Startseite Policy Uncertainty and Technology Adoption
Artikel
Lizenziert
Nicht lizenziert Erfordert eine Authentifizierung

Policy Uncertainty and Technology Adoption

  • Mohammad H. Dehghani EMAIL logo
Veröffentlicht/Copyright: 7. Juni 2014

Abstract

This paper considers technology adoption under both technological and subsidy uncertainties. Uncertainty in subsidies for green technologies is considered as an example. Technological progress is exogenous and modeled as a jump process with a drift. The analytical solution is presented for cases when there is no subsidy uncertainty and when the subsidy changes once. The case when the subsidy follows a time invariant Markov process is analyzed numerically. The results show that improving the innovation process raises the investment thresholds. When technological jumps are small or rare, this improvement reduces the expected time before technology adoption. However, when technological jumps are large or abundant, this improvement may raise this expected time.

JEL Classification: C63; D81; O33; Q58

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank Svetlana Boyarchenko for her continued advice and encouragement. I also thank Thomas Wiseman, Maxwell Stinchcombe, Andres Almazan, Stathis Tompaidis, Charles F. Mason, Till Requate, Maurizio Iacopetta, Eugenio Miravete, Randal Watson Maedeh Faraji, Marzieh Mirghasemi, Ali Akbar Merrikh and anonymous referees. I am thankful to seminar participants at University of Texas at Austin in Fall 2009 for insightful comments. Also I benefited from comments of participants of the Midwest Economic Theory and Trade Meetings (Madison, Fall 2010) and CU Environmental and Resource Economics Workshop (Vail, 2010).

Appendix

Derivation of adoption thresholds and value function

Let Eq be the normalized expected present value operator or EPV-operator. This operator gives the present value of a stream of payoffs. The value depends on the present observed x and it is normalized such that Eq of a stream of payoff that gives one unit at any time is equal to one. Note that Eq=q(qL)1. See Boyarchenko and Levendorskiĭ (2007) for details. I also define Eq+ to be the normalized EPV-operator under the supremum process X¯t=sup0s<tXs and Eq to be the normalized EPV-operator under the infimum process X_t=inf0s<tXs. Let a1=q(λβ1)μ(β2β1) and a2=q(λβ2)μ(β1β2), I derive the action of operators for supremum and infimum processes to be

[30]{Equ(x)=u(x)Eq+u(x)=i=12ai0+eβiyu(x+y)dy.

Refer to Boyarchenko and Levendorskiĭ (2007) for more details on how to derive the EPV-operators. For exponential functions they reduce to

[31]{Eqezx=ezxEq+ezx=i=12ai0+eβiyez(x+y)dy=[a1β1z+a2β2z]ezx.

I define κq+z and κqz such that Eq±ezx=κq±(z)ezx. It also holds that

[32]{κq(z)=1κq+(z)=qqΨ(z)=a1β1z+a2β2z

According to Wiener-Hopf factorization formula, the normalized EPV operator can be expressed as Eq=Eq+Eq. Hence, κq(z)=qqΨ(z)=κq+(z)κq(z). See Boyarchenko and Levendorskiĭ (2007) for more details on Wiener-Hopf factorization, EPV-operators and how they are derived.

To make the problem [4] look like the standard exit problem, I define V(x;h)=V(x;h)A0Bqeσx(1qθ). Then, problem [4] is equivalent to the following in which the firm chooses the optimal time to exit:

[33]{(qL)V(x;h)=A0BA0Bκq(σ)eσx(1qθ)x<hV(x;h)=0xh

The adoption threshold in problem [4] is the same as the exit threshold in problem [33]. From the paper by Boyarchenko and Levendorskiĭ (2006), it follows that the solution for the value function for x<h is

[34]V(x;h)=A0BqEq+1(,h)(x)Eq11qθκq(σ)eσx.

The right hand side of the Bellman equation in problem [33] is non-increasing in x. Based on what Boyarchenko and Levendorskiĭ (2006) have shown, to maximize the value function, h needs to solve EqA0B11qθκq(σ)eσx=0.

[35]eσh=κq+(σ)1qθ=κq(σ)1qθ

Knowing the adoption threshold, h, I can find the value function for x<h from eq. [34].

[36]V(x)={A0Bq[1+i=12aiσβi(βiσ)eβi(hx)]x<hA0Bq(1qθ)eσxxh.

Proof of Proposition 2.1

Proof. From eq. [8] it follows that

[37]h=1σlnκq(σ)1qθ=1σlnqlnqΨ(σ)ln(1qθ).
  • θ: By direct differentiation with respect to θ I have: hθ=qσ(1qθ)>0. Hence h increases as θ goes up.

  • σ: hσ=1σκq(σ)κq(σ)1σ2lnκq(σ)1qθ=1σa1(β1σ)2+a2(β2σ)2a1β1σ+a2β2σ1σlna1β1σ+a2β2σ1qθ which goes to as σ gets close to zero from the right and goes to + when σ gets close to β1.

For the rest of the proof remember that qΨ(σ)=qμσcσλσ

  • μ: hμ=1qΨ(σ)>0 because the valid values of σ are between zero and β1 which makes qΨ(σ) positive.

  • c: hc=1(λσ)(qΨ(σ))>0.

  • λ:hλ=c(λσ)2(qΨ(σ))<0.

  • q: hq=1σ1q1qΨ(σ)+θ(1qθ). As q increases from Ψ(σ) to 1θ, this derivative change from to +.

References

Abel, A. B., and J. C.Eberly. 2002. “Q for the Long Run.” Working Paper.Suche in Google Scholar

Baerenklau, K. A., and K. C.Knapp. 2007. “Dynamics of Agricultural Technology Adoption: Age Structure, Reversibility, and Uncertainty.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics89:190201.10.1111/j.1467-8276.2007.00972.xSuche in Google Scholar

Baker, L. C. 2001. “Managed Care and Technology Adoption in Health Care: Evidence from Magnetic Resonance Imaging.” Journal of Health Economics20:395421.10.1016/S0167-6296(01)00072-8Suche in Google Scholar

Boyarchenko, S., and S.Levendorskiĭ. 2006. “General Option Exercise Rules, with Applications to Embedded Options and Monopolistic Expansion.” B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics: Contributions to Theoretical Economics6:153.10.2202/1534-5971.1292Suche in Google Scholar

Boyarchenko, S., and S.Levendorskiĭ. 2007. Irreversible Decisions Under Uncertainty: Optimal Stopping Made Easy. Studies in Economic Theory, Vol. 27. Berlin: Springer.Suche in Google Scholar

Boyarchenko, S., and S.Levendorskiĭ. 2008. “Exit Problems in Regime-Switching Models.” Journal of Mathematical Economics44:180206.10.1016/j.jmateco.2007.07.001Suche in Google Scholar

Dixit, A. K., and R. S.Pindyck. 1994. Investment under Uncertainty, 30309. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9781400830176Suche in Google Scholar

Doraszelski, U. 2001. “The Net Present Value Method versus the Option Value of Waiting: A Note on Farzin, Huisman and Kort (1998).” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control25:110915.10.1016/S0165-1889(00)00023-3Suche in Google Scholar

Farzin, Y. H., K. J. M.Huisman, and P. M.Kort. 1998. “Optimal Timing of Technology Adoption.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control22:77999.10.1016/S0165-1889(97)00097-3Suche in Google Scholar

Hoppe, H. C. 2002. “The Timing of New Technology Adoption: Theoretical Models and Empirical Evidence.” Manchester School70:5676.10.1111/1467-9957.00283Suche in Google Scholar

Huisman, K. J. M. 2001. Technology Investment: A Game Theoretic Real Options Approach. Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers.10.1007/978-1-4757-3423-2Suche in Google Scholar

Isik, M. 2004. “Incentives for Technology Adoption under Environmental Policy Uncertainty: Implications for Green Payment Programs.” Environmental and Resource Economics27:24763.10.1023/B:EARE.0000017624.07757.3fSuche in Google Scholar

Kretschmer, T., E. J.Miravete, and J. C.Pernias. 2012. “Competitive Pressure and the Adoption of Complementary Innovations.” The American Economic Review102:154070.10.1257/aer.102.4.1540Suche in Google Scholar

Pawlina, G., and P. M.Kort. 2005. “Investment under Uncertainty and Policy Change.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control29:1193209.10.1016/j.jedc.2004.07.002Suche in Google Scholar

Sarkar, S. 2000. “On the Investment-Uncertainty Relationship in a Real Options Model.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control24:21925.10.1016/S0165-1889(99)00005-6Suche in Google Scholar

Stoneman, P., O.Toivanen, C.Antonelli, D.Foray, B. H.Hall, and W. E.Steinmueller. 2006. Technological Diffusion Under Uncertainty: A Real Options Model Applied to the Comparative International Diffusion of Robot Technology, 43867. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Warwick U.Suche in Google Scholar

von Dollen, A., and T.Requate. 2008. “Environmental Policy and Uncertain Arrival of Future Abatement Technology.” B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy: Topics in Economic Analysis and Policy8:120.Suche in Google Scholar

Wong, K. P. 2007. “The Effect of Uncertainty on Investment Timing in a Real Options Model.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control31:215267.10.1016/j.jedc.2006.07.002Suche in Google Scholar

  1. 1

    To derive the profit flow it is assumed that the monopolist uses Lt units of labor to produce quantity Qt of a product. Let w be the wage for one unit of labor. Eq. [1] can be derived for two different scenarios. In the first one technology improves the productivity. For this case assume the production function is Qt=DtLtρ, where ρ(0,1] and the firm faces a market demand Qt=Ptϵ for its output, where Pt is the price of the product and ϵ is the price elasticity of demand and ϵ>1. Using these assumptions, the solution for the profit of the firm is given by eq. [1] where σ=(ϵ1)ϵρ(ϵ1) and B=wρ(ϵ1)ρ(ϵ1)ϵϵρ(ϵ1)ϵρ(ϵ1)ϵϵρ(ϵ1)1.

    In the second scenario technology raises the demand. For this case assume the production function is Qt=Ltρ, where ρ(0,1] and the firm faces a market demand Qt=DtPtϵ for its output, where Pt is the price of the product and ϵ is the elasticity of demand and ϵ>1. Using these assumptions, the solution for the profit of the firm is given by eq. [1] where σ=1ϵρ(ϵ1) and B=wρ(ϵ1)ρ(ϵ1)ϵϵρ(ϵ1)ϵρ(ϵ1)ϵϵρ(ϵ1)1.

    If innovation improves the productivity, then σ can take any positive value depending on the elasticity of demand and the parameter of the production function. If innovation raises the demand for the product, σ cannot take values less than or equal to one.

  2. 2

    The work by Boyarchenko and Levendorskiĭ (2006) is an example of models with multiple adoptions of technology. Another example is the work by Farzin, Huisman, and Kort (1998) which was improved by Doraszelski (2001).

  3. 3

    Having the cost of adoption proportional to the profit flow after adoption is a better assumption than a constant value for the cost of adoption. The cost of adoption of a more advanced technology is larger due to higher adjustment costs. So it is expected that the cost of adoption increases as the frontier technology advances. This assumption is also used by Boyarchenko and Levendorskiĭ (2006).

Published Online: 2014-6-7
Published in Print: 2014-10-1

©2014 by De Gruyter

Heruntergeladen am 21.10.2025 von https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejeap-2013-0167/html
Button zum nach oben scrollen