology licensing benefits the consumers. We show in this paper that this conclusion may not hold true if the tariff rate is influenced by lobbying by the domestic firm.
In contrast to the existing literature, we show that lobbying for a tariff protection may decrease or increase technology licensing compared to free trade, depending on the way lobbying affects the tariff rate. The effects of lobbying on consumer surplus also depend on the lobbying process. Hence, how tariffs are determined – by welfare-maximising governments or through lobbying by the domestic firms – and how lobbying affects the tariff rates are important for international technology licensing and the corresponding effects on the consumers.
To show that the results of Kabiraj and Marjit (2003) can be influenced significantly if the tariff rate is influenced by the lobbying effort of the domestic firm, we consider a market structure similar to theirs. An extension of our paper will be to consider the effects of multiple domestic firms. However, this is not a trivial extension, as it will raise several new questions. The foreign firm needs to determine how many licenses to offer, in the manner studied by Sen and Tauman (2007) for licensing to multiple licensees. Since lobbying by multiple domestic firms can create a free rider problem for lobbying, there will be an issue of cooperative versus non-cooperative lobbying by the firms. These issues need a full-fledged analysis. We leave them for future research.
Acknowledgments
We would like to thank two anonymous referees and an editor of this journal and the participants at the workshop on “Innovations and Patent Licensing” held at the State University of New York, Stony Brook, USA, on 15-16 July, 2021, for stimulating discussions. The usual disclaimer applies. Data sharing not applicable to this article as no datasets were generated or analysed during the current study.
References
Acharya, V. V., and T. Yorulmazer. 2007. “Too Many to Fail — an Analysis of Time-Inconsistency in Bank Closure Policies.” Journal of Financial Intermediation 16: 1–31. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfi.2006.06.001.Search in Google Scholar
Al-Saadon, Y., and S. P. Das. 1996. “Host-country Policy, Transfer Pricing and Ownership Distribution in International Joint Ventures: A Theoretical Analysis.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 14: 345–64. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-7187(95)00476-9.Search in Google Scholar
Arora, A., A. Fosfuri, and A. Gambardella. 2001. Markets for Technology: The Economics of Innovation and Corporate Strategy. Cambridge: The MIT Press.10.7551/mitpress/4451.001.0001Search in Google Scholar
Arya, A., and B. Mittendorf. 2006. “Enhancing Vertical Efficiency through Horizontal Licensing.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 29: 333–42. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-006-7403-7.Search in Google Scholar
Avagyan, V., M. Esteban-Bravo, and J. M. Vidal-Sanz. 2014. “Licensing Radical Product Innovations to Speed up the Diffusion.” European Journal of Operational Research 239: 542–55. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2014.05.031.Search in Google Scholar
Bagchi, A., and A. Mukherjee. 2014. “Technology Licensing in a Differentiated Oligopoly.” International Review of Economics & Finance 29: 455–65. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2013.07.005.Search in Google Scholar
Bagchi, A., and A. Mukherjee. 2020. “Information Disclosure through Technology Licensing.” Games 11: 37. https://doi.org/10.3390/g11030037.Search in Google Scholar
Bandyopadhyay, S., S. Lahiri, and H. J. Wall. 2012. “Cross-border Lobbying in Preferential Trading Agreements: Implications for External Tariffs and Welfare.” Review of International Economics 20: 1034–45. https://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12011.Search in Google Scholar
Barro, R., and D. Gordon. 1983. “Rules, Discretion and Reputation in a Model of Monetary Policy.” Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 101–21. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(83)90051-x.Search in Google Scholar
Berlemann, M. 2005. “Time Inconsistency of Monetary Policy: Empirical Evidence from Polls.” Public Choice 125: 1–15. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-005-3324-8.Search in Google Scholar
Bhagwati, J. 2000. The Wind of the Hundred Days: How Washington Mismanaged Globalization. Cambridge: MIT Press.10.7551/mitpress/7247.001.0001Search in Google Scholar
Cai, D., and J. Li. 2014. “Protection versus Free Trade: Lobbying Competition between Domestic and Foreign Firms.” Southern Economic Journal 81: 489–505. https://doi.org/10.4284/0038-4038-2012.144.Search in Google Scholar
Chang, R.-Y., H. Hwang, and C.-H. Peng. 2013. “Technology Licensing, R&D and Welfare.” Economics Letters 118: 396–9. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2012.11.016.Search in Google Scholar
Dijkstra, B. R., A. J. Mathew, and A. Mukherjee. 2011. “Environmental Regulation: An Incentive for Foreign Direct Investment.” Review of International Economics 19: 568–78. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9396.2011.00966.x.Search in Google Scholar
Dinda, S., and A. Mukherjee. 2011. “International Outsourcing, Tax, and Patent Protection.” Journal of Public Economic Theory 13: 139–54. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9779.2010.01496.x.Search in Google Scholar
Duchêne, A., D. Sen, and K. Serfes. 2015. “Patent Licensing and Entry Deterrence: The Role of Low Royalties.” Economica 82: 1324–48. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecca.12141.Search in Google Scholar
Faulí-Oller, R., and J. Sandonís. 2002. “Welfare Reducing Licensing.” Games and Economic Behavior 41: 192–205. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0899-8256(02)00513-4.Search in Google Scholar
Faulí-Oller, R., and J. Sandonís. 2003. “To Merge or to License: Implications for Competition Policy.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 21: 655–72. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0167-7187(02)00122-4.Search in Google Scholar
Findlay, R. F., and S. Wellisz. 1982. “Endogenous Tariff, the Political Economy of Trade Restriction, and Welfare.” In Import, Competition and Response, edited by J.N. Bhagwati, 223–38. Chicago University Press.Search in Google Scholar
Gallini, N. T., and R. A. Winter. 1985. “Licensing in the Theory of Innovation.” The RAND Journal of Economics 16: 237–52. https://doi.org/10.2307/2555412.Search in Google Scholar
Gallini, N. T., and B. D. Wright. 1990. “Technology Transfer under Asymmetric Information.” The RAND Journal of Economics 21: 147–60. https://doi.org/10.2307/2555500.Search in Google Scholar
García, A., M. Leal, and S.-H. Lee. 2018. “Time-inconsistent Environmental Policies with a Consumer-Friendly Firm: Tradable Permits versus Emission Tax.” International Review of Economics & Finance 58: 523–37. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2018.06.001.Search in Google Scholar
Gawande, K., P. Krishna, and M. Olarreaga. 2012. “Lobbying Competition over Trade Policy.” International Economic Review 53: 115–32. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-2354.2011.00673.x.Search in Google Scholar
Ghosh, A., and S. Saha. 2008. “Trade Policy in the Presence of Technology Licensing.” Review of International Economics 16: 45–68. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9396.2007.00728.x.Search in Google Scholar
Ghosh, A., and S. Saha. 2015. “Price Competition, Technology Licensing and Strategic Trade Policy.” Economic Modelling 46: 91–9. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2014.09.014.Search in Google Scholar
Glass, A. J., and K. Saggi. 2002. “Licensing versus Direct Investment: Implications for Economic Growth.” Journal of International Economics 56: 131–53. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0022-1996(01)00106-4.Search in Google Scholar
Golmbek, R., M. Greaker, and M. Hoel. 2010. “Carbon Taxes and Innovation without Commitment.” The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 10: 32. https://doi.org/10.2202/1935-1682.2473.Search in Google Scholar
Grossman, G., and E. Helpman. 1994. “Protection for Sale.” The American Economic Review 84: 833–50.Search in Google Scholar
Harstad, B. 2020. “Technology and Time Inconsistency.” Journal of Political Economy 128: 2653–89, 2689, https://doi.org/10.1086/707024.Search in Google Scholar
Hillman, A. L. 1989. The Political Economy of Protection. Chur: Harwood.Search in Google Scholar
Iida, T., and A. Mukherjee. 2020. “Make and Buy in a Polluting Industry.” Journal of Public Economic Theory 22: 1852–74. https://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12440.Search in Google Scholar
Kabiraj, T., and S. Marjit. 1993. “International Technology Transfer under Potential Threat of Entry – A Cournot-Nash Framework.” Journal of Development Economics 42: 75–88. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3878(93)90073-v.Search in Google Scholar
Kabiraj, T., and S. Marjit. 2003. “Protecting Consumers through Protection: The Role of Tariff-Induced Technology Transfer.” European Economic Review 47: 113–24. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0014-2921(02)00208-8.Search in Google Scholar
Kamien, M. I., and Y. Tauman. 1986. “Fee versus Royalties and the Private Value of a Paten.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 101: 471–91. https://doi.org/10.2307/1885693.Search in Google Scholar
Kamien, M. I., S. S. Oren, and Y. Tauman. 1992. “Optimal Licensing of Cost-Reducing Innovation.” Journal of Mathematical Economics 21: 483–508. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-4068(92)90036-7.Search in Google Scholar
Katz, M., and C. Shapiro. 1985. “On the Licensing of Innovations.” The RAND Journal of Economics 16: 504–18. https://doi.org/10.2307/2555509.Search in Google Scholar
Kayalica, M. Ö., and S. Lahiri. 2007. “Domestic Lobbying and Foreign Direct Investment: The Role of Policy Instruments.” Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 16: 299–323. https://doi.org/10.1080/09638190701524316.Search in Google Scholar
Kim, Y. 2009. “Choosing between International Technology Licensing Partners: An Empirical Analysis of U.S. Biotechnology Firms.” Journal of Engineering and Technology Management 26: 57–72. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jengtecman.2009.03.003.Search in Google Scholar
Kydland, F., and E. Prescott. 1977. “Rules rather Than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans.” Journal of Political Economy 85: 473–90. https://doi.org/10.1086/260580.Search in Google Scholar
Lim, C. S. H., and A. Yurukoglu. 2018. “Dynamic Natural Monopoly Regulation: Time Inconsistency, Moral Hazard, and Political Environments.” Journal of Political Economy 126: 263–312. https://doi.org/10.1086/695474.Search in Google Scholar
Long, N. V., and A. Soubeyran. 1996. “Lobbying for Protection by Heterogeneous Firms.” European Journal of Political Economy 12: 19–32. https://doi.org/10.1016/0176-2680(95)00023-2.Search in Google Scholar
Lu, Y., S. Banerjee, and S. Poddar. 2019. “Technology Licensing and Innovation – a Correction on Two-Part Tariff Analysis.” Economics Letters 183: 108591. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2019.108591.Search in Google Scholar
Magee, S. P., W. A. Brock, and L. Young. 1989. Black Hole Tariffs and Endogenous Policy Theory: Political Economy in General Equilibrium. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Search in Google Scholar
Marjit, S. 1990. “On a Non-cooperative Theory of Technology Transfer.” Economics Letters 33: 293–8. https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-1765(90)90018-v.Search in Google Scholar
Maskus, K., and K. Saggi. 2014. “International Technology Transfer: An Analysis from the Perspective from Developing Countries.” In Fourteenth Session, Committee on Development and Intellectual Property (CDIP). Geneva: World Intellectual Property Organization.Search in Google Scholar
Mayer, W. 1984. “Endogenous Tariff Formation.” The American Economic Review 74: 970–85.Search in Google Scholar
Minford, P. 1995. “Time-inconsistency, Democracy, and Optimal Contingent Rules.” Oxford Economic Papers 47: 195–210. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.oep.a042166.Search in Google Scholar
Mitra, D. 1999. “Endogenous Lobby Formation and Endogenous Protection: A Long-Run Model of Trade Policy Determination.” The American Economic Review 89: 1116–34. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.89.5.1116.Search in Google Scholar
Mukherjee, A. 2000. “Host-country Policy: Commitment or No-Commitment: A Theoretical Analysis.” Policy Reform 4: 75–89. https://doi.org/10.1080/13841280008523414.Search in Google Scholar
Mukherjee, A. 2001. “Technology Transfer with Commitment.” Economic Theory 17: 345–69. https://doi.org/10.1007/pl00004109.Search in Google Scholar
Mukherjee, A. 2002. “Subsidy and Entry: The Role of Licensing.” Oxford Economic Papers 54: 160–71. https://doi.org/10.1093/oep/54.1.160.Search in Google Scholar
Mukherjee, A., and N. Balasubramanian. 2001. “Technology Transfer in Horizontally Differentiated Product Market.” Research in Economics 55: 257–74. https://doi.org/10.1006/reec.2001.0254.Search in Google Scholar
Mukherjee, A., and S. Mukherjee. 2013. “Technology Licensing and Innovation.” Economics Letters 120: 499–502. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2013.05.015.Search in Google Scholar
Mukherjee, A., and E. Pennings. 2006. “Tariffs, Licensing and Market Structure.” European Economic Review 50: 1699–707. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2005.08.005.Search in Google Scholar
Mukherjee, A., U. Broll, and S. Mukherjee. 2008. “Unionized Labor Market and Licensing by a Monopolist.” Journal of Economics 93: 59–79. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-007-0293-z.Search in Google Scholar
Muto, S. 1993. “On Licensing Policies in Bertrand Competition.” Games and Economic Behavior 5: 257–67. https://doi.org/10.1006/game.1993.1015.Search in Google Scholar
Neary, J. P., and D. Leahy. 2000. “Strategic Trade and Industrial Policy towards Dynamic Oligopolies.” Economic Journal 110: 484–508. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0297.00534.Search in Google Scholar
Poddar, S., and U. B. Sinha. 2004. “On Patent Licensing in Spatial Competition.” The Economic Record 80: 208–18. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-4932.2004.00173.x.Search in Google Scholar
Poyago-Theotoky, J. A. 2007. “The Organization of R&D and Environmental Policy.” Journal of Economics Behavior and Organization 62: 63–75. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2004.09.015.Search in Google Scholar
Rockett, K. 1990. “The Quality of Licensed Technology.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 8: 559–74. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-7187(90)90030-5.Search in Google Scholar
Rostoker, M. D. 1984. “A Survey of Corporate Licensing.” IDEA 24: 59–92.Search in Google Scholar
Saggi, K. 1996. “Entry into a Foreign Market: Foreign Direct Investment versus Licensing.” Review of International Economics 4: 99–104. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9396.1996.tb00087.x.Search in Google Scholar
Saggi, K. 1999. “Foreign Direct Investment, Licensing, and Incentives for Innovation.” Review of International Economics 7: 699–714. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9396.00194.Search in Google Scholar
Saha, A. 2019. “Trade Policy & Lobbying Effectiveness: Theory and Evidence for India.” European Journal of Political Economy 56: 165–92. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2018.08.004.Search in Google Scholar
Saha, A. 2020. “Join Hands or Walk Alone? Evidence on Lobbying for Trade Policy in India.” Economics & Politics 32: 28–67. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecpo.12141.Search in Google Scholar
Sayman, S., and A. Öncüler. 2009. “An Investigation of Time Inconsistency.” Management Science 55: 470–82. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1080.0942.Search in Google Scholar
Sen, D. 2005. “Fee versus Royalty Reconsidered.” Games and Economic Behavior 53: 141–7. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2004.09.005.Search in Google Scholar
Sen, N., and S. Bhattacharya. 2017. “Technology Licensing between Rival Firms in Presence of Asymmetric Information.” The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics 17: 20150097. https://doi.org/10.1515/bejte-2015-0097.Search in Google Scholar
Sen, D., and G. Stamatopoulos. 2016. “Licensing under General Demand and Cost Functions.” European Journal of Operational Research 253: 273–80. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2016.01.057.Search in Google Scholar
Sen, D., and Y. Tauman. 2007. “General Licensing Schemes for a Cost-Reducing Innovation.” Games and Economic Behavior 59: 163–86. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2006.07.005.Search in Google Scholar
Staiger, R., and G. Tabellini. 1987. “Discretionary Trade Policy and Excessive Protection.” The American Economic Review 77: 823–37.Search in Google Scholar
Stamatopoulos, G., and T. Tauman. 2009. “On the Superiority of Fixed Fee over Auction in Asymmetric Markets.” Games and Economic Behavior 67: 331–3. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2008.11.008.Search in Google Scholar
Vishwasrao, S. 2007. “Royalties versus Fees: How Do Firms Pay for Foreign Technology?” International Journal of Industrial Organization 25: 741–59. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2006.07.007.Search in Google Scholar
Wang, L. F. S., A. Mukherjee, and C. Zeng. 2020. “Does Technology Licensing Matter for Privatization?” Journal of Public Economic Theory 22: 1462–80. https://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12431.Search in Google Scholar
Weymouth, S. 2012. “Firm Lobbying and Influence in Developing Countries: A Multilevel Approach.” Business and Politics 14: 1–26. https://doi.org/10.1515/bap-2012-0030.Search in Google Scholar
Willett, T. D., and N. Srisorn. 2014. “The Political Economy of the Euro Crisis: Cognitive Biases, Faulty Mental Models, and Time Inconsistency.” Journal of Economics and Business 76: 39–54. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconbus.2013.12.001.Search in Google Scholar
Wu, C.-H. 2019. “Licensing to a Competitor and Strategic Royalty Choice in a Dynamic Duopoly.” European Journal of Operational Research 279: 840–53. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2019.06.035.Search in Google Scholar
Yang, G., and K. E. Maskus. 2001. “Intellectual Property Rights, Licensing, and Innovation in an Endogenous Product-Cycle Model.” Journal of International Economics 53: 169–87. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0022-1996(00)00062-3.Search in Google Scholar
Yang, L., and K. E. Maskus. 2009. “Intellectual Property Rights, Technology Transfer and Exports in Developing Countries.” Journal of Development Economics 90: 231–136. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2008.11.003.Search in Google Scholar
© 2023 the author(s), published by De Gruyter, Berlin/Boston
This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Research Articles
- Gender Differences and Firm Performance: Evidence from India
- The Effect of Soft Skills on Academic Outcomes
- Search and Matching in Political Corruption
- The New Form Agency Problem: Cooperation and Circular Agency
- Lobbying for Tariff Protection, International Technology Licensing and Consumer Surplus
- Active Labour Market Policies: What Works for the Long-Term Unemployed?
- Does Abolishing a Copayment Increase Doctor Visits? A Comparative Case Study
- An Experimental Analysis of Patient Dumping Under Different Payment Systems
- Does Excellence Pay Off? Evidence from the Italian Wine Market
- Letters
- Estimating the Socio-Economic Status of the U.S. Capitol Insurrectionists
- The Effect of Elevating the Supplemental Poverty Measure on Government Program Eligibility and Spending
- Data-Driven Health Innovation and Privacy Regulation
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Research Articles
- Gender Differences and Firm Performance: Evidence from India
- The Effect of Soft Skills on Academic Outcomes
- Search and Matching in Political Corruption
- The New Form Agency Problem: Cooperation and Circular Agency
- Lobbying for Tariff Protection, International Technology Licensing and Consumer Surplus
- Active Labour Market Policies: What Works for the Long-Term Unemployed?
- Does Abolishing a Copayment Increase Doctor Visits? A Comparative Case Study
- An Experimental Analysis of Patient Dumping Under Different Payment Systems
- Does Excellence Pay Off? Evidence from the Italian Wine Market
- Letters
- Estimating the Socio-Economic Status of the U.S. Capitol Insurrectionists
- The Effect of Elevating the Supplemental Poverty Measure on Government Program Eligibility and Spending
- Data-Driven Health Innovation and Privacy Regulation