Startseite Mixed Bundling and Mergers
Artikel
Lizenziert
Nicht lizenziert Erfordert eine Authentifizierung

Mixed Bundling and Mergers

  • Daniel R. Vincent EMAIL logo
Veröffentlicht/Copyright: 12. Februar 2024

Abstract

Beginning with two Hotelling duopolies where demand for the product in each market is independent of demand for the product in the other, the paper examines the price, profit and welfare consequences that result when first one firm in a market merges with a firm in the other market creating a single two-product firm and then the remaining two firms merge – resulting in a duopoly of two-product firms. The paper demonstrates how to compute the equilibrium in each market structure. Assuming that firms cannot commit not to use all the pricing instruments at their disposal, mixed bundling by two-product firms emerges following each merger. While such behavior is a unilateral best response, the equilibrium consequences of these choices end up lowering total profits and welfare compared to the pre-merger markets suggesting that the opportunity to engage in mixed bundling cannot be the sole motivation for such mergers.


Corresponding author: Daniel R. Vincent, Department of Economics, University of Maryland, College Park, MD 20742, USA, E-mail:

I am grateful to Marius Schwartz for many insightful discussions and suggestions.


Appendix 1

Computational Figures

See Figures 311.

Figure 3: 
Effect on bundle prices in independent goods and blended markets: t1 = t2 = t.
Figure 3:

Effect on bundle prices in independent goods and blended markets: t1 = t2 = t.

Figure 4: 
Effect on bundle prices in independent goods and blended markets: t1 = 1 ≥ t2.
Figure 4:

Effect on bundle prices in independent goods and blended markets: t1 = 1 ≥ t2.

Figure 5: 
Effect on bundle prices in blended and duopoly markets: t1 = t2 = t.
Figure 5:

Effect on bundle prices in blended and duopoly markets: t1 = t2 = t.

Figure 6: 
Effect on bundle prices in blended and duopoly markets: t1 = 1 ≥ t2.
Figure 6:

Effect on bundle prices in blended and duopoly markets: t1 = 1 ≥ t2.

Figure 7: 
Individual price effects of mergers (t1 = t2 = t).
Figure 7:

Individual price effects of mergers (t1 = t2 = t).

Figure 8: 
Effects of mergers on individual goods prices (t1 = 1 ≥ t2): p2.
Figure 8:

Effects of mergers on individual goods prices (t1 = 1 ≥ t2): p2.

Figure 9: 
Effects of mergers on individual goods prices (t1 = 1 ≥ t2): p1.
Figure 9:

Effects of mergers on individual goods prices (t1 = 1 ≥ t2): p1.

Figure 10: 
Profit effects of mergers (t1 = t2 = t).
Figure 10:

Profit effects of mergers (t1 = t2 = t).

Figure 11: 
Profit effects of mergers (t1 = 1 ≥ t2).
Figure 11:

Profit effects of mergers (t1 = 1 ≥ t2).

Appendix 2

Proofs

Proof of Result 4

For a fixed vector of prices, p 1 A , p 2 A , P A , p 1 B , p 2 B , P B , assuming all consumers buy all bundles, the market is partitioned as given in Lemma 1. The uniform distribution then gives the measures of the four market segments as the area of the sets AB, AA, BB, BA:

μ ( A B ) = ( 1 x ̄ 2 ) x ̲ 1 ; μ ( B A ) = ( 1 x ̄ 1 ) x ̲ 2 ; μ ( A A ) = x ̄ 2 x ̄ 1 ( x ̄ 2 x ̲ 2 ) ( x ̄ 1 x ̲ 1 ) / 2 .

These definitions yield the following:

μ ( A B ) p 1 A = ( 1 x ̄ 2 ) 2 t 1 x ̲ 1 2 t 2 μ ( A B ) P A = x ̲ 1 2 t 2 μ ( A A ) p 1 A = x ̲ 1 2 t 2 μ ( A A ) P A = x ̄ 1 2 t 2 x ̄ 2 2 t 1 + x ̄ 1 x ̲ 1 4 t 2 + x ̄ 2 x ̲ 2 4 t 1 = t 1 ( x ̄ 1 + x ̲ 1 ) + t 2 ( x ̄ 2 + x ̲ 2 ) 4 t 1 t 2 .

Using the fact that

t j ( x ̄ j + x ̲ j ) = 2 t j + P B P A + p j B + p i A p j B p i B / 2 ,

we can also write

μ ( A A ) P A = t 1 + t 2 + P B P A 4 t 1 t 2 .

Firm A’s profit function is

(9) Π p 1 A , p 2 A , P A = p 1 A μ ( A B ) + P A μ ( A A ) + p 2 A μ ( B A ) .

Thus the first order condition for p 1 A is

(10) 0 = μ ( A B ) p 1 A 1 x ̄ 2 2 t 1 + P A p 1 A x ̲ 1 2 t 2

A symmetric condition holds for p 2 A . The first order condition for P A is

(11) 0 = μ ( A A ) + p 1 A x ̲ 1 2 t 2 P A t 1 + t 2 + P B P A 4 t 1 t 2 + p 2 A x ̲ 2 2 t 1

Assuming a symmetric solution, p j A = p j B , P A = P B , x ̲ j = 1 x ̄ j , μ(AB) = μ(BA) and Δ = p 1 A + p 2 A P A . Summing the first order conditions for p 1 A , p 2 A then eliminates the p j A s yielding an expression only in terms of Δ:

( t 2 Δ ) + ( t 1 Δ ) = 2 ( t 2 Δ ) ( t 1 Δ ) .

This is a convex quadratic in Δ (and therefore p j A ) so necessary second order conditions imply selecting the smallest of the roots. Substituting into (10) for p 1 A and (11) for P A , yields necessary conditions for a symmetric equilibrium. If t1 = t2 = t, then the solution for Δ = t/2. This then gives p j = 11 t / 12 + c j , P = 8 t / 6 + c 1 + c 2 , x ̲ j = 1 x ̄ j = 1 / 4 and firm profits are (2/3 + 1/32)t = 0.698t.

Proof of Theorem 1

Suppose that Firm A offers its product solely as a bundle at price P A and no synthetic bundling occurs.[18] Define P B = p 1 B + p 2 B and δ = P B P A . This implies that the market is partitioned by the partition of the unit square determined by intersection of the line

x 2 = t 1 + t 2 + δ 2 t 2 t 1 t 2 x 1

and the unit square.

The partition could occur in three ways: (a) the dividing manifold could intersect the left edge and the bottom of the square (δ < t2t1); (b) the manifold could intersect the top and bottom of the square, (δ ∈ [t2t1, t1t2]), or; (c) the top of the square and the right edge of the square (δt1t2).

Case (a) can be shown never to be an equilibrium since in that case, Firm A’s bundle price exceeds the sum of the prices of the independent firms and Firm A always prefers to lower its price to capture more market.

In Case (b), suppose δ = t1t2γ, γ > 0. The firms’ first order conditions can be solved directly to yield

P A = 5 4 t 1 p i B = 3 4 t 1 ,

and this case can only arise for t 2 ( 0 , 3 4 t 1 ] .

Suppose instead of offering only the bundle price Firm A offers the equilibrium bundle price and a stand-alone price for product 2A of

p 2 A = t 2 + p 2 B 2 t 2 ϵ .

At this price, consumers in the lower right corner of the unit square will choose to form the synthetic bundle BA since a consumer of type ( t 1 + t 2 + δ 2 t 1 , 0 ) was previously just indifferent between buying the two goods from A and buying the two goods from B. This segment of the market is the rectangle x 1 ϵ , 1 × [ 0 , x ̲ 2 ] where

x 1 ϵ = t 1 + t 2 + δ 2 t 2 ϵ 2 t 1 = 1 γ + 2 t 2 ϵ 2 t 1

and, from Lemma 1,

x ̲ 2 = t 2 p 2 A + p 1 B P B 2 t 2 = t 2 t 2 + p 2 B 2 t 2 ϵ + p 1 B P B 2 t 2 = ϵ

since P B = p 1 B + p 2 B . This rectangle has area ϵ 1 x 1 ϵ = γ ϵ + 2 t 2 ϵ 2 2 t 1 The intersection of this segment with the segment Firm A was selling under pure bundling is a triangle with vertices

x 1 ϵ , 0 , x 1 ϵ , ϵ , t 1 + t 2 + δ 2 t 1 , 0

where t 1 + t 2 + Δ 2 t 1 x 1 ϵ = t 2 t 1 ϵ so its area is t 2 2 t 1 ϵ 2 . Thus, the deviation generates a gross gain of

p 2 A γ ϵ + 2 t 2 ϵ 2 2 t 1

and a gross loss from cannibalized sales of the bundle of

P A t 2 2 t 1 ϵ 2 .

For small ϵ, the gain dominates the loss and this deviation is profitable.

Case (c) occurs for t 2 [ 3 4 t 1 , t 1 ] . In this case, BB is a triangle in the upper right corner of the unit square with vertices

( x ̲ 1 c ( δ ) , 1 ) , ( 1 , x ̲ 2 c ( δ ) , ( 1,1 )

where

x ̲ 1 c ( δ ) = t 1 t 2 + δ 2 t 1 ,

and

x ̲ 2 c ( δ ) = t 2 t 1 + δ 2 t 2 .

The first order conditions for 1B, 2B, A imply

P B = t 1 + t 2 + P A 2

and

0 = 8 t 1 t 2 ( P B ) 2 2 P B P A .

Combining the two equations from the FOCs gives

0 = 5 ( P B ) 2 2 ( t 1 + t 2 ) P B 8 t 1 t 2

which implies

P B = ( 2 ( t 1 + t 2 ) + 4 ( t 1 + t 2 ) 2 + 160 t 1 t 2 ) / 10 .

The candidate equilibrium price P B is increasing in t2 so it reaches its maximum at t2 = t1. At that value, P B = 1.76t1 and assuming symmetry, p 1 B = . 86 t 1 . Thus, in this region, any optimal p 1 B < t 1 .

Suppose Firm A offers instead of the pure bundling solution, the bundle price P A and a stand-alone price, p 2 A = P A (or equivalently, suppose a consumer can purchase the bundle, AA and discard 1A costlessly.) Applying the definitions in Lemma 1, if x ̄ 1 < 1 , the market segment BA will have positive measure.

x ̄ 1 = t 1 + p 2 A + p 1 B P A 2 t 1 = 2 t 1 + p 1 B t 1 2 t 1 = 1 t 1 p 1 B 2 t 1 < 1 .

Since this implies (using Lemma 1)

x ̲ 2 = t 2 + p 1 B + p 2 B P A p 1 B 2 t 2 = t 2 + p 2 B P A 2 t 2 = t 2 p 1 B + p 1 B + p 2 B P A 2 t 2 t 2 t 1 + δ 2 t 2 = x ̲ 2 c ,

and p 2 A = P A , Firm A obtains the same revenue per sale in market segment BA and the union of the new segments AA and BA strictly contains the old AA. Thus, this deviation is profitable and breaks the candidate equilibrium.

Proof of Theorem 2

The market partitions are as outlined in Lemma 1, however, since the price of bundle BB is the sum of the standalone prices, p j B , the definitions of the boundaries between BB and AB or BA are simplified somewhat to

x ̲ j = t j + p j B p j A 2 t j .

The upper boundary, x ̄ j is the same as before. For convenience, set Δ A = p 1 A + p 2 A P A and note that

x ̄ j x ̲ j = t j + p i A + p j B P A t j + p j B p j A 2 t j = p i A + p j B P A + p j A p j B 2 t j = p i A + p j A P A 2 t j = Δ A 2 t j

Given the uniform distribution, the measures of the sets are computed in the same way as for the mixed bundling two-firm market. Now, however, the sales of (say) product 2B, then is the sum μ(BA) + μ(BB). This yields

μ ( A B ) + μ ( B B ) = ( 1 x ̄ 2 ) + ( x ̄ 2 x ̲ 2 ) ( 1 x ̲ 1 ) ( x ̄ 1 x ̲ 1 ) ( x ̄ 2 x ̲ ) 2 = ( 1 x ̄ 2 ) + Δ A ( 1 x ̲ 1 ) 2 t 2 Δ A 2 8 t 1 t 2

Only the first term depends on p 2 B so

μ ( A B ) p 2 B + μ ( B B ) p 2 B = ( 1 x ̄ 2 ) p 2 B = 1 2 t 2

Firm 2B then selects its best response in price, p 2 B holding fixed the three prices of Firm A and the price of Firm 1B. The first order condition yields a unique solution

0 = μ ( A B ) + μ ( B B ) p 2 B 2 t 2 = ( 1 x ̄ 2 ) + Δ A ( 1 x ̲ 1 ) 2 t 2 Δ A 2 8 t 1 t 2 p 2 B 2 t 2 = t 2 p 1 A p 2 B + P A 2 t 2 + Δ A ( 1 x ̲ 1 ) 2 t 2 Δ A 2 8 t 1 t 2 p 2 B 2 t 2 = t 2 p 1 A + p 2 A P A + p 2 A p 2 B 2 t 2 + Δ A ( 1 x ̲ 1 ) 2 t 2 Δ A 2 8 t 1 t 2 p 2 B 2 t 2 = t 2 Δ A + p 2 A p 2 B 2 t 2 + Δ A ( 1 x ̲ 1 ) 2 t 2 Δ A 2 8 t 1 t 2 p 2 B 2 t 2 = t 2 Δ A + p 2 A 2 t 2 + Δ A t 1 + p 1 A p 1 B 4 t 2 t 1 Δ A 2 8 t 1 t 2 p 2 B t 2 = t 2 Δ A + p 2 A 2 + Δ A t 1 + p 1 A p 1 B 4 t 1 Δ A 2 8 t 1 p 2 B .

Observe this is decreasing in p 2 B so yields a unique best response. Rewriting, yields

p 2 B = t 2 Δ A + p 2 A 2 + Δ A t 1 + p 1 A 4 t 1 Δ A 2 8 t 1 Δ A 4 t 1 p 1 B .

A similar condition, replacing 1 with 2 and BA for AB, holds for the other independent firm. These equations form a linear system in p 1 B , p 2 B and yield unique solutions as functions of P 1 A , p 2 A , p 1 A .

Writing p i B = A i Δ A 4 t 1 p 1 B we get

Δ A p 2 B 4 t 2 = Δ A 2 4 t 2 Δ A p 1 B 16 t 1 t 2 = A 1 p 1 B

So,

Δ A 4 t 1 A 2 Δ A 2 p 1 B = 16 t 1 t 1 A 1 16 t 1 t 2 p 1 B .

Thus

(12) p i B = 4 t i 4 t j A i Δ A A j 16 t 1 t 2 Δ A 2

The derivatives of the profit function for the integrated firm are the same as given in (10) and (11). These solutions are then inserted in (12) to obtain the prices for the single-good firms.

References

Adams, W.J., and J. L. Yellen. 1976. “Commodity Bundling and the Burden of Monopoly.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 90: 475–98. https://doi.org/10.2307/1886045.Suche in Google Scholar

Armstrong, M. 2006. “Recent Developments in the Economics of Price Discrimination.” In Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications: Ninth World Congress, Vol. 2, edited by R. Blundell, W. Newey, and T. Perssons, 97–141. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9781139052276.006Suche in Google Scholar

Armstrong, M., and J. Vickers. 2010. “Competitive Nonlinear Pricing and Bundling.” The Review of Economic Studies 77: 30–60. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-937x.2009.00562.x.Suche in Google Scholar

Chen, Y.M. 1997. “Equilibrium Product Bundling.” Journal of Business 70: 85–103. https://doi.org/10.1086/209709.Suche in Google Scholar

Federal Communications Commission. 2015. Memorandum Opinion and Order: ATT and DirecTV. Available at: https://docs.fcc.gov/public/attachments/FCC-15-94A1.pdf.Suche in Google Scholar

Gans, J., and S. King. 2006. “Paying for Loyalty: Product Bundling in Oligopoly.” The Journal of Industrial Economics LIV (1): 43–62. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6451.2006.00275.x.Suche in Google Scholar

Kolasky, W. 2001. Conglomerate Mergers and Range Effects: It’s a Long Way from Chicago to Brussels. Technical Report, Department of Justice.Suche in Google Scholar

Manelli, A., and D.R. Vincent. 2006. “Bundling as an Optimal Selling Mechanism for a Multiple Good Monopoly.” Journal of Economic Theory 127 (1): 1–35. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jet.2005.08.007.Suche in Google Scholar

Matutes, C., and P. Regibeau. 1988. ““Mix and Match”: Product Compatibility without Network Externalities.” The RAND Journal of Economics 19 (2): 221–34. https://doi.org/10.2307/2555701.Suche in Google Scholar

Matutes, C., and P. Regibeau. 1992. “Compatibility and Bundling of Complementary Goods in a Duopoly.” The Journal of Industrial Economics XL (1): 37–54. https://doi.org/10.2307/2950626.Suche in Google Scholar

McAfee, R.P., J. McMillan, and M. Whinston. 1989. “Multi-product Monopoly, Commodity Bundling and Correlation of Values.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 104 (2): 371–83. https://doi.org/10.2307/2937852.Suche in Google Scholar

Thanassoulis, J. 2007. “Competitive Mixed Bundling and Consumer Surplus.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 16 (2): 437–67. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1530-9134.2007.00145.x.Suche in Google Scholar

Tirole, Jean. 1988. The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Suche in Google Scholar

Zhou, J. 2017. “Competitive Bundling.” Econometrica 87 (1): 145–72. https://doi.org/10.3982/ecta14251.Suche in Google Scholar

Received: 2024-01-04
Accepted: 2024-01-16
Published Online: 2024-02-12
Published in Print: 2024-10-26

© 2024 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Heruntergeladen am 21.9.2025 von https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/rne-2024-0001/html?lang=de
Button zum nach oben scrollen