Startseite On Public Host Liability
Artikel
Lizenziert
Nicht lizenziert Erfordert eine Authentifizierung

On Public Host Liability

  • Jeong-Yoo Kim EMAIL logo
Veröffentlicht/Copyright: 17. Oktober 2015
Veröffentlichen auch Sie bei De Gruyter Brill

Abstract

Civil laws or commercial laws in many countries stipulate the liability of the public host whereby a public host is liable for the losses due to damage or lost of the property of the guest left to the host. In this paper, we consider the situation in which the value of the property is ex ante not known to the host. In this case, we show that the voluntary information disclosure rule is more efficient than the mandatory information disclosure rule. We also derive some implications on Article 153 of the Korean Commercial Law prescribing for this case.


Corresponding author: Jeong-Yoo Kim, Department of Economics, Kyung Hee University, 1 Hoegidong, Dongdaemunku, Seoul 130-701, Korea, e-mail:
aI started to write this paper with Kyu Yub Lee at the early stage, but did not include his coauthorship at his request. I am grateful to Albert Choi and the audiences at the 4th annual conference of AsLEA held at University of Kyushu for helpful comments.

Appendix

Proof of Lemma 1: Suppose e2s>0. By Kuhn-Tucker conditions, it must be that

(7)p2(e1s,e2s)v+1=0, (7)
(8)p1(e1s,e2s)v+10. (8)

Since p1(e1, e2)<p2(e1, e2), this is contradictory. ||

Proof of Proposition 1: Under the guest liability rule, H has no incentive to monitor at all. Thus, e1=0. Hence, G chooses e2 to minimize the cost borne by G

mine2GC(e2)=p(0,e2)v+e2.

On the other hand, under the host liability rule, G can be compensated for all his losses, so he will choose e2=0. Then, H chooses e1 to minimize the cost incurred to H

mine1HC(e1)=p(e1,0)v+e1.

This is equivalent to the social optimum.||

Proof of Proposition 2: The social cost under mandatory disclosure rule given in (3) can be rewritten as

E[SCM(v)]=v˜v¯[p(e1(v),0)v+e1(v)+c]f(v)dv+v_v˜[p(e1(v),0)v+e1(v)+c]f(v)dv=E[SCV(v)]v_v¯[p(0,e2(v))v+e2(v)]f(v)dv+v_v˜[p(e1(v),0)v+e1(v)+c]f(v)dv,

by using (6). Since c>p(0,e2(v))v+e2 for v(v_,v˜), we have E[SCM(v)]>E[SCV(v)]. ‖

References

Cheong, I., and J.-Y. Kim. 2004. “Costly Information Disclosure in Oligopoly.” Journal of Industrial Economics 52: 121–132.10.1111/j.0022-1821.2004.00218.xSuche in Google Scholar

Crawford, V., and J. Sobel. 1982. “Strategic Information Transmission.” Econometrica 50: 1431–1451.10.2307/1913390Suche in Google Scholar

Farrell, J., and R. Gibbons. 1989. “Cheap Talk can Matter in Bargaining.” Journal of Economic Theory 48: 221–237.10.1016/0022-0531(89)90125-7Suche in Google Scholar

Grossman, S. 1981. “The Role of Warranties and Private Disclosure about Product Quality.” Journal of Law and Economics 24: 461–483.10.1086/466995Suche in Google Scholar

Milgrom, P. 1981. “Good News and Bad News: Representation Theorems and Applications.” Bell Journal of Economics 12: 380–391.10.2307/3003562Suche in Google Scholar

Mookherjee, D., and I. Png. 1992. “Monitoring versus Investigation in Law Enforcement and Regulation.” American Economic Review 82: 556–565.Suche in Google Scholar

Shavell, S. 1991. “Specific versus General Enforcement of Law.” Journal of Political Economy 99: 1088–1108.10.1086/261790Suche in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2015-10-17
Published in Print: 2015-10-1

©2015 by De Gruyter

Heruntergeladen am 3.10.2025 von https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/ajle-2015-0011/html
Button zum nach oben scrollen