Abstract
Beginning with two Hotelling duopolies where demand for the product in each market is independent of demand for the product in the other, the paper examines the price, profit and welfare consequences that result when first one firm in a market merges with a firm in the other market creating a single two-product firm and then the remaining two firms merge – resulting in a duopoly of two-product firms. The paper demonstrates how to compute the equilibrium in each market structure. Assuming that firms cannot commit not to use all the pricing instruments at their disposal, mixed bundling by two-product firms emerges following each merger. While such behavior is a unilateral best response, the equilibrium consequences of these choices end up lowering total profits and welfare compared to the pre-merger markets suggesting that the opportunity to engage in mixed bundling cannot be the sole motivation for such mergers.
Computational Figures

Effect on bundle prices in independent goods and blended markets: t1 = t2 = t.

Effect on bundle prices in independent goods and blended markets: t1 = 1 ≥ t2.

Effect on bundle prices in blended and duopoly markets: t1 = t2 = t.

Effect on bundle prices in blended and duopoly markets: t1 = 1 ≥ t2.

Individual price effects of mergers (t1 = t2 = t).

Effects of mergers on individual goods prices (t1 = 1 ≥ t2): p2.

Effects of mergers on individual goods prices (t1 = 1 ≥ t2): p1.

Profit effects of mergers (t1 = t2 = t).

Profit effects of mergers (t1 = 1 ≥ t2).
Appendix 2
Proofs
Proof of Result 4
For a fixed vector of prices,
These definitions yield the following:
Using the fact that
we can also write
Firm A’s profit function is
Thus the first order condition for
A symmetric condition holds for
Assuming a symmetric solution,
This is a convex quadratic in Δ (and therefore
Proof of Theorem 1
Suppose that Firm A offers its product solely as a bundle at price P
A
and no synthetic bundling occurs.[18] Define
and the unit square.
The partition could occur in three ways: (a) the dividing manifold could intersect the left edge and the bottom of the square (δ < t2 − t1); (b) the manifold could intersect the top and bottom of the square, (δ ∈ [t2 − t1, t1 − t2]), or; (c) the top of the square and the right edge of the square (δ ≥ t1 − t2).
Case (a) can be shown never to be an equilibrium since in that case, Firm A’s bundle price exceeds the sum of the prices of the independent firms and Firm A always prefers to lower its price to capture more market.
In Case (b), suppose δ = t1 − t2 − γ, γ > 0. The firms’ first order conditions can be solved directly to yield
and this case can only arise for
Suppose instead of offering only the bundle price Firm A offers the equilibrium bundle price and a stand-alone price for product 2A of
At this price, consumers in the lower right corner of the unit square will choose to form the synthetic bundle BA since a consumer of type
and, from Lemma 1,
since
where
and a gross loss from cannibalized sales of the bundle of
For small ϵ, the gain dominates the loss and this deviation is profitable.
Case (c) occurs for
where
and
The first order conditions for 1B, 2B, A imply
and
Combining the two equations from the FOCs gives
which implies
The candidate equilibrium price P
B
is increasing in t2 so it reaches its maximum at t2 = t1. At that value, P
B
= 1.76t1 and assuming symmetry,
Suppose Firm A offers instead of the pure bundling solution, the bundle price P
A
and a stand-alone price,
Since this implies (using Lemma 1)
and
Proof of Theorem 2
The market partitions are as outlined in Lemma 1, however, since the price of bundle BB is the sum of the standalone prices,
The upper boundary,
Given the uniform distribution, the measures of the sets are computed in the same way as for the mixed bundling two-firm market. Now, however, the sales of (say) product 2B, then is the sum μ(BA) + μ(BB). This yields
Only the first term depends on
Firm 2B then selects its best response in price,
Observe this is decreasing in
A similar condition, replacing 1 with 2 and BA for AB, holds for the other independent firm. These equations form a linear system in
Writing
So,
Thus
The derivatives of the profit function for the integrated firm are the same as given in (10) and (11). These solutions are then inserted in (12) to obtain the prices for the single-good firms.
References
Adams, W.J., and J. L. Yellen. 1976. “Commodity Bundling and the Burden of Monopoly.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 90: 475–98. https://doi.org/10.2307/1886045.Suche in Google Scholar
Armstrong, M. 2006. “Recent Developments in the Economics of Price Discrimination.” In Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications: Ninth World Congress, Vol. 2, edited by R. Blundell, W. Newey, and T. Perssons, 97–141. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9781139052276.006Suche in Google Scholar
Armstrong, M., and J. Vickers. 2010. “Competitive Nonlinear Pricing and Bundling.” The Review of Economic Studies 77: 30–60. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-937x.2009.00562.x.Suche in Google Scholar
Chen, Y.M. 1997. “Equilibrium Product Bundling.” Journal of Business 70: 85–103. https://doi.org/10.1086/209709.Suche in Google Scholar
Federal Communications Commission. 2015. Memorandum Opinion and Order: ATT and DirecTV. Available at: https://docs.fcc.gov/public/attachments/FCC-15-94A1.pdf.Suche in Google Scholar
Gans, J., and S. King. 2006. “Paying for Loyalty: Product Bundling in Oligopoly.” The Journal of Industrial Economics LIV (1): 43–62. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6451.2006.00275.x.Suche in Google Scholar
Kolasky, W. 2001. Conglomerate Mergers and Range Effects: It’s a Long Way from Chicago to Brussels. Technical Report, Department of Justice.Suche in Google Scholar
Manelli, A., and D.R. Vincent. 2006. “Bundling as an Optimal Selling Mechanism for a Multiple Good Monopoly.” Journal of Economic Theory 127 (1): 1–35. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jet.2005.08.007.Suche in Google Scholar
Matutes, C., and P. Regibeau. 1988. ““Mix and Match”: Product Compatibility without Network Externalities.” The RAND Journal of Economics 19 (2): 221–34. https://doi.org/10.2307/2555701.Suche in Google Scholar
Matutes, C., and P. Regibeau. 1992. “Compatibility and Bundling of Complementary Goods in a Duopoly.” The Journal of Industrial Economics XL (1): 37–54. https://doi.org/10.2307/2950626.Suche in Google Scholar
McAfee, R.P., J. McMillan, and M. Whinston. 1989. “Multi-product Monopoly, Commodity Bundling and Correlation of Values.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 104 (2): 371–83. https://doi.org/10.2307/2937852.Suche in Google Scholar
Thanassoulis, J. 2007. “Competitive Mixed Bundling and Consumer Surplus.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 16 (2): 437–67. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1530-9134.2007.00145.x.Suche in Google Scholar
Tirole, Jean. 1988. The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Suche in Google Scholar
Zhou, J. 2017. “Competitive Bundling.” Econometrica 87 (1): 145–72. https://doi.org/10.3982/ecta14251.Suche in Google Scholar
© 2024 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Frontmatter
- Articles
- Mixed Bundling and Mergers
- Price-Cap Regulation of Firms That Supply Their Rivals
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Frontmatter
- Articles
- Mixed Bundling and Mergers
- Price-Cap Regulation of Firms That Supply Their Rivals