Home Price-Cap Regulation of Firms That Supply Their Rivals
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

Price-Cap Regulation of Firms That Supply Their Rivals

  • Soo Jin Kim , Omar A. Nayeem and Aleksandr Yankelevich EMAIL logo
Published/Copyright: February 12, 2024

Abstract

We study price-cap regulation in a market in which a vertically integrated upstream monopolist sells an essential input to a downstream competitor. In the absence of regulation, entry benefits both firms, but may harm downstream consumers because the upstream monopolist can set a high input price that would push downstream prices above the unregulated monopoly level. However, if a regulator caps the incumbent’s upstream and downstream prices, consumers and firms are better off after entry than under a price-cap monopoly. We extend our model to examine the concern that price caps may induce incumbents to forgo cost-reducing investments and dampen entrants’ incentives to self-provision the input.

JEL Classification: D43; L13; L50

Corresponding author: Aleksandr Yankelevich, Federal Communications Commission, Washington, D.C., USA, E-mail:

The analysis and conclusions presented here are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of Deloitte, the Federal Communications Commission, or the U.S. Government. The authors acknowledge helpful comments from Janice Beecher, Octavian Carare, Eric Ralph, Marius Schwartz, and Katja Seim, as well as seminar participants at the Federal Communications Commission, International Industrial Organization Conference (2017), Michigan State University, Midwest Economic Theory Conference (Fall 2016), and Southern Economic Conference (2015). Yankelevich has benefited from travel support from the Quello Center at Michigan State University.

The authors dedicate this paper to the memory of Shane Taylor, who along with other FCC staffers with whom both Yankelevich and Nayeem have had the privilege of working, dedicated his career to the difficult and noble work of designing in detail the public policies about which we merely theorize.


Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

Proof. Assume that α E /α I  > β. Arya, Mittendorf, and Sappington (2008) show that entry occurs. Denote the incumbent’s downstream price under duopoly by p I D . Solving the game by backward induction, we find that

p I D = c I + 8 β 2 α I + 2 β α E 2 8 + β 2 .

On the other hand, when the incumbent operates as a monopolist, its downstream price is given by p I M = ( α + c I ) / 2 . Moreover,

p I D p I M = β α E β α I 8 + β 2 > 0 ,

so that the incumbent sets a higher downstream price under duopoly than under monopoly.

  1. Solving the game by backward induction shows that consumer surplus under duopoly is given by

    C S D = 64 23 β 4 5 β 6 α I 2 + 4 α E 2 4 + 5 β 2 4 α I α E 16 β + 3 β 3 β 5 8 1 β 2 8 + β 2 2 .

    On the other hand, consumer surplus under monopoly (and hence under foreclosure) is given by C S M = α I 2 / 8 . Thus, the consumer-welfare gain from entry is

    (17) C S D C S M = α E β α I 4 α E 12 α I β + 5 α E β 2 + 2 α I β 3 + α I β 5 2 1 β 2 8 + β 2 2 .

    Because α E /α I  > β, the sign of CS D  − CS M is the same as that of the second parenthesized expression in the numerator of the term on the right-hand side of Equation (17): 4α E  − 12α I β + 5α E β 2 + 2α I β 3 + α I β 5. For fixed values of α I and β, let φ(⋅; α I , β) denote the function (of α E ) that this expression defines. Note that φ(⋅; α I , β) is continuous and increasing. Furthermore,

    lim α E α I β φ ( α E ; α I , β ) = α E 1 β 2 8 + β 2 < 0 .

    Thus, entry of a relatively inefficient provider decreases consumer surplus relative to the case of monopoly. In particular,

    sign C S D C S M = sign α E α I 12 β 2 β 3 β 5 4 + 5 β 2 .

    Furthermore, when 12 β 2 β 3 β 5 / 4 + 5 β 2 1 (which holds for β > 0.42), CS D  > CS M only if α E  > α I .

  2. Under duopoly, the firms’ equilibrium profits are

    π I D = 8 3 β 2 β 4 α I 2 + 4 α E 2 8 β α I α E 4 1 β 2 8 + β 2 ,

    (18) π E D = 2 + β 2 2 α E β α I 2 1 β 2 8 + β 2 2 .

    Under monopoly, the incumbent’s equilibrium profit is π I M = α I 2 / 4 . The difference in welfare levels between duopoly and monopoly is given by

    (19) W D W M = α E β α I 28 α E 36 α I β + 15 α E β 2 8 α I β 3 + 2 α E β 4 α I β 5 2 1 β 2 8 + β 2 2 .

    Because α E /α I  > β, the sign of W D  − W M is the same as that of the second parenthesized expression in the numerator of the term on the right-hand side of Equation (19): 28α E  − 36α I β + 15α E β 2 − 8α I β 3 + 2α E β 4 − α I β 5. For fixed values of α I and β, let ϕ(⋅; α I , β) denote the function (of α E ) that this expression defines. Note that ϕ(⋅; α I , β) is continuous and increasing. Furthermore,

    lim α E α I β ϕ ( α E ; α I , β ) = α E 1 β 2 8 + β 2 < 0 .

    Thus, entry of a relatively inefficient provider decreases total welfare relative to the case of monopoly. In particular,

    sign W D W M = sign α E α I 36 β + 8 β 3 + β 5 28 + 15 β 2 + 2 β 4 .

    Because 36 β + 8 β 3 + β 5 / 28 + 15 β 2 + 2 β 4 < 1 for all β ∈ (0, 1), entry unambiguously increases total welfare if the entrant is more efficient than the incumbent. □

Proof of Proposition 2

Proof

It is clear from Equation (18) that π E D is increasing in α E . Observe that

π I D α E = 2 α E β α I 1 β 2 8 + β 2 > 0 .

Hence, both firms’ profits increase with α E . Finally, we have

C S α E = 8 α E 16 α I β + 10 α E β 2 3 α I β 3 + α I β 5 2 1 β 2 8 + β 2 2 ,

which implies that

sign C S α E = sign 8 α E 16 α I β + 10 α E β 2 3 α I β 3 + α I β 5 .

For given values of α I and β, let ξ(α E ; α I , β) ≡ 8α E  − 16α I β + 10α E β 2 − 3α I β 3 + α I β 5. Note that ξ(⋅; α I , β) is continuous and increasing in α E , and that

lim α E α I β ξ ( α E ; α I , β ) = α E β 2 + 8 β 2 1 < 0 .

However, ξ(α; α I , β) > 0 for

(20) α E α I > 16 β + 3 β 3 β 5 8 + 10 β 2 .

The expression on the right-hand side of Inequality (20) is strictly increasing in β and bounded above by 1. □

Proof of Proposition 3

Proof

It is clear from Equation (18) that π E D is decreasing in α I . Note that

(21) π I D α I = 4 α E β + α I β 4 + 3 β 2 8 2 β 2 + 8 β 2 1 .

Because the denominator in Equation (21) is negative for β ∈ (0, 1),

sign π I D α I = sign 4 α E β + α I ( β 4 + 3 β 2 8 ) .

Thus, π I D / α I > 0 if and only if

(22) β α E α I < 8 3 β 2 β 4 4 β .

The function of β that is defined by the expression on the right-hand side of Inequality (22) is unbounded above and decreasing in β. It approaches 1 as β approaches 1.

For consumer surplus,

C S D α I = 64 α I 32 α E β 6 α E β 3 23 α I β 4 + 2 α E β 5 5 α I β 6 4 1 β 2 8 + β 2 2 ,

so that

sign C S D α I = sign 64 α I 32 α E β 6 α E β 3 23 α I β 4 + 2 α E β 5 5 α I β 6 .

Therefore, ∂CS D /∂α I  > 0 if and only if

(23) β α E α I < 64 23 β 4 5 β 6 32 β + 6 β 3 2 β 5 .

Just as in Inequality (22), the function of β that is defined by the expression on the right-hand side of Inequality (23) is unbounded above and decreasing and approaches 1 as β approaches 1. □

Proof of Lemma 1

Proof

The proof is by contradiction. Suppose that w < 0. If p I(w) < c I , the incumbent loses money on both upstream sales of the input and downstream sales of the product and can do strictly better by setting w = 0 and p I (w) = c I .

Now assume that p I (w) = c I . Consider a deviation to a higher input price, w′ ∈ (w, 0), while keeping the incumbent’s downstream price fixed. The deviation has three effects:

  1. The incumbent incurs a smaller loss on each inframarginal sale of the input than at w.

  2. The entrant’s marginal cost rises. In response, the entrant raises its downstream price, which lowers the quantity demanded for its product. As a result, the entrant purchases less of the input. This effect further reduces the incumbent’s upstream loss.

  3. The rise in the entrant’s downstream price increases the incumbent’s downstream sales.

The first two effects identified above strictly increase the incumbent’s profit, whereas the third effect does not change the incumbent’s profit. Thus, deviating to w′ is profitable.

Finally, consider the case in which p I (w) > c I , which can hold only if the incumbent does not face a price cap. As in the previous case, consider a deviation to w′ ∈ (w, 0). The three effects identified above also arise here, but the third effect now results in a strict increase in the incumbent’s profit. □

Proof of Lemma 3

Proof

A price-capped incumbent achieves positive downstream sales at input price w if and only if

(24) q I p ̄ I ( w ) , p ̄ E ( w ) > 0 .

In view of Lemma 2, we can substitute c I in for p ̄ I ( w ) into Inequality (24), which can then be rewritten as

(25) α ( 2 + β ) ( 1 β ) + β 2 2 c I + β w + β c E 2 1 β 2 > 0 .

Because 0 < β < 1, Inequality (25) holds if and only if the numerator in the left-hand side term is positive. That condition can be rewritten as

(26) w > α E α I 2 β β .

The result now follows by observing that the expression on the right-hand side of Inequality (26) is negative (and hence Inequality (26) holds for every w ≥ 0) if and only if α E /α I  < 2/β − β. In particular, this latter condition holds whenever α I  > α E , and, for fixed values of α E and α I , it holds for β sufficiently close to zero (i.e. when the retail products are sufficiently differentiated). □

Before we proceed with the proof of Proposition 5, we must establish the following result.

Lemma 4

Let f 1 : [ 0,1 ] R and f 2 : [ 0,1 ] R be two affine functions with f 1(0) < f 2(0) and f 1(1) < f 2(1). Let g : [ 0,1 ) R be a differentiable, convex function that satisfies g(0) < f 1(0) and limt↑1 g(t) > f 2(1). There exist unique numbers t 1, t 2 ∈ (0, 1) that satisfy f 1(t 1) = g(t 1) and f 2(t 2) = g(t 2). Furthermore, t 1 < t 2.

Proof

For each i ∈ {1, 2}, let h i : [ 0,1 ) R be defined by h i  ≡ g − f i . Because f 1(0) > g(0) and limt↑1 f 1(t) = f 1(1) < limt↑1 g(t), we have h 1(0) < 0 < limt↑1 h 1(t). By the Intermediate Value Theorem, there exists at least one t 1 ∈ (0, 1) such that h 1(t 1) = 0. We now prove by contradiction that there exists exactly one such t 1. To this end, suppose that there exist t 1 and t ̃ 1 that satisfy 0 < t 1 < t ̃ 1 < 1 and h 1 ( t 1 ) = h 1 ( t ̃ 1 ) = 0 . By Rolle’s Theorem, there exists t 0 ( t 1 , t ̃ 1 ) such that h 1 ( t 0 ) = 0 . Furthermore, the Mean Value Theorem implies that there exists t* ∈ (0, t 1) such that h 1 ( t * ) = h 1 ( 0 ) / t 1 > 0 = h 1 ( t 0 ) . On the other hand, since f 1 is affine and g is convex, h 1 is nondecreasing on (0,1), which contradicts the finding that h 1 ( t * ) > h 1 ( t 0 ) . Thus, there exists exactly one t 1 ∈ (0, 1) for which h 1(t 1) = 0 (or, equivalently, f 1(t 1) = g(t 1)). An analogous argument shows that there exists exactly one t 2 ∈ (0, 1) that satisfies f 2(t 2) = g(t 2).

It remains to show that t 1 < t 2. First, note that f 1 < f 2. To see why, suppose that there exists t 0 ∈ (0, 1) for which f 1(t 0) ≥ f 2(t 0). Let h ≡ f 1 − f 2. Since h is affine, it is monotonic, which contradicts the fact that max{h(0), h(1)} < 0 ≤ h(t 0). So f 1 < f 2. Now note that g(t 1) = f 1(t 1) < f 2(t 1), and g(t 2) = f 2(t 2), so that h 2(t 1) < 0 = h 2(t 2). By the Mean Value Theorem, there exists t ̄ ( 0 , t 2 ) such that h 2 ( t ̄ ) = h 2 ( 0 ) / t 2 > 0 . By the convexity of h 2, h 2 ( t ) h 2 ( t ̄ ) > 0 for all t [ t ̄ , 1 ) ; that is, h 2 is increasing on [ t ̄ , 1 ] . In particular, h 2(t) ≥ 0 for all t ∈ [t 2, 1]. From h 2(t 1) < 0, it therefore follows that t 1 < t 2. □

Proof of Proposition 5

Proof

Suppose that w*(k) < c I for all k ∈ [0, 1]. Then, if we show that the difference between the derivatives of regulated and unregulated incumbent profits with respect to k, π ̃ I D ( k ) π I D ( k ) is positive when k = 0 and k = 1, then because both π ̃ I D ( k ) and π I D ( k ) are affine functions of k, from Lemma 4, it follows that the unique equilibrium level of k is higher under regulation than without.

(27) π ̃ I D ( 0 ) π I D ( 0 ) = c I α I ( 16 14 β 2 β 4 ) α E β 3 4 ( 8 7 β 2 β 4 ) .

Equation (27) is increasing in c E and α, so that if it is positive for c E  = 0 and the lowest value of α that satisfies our assumptions, then it holds for all c E and α. Note that c E  = 0 implies that Inequality (8) holds, so that foreclosure does not occur. Moreover, Inequality (12) stipulates an infimum for α. Substituting c E  = 0 into Inequality (12) yields the following infimum for α

(28) α = c I ( 2 β ) ( 1 β ) .

Substituting c E  = 0 and Equation (28) into the right-hand side of Equation (27) yields

(29) c I 2 [ 8 + β ( 8 + β ) ] 2 ( 8 7 β 2 β 4 ) > 0 ,

which proves that π ̃ I D ( 0 ) π I D ( 0 ) > 0 when w*(k) < c I .

(30) π ̃ I D ( 1 ) π I D ( 1 ) = c I 4 α I ( 8 7 β 2 β 4 ) α ( 16 14 β 2 3 β 4 ) α E β 3 4 ( 8 7 β 2 β 4 ) .

Equation (30) is also increasing in c E and α, so that we may proceed as above, by substituting c E  = 0 and Equation (28) into the right-hand side of Equation (30). This yields

(31) c I 2 β ( 16 + 16 β + 3 β 3 ) 4 ( 8 7 β 2 β 4 ) > 0 ,

completing the proof for the case of w*(k) < c I for all k ∈ [0, 1].

Now suppose that w*(k) = c I for all k ∈ [0, 1]. The proof of this case is analogous. In particular, the first-order condition analog to Equation (14) in this case is

(32) κ ( k ̄ * ) = π ̄ I D ( k ̄ * ) = c I α I ( 2 β β 2 ) + c E β 2 ( 1 β 2 ) .

It is readily shown that both π ̄ I D ( 0 ) π I D ( 0 ) and π ̄ I D ( 1 ) π I D ( 1 ) are increasing in c E and α. Substituting c E  = 0 and Equation (28) into these expressions yields respectively

(33) c I 2 [ 8 + β ( 8 + β ) ] 2 ( 8 7 β 2 β 4 ) > 0 , c I 2 β ( 8 + 4 β + β 3 ) 2 ( 8 7 β 2 β 4 ) > 0 ,

completing the proof when w*(k) = c I for all k ∈ [0, 1].

Finally, recalling that w*(k) is increasing in k up to c I , suppose that w*(k) binds above some k ̂ ( 0 ,  1 ) , but not below it. From the left-hand side of Inequality (15), recall that π ̃ I D ( k ) is increasing in k, whereas from the right-hand side of Equation (32), it follows that π ̄ I D ( k ) is constant in k, so that the curve consisting of π ̃ I D ( k ) for k [ 0 ,  k ̂ ] and π ̄ I D ( k ) for k ( k ̂ ,  1 ] represents the relevant set of profit derivatives over all possible values of k. But then Inequality (29) and the rightmost inequality in Expression (33) again imply that the unique equilibrium level of k is higher under regulation, completing the proof. □

Proof of Proposition 6

Proof

Here, we complete the proof for the case in which the upstream price binds under price-cap regulation by comparing Z and X, the differences in the entrant’s equilibrium profit assuming w = 0 as opposed to the equilibrium value of w that prevails with and without price-cap regulation, respectively. Like, Y − X, Z − X can be broken down into a quadratic equation that can be plotted over parameter space α E /α I  × β. However, in this case, to make this decomposition tractable, we first define λ ≡ c I /α I . By definition, λ ∈ [0, 1). We can then write,

(34) Z X = 1 D ̄ A ̄ α E α I 2 + B ̄ α E α I + C ̄

where A ̄ = 768 + 896 β 2 64 β 4 64 β 6 , B ̄ = β ( 512 512 β 2 16 β 4 + 24 β 6 8 β 8 ) + λ ( 2048 512 β 2 96 β 4 + 16 β 6 + 2 β 8 ) , C ̄ = β 4 ( 64 52 β 2 16 β 4 + 4 β 6 ) β λ ( 2048 512 β 3 96 β 4 + 16 β 6 + 2 β 8 ) λ 2 ( 1024 256 β 2 48 β 4 + 8 β 6 + β 8 ) , and D ̄ = 4 ( 1 β 2 ) ( 32 4 β 2 β 4 ) 2 . For each λ ∈ [0, 1), we can now plot Equation (34) over parameter space α E /α I  × β, as we do for λ = 0.375 in Figure 7.[29]

Recall that under price-cap regulation, the equilibrium input price binds only if α E α I β / 2 > c I , which may be rewritten as α E /α I  > 2λ + β. Graphically, α E /α I  = 2λ + β forms a line parallel to and above the line denoting the foreclosure condition in Figure 7. Because the equilibrium input price does not bind below the line, only the space above the line is relevant for the comparison in Figure 7. Additionally, by varying λ, it is easy to see that as was the case with Y relative to X, an entrant that is less efficient (downstream) than the incumbent, will never choose to self-provision under regulation if it would not be worthwhile to do so in an equilibrium without price-caps. □

Figure 7: 
As was the case with Y relative to X, when the upstream price binds under price-cap regulation, unless the two firm’s products are close substitutes or the entrant is much more efficient than the incumbent, X > Z.
Figure 7:

As was the case with Y relative to X, when the upstream price binds under price-cap regulation, unless the two firm’s products are close substitutes or the entrant is much more efficient than the incumbent, X > Z.

References

Aguelakakis, N., and A. Yankelevich. 2019. “Collaborate or Consolidate: Assessing the Competitive Effects of Production Joint Ventures.” Economic Inquiry 57: 73–84. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecin.12707.Search in Google Scholar

Armstrong, M., C. Doyle, and J. Vickers. 1996. “The Access Pricing Problem: A Synthesis.” The Journal of Industrial Economics 44: 131–50. https://doi.org/10.2307/2950642.Search in Google Scholar

Arve, M., Ø. Foros, and H. J. Kind. 2022. “Access Price Structure and Entrant Build-or-Buy Incentives in Mobile Markets.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 61 (1): 67–87. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-021-09442-3.Search in Google Scholar

Arya, A., B. Mittendorf, and D. E. M. Sappington. 2008. “Outsourcing, Vertical Integration, and Price vs. Quantity Competition.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 26: 1–16. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2006.10.006.Search in Google Scholar

Bernstein, J. I., and D. E. M. Sappington. 1999. “Setting the X Factor in Price-Cap Regulation Plans.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 16: 5–26. https://doi.org/10.1023/a:1008178112895.10.3386/w6622Search in Google Scholar

Bonanno, G., and J. Vickers. 1988. “Vertical Separation.” The Journal of Industrial Economics 36: 257–65. https://doi.org/10.2307/2098466.Search in Google Scholar

Bouckaert, J., and F. Verboven. 2004. “Price Squeezes in a Regulatory Environment.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 26: 321–51. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-004-7554-3.Search in Google Scholar

Bourreau, M., J. Hombert, J. Pouyet, and N. Schutz. 2011. “Upstream Competition between Vertically Integrated Firms.” The Journal of Industrial Economics 59: 677–713. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6451.2011.00469.x.Search in Google Scholar

Braeutigam, R. R., and J. C. Panzar. 1993. “Effects of the Change from Rate-of-Return to Price-Cap Regulation.” The American Economic Review 83: 191–8.Search in Google Scholar

Canzian, G., G. Mazzarella, F. Verboven, S. Verzillo, and L. Ronchail. 2021. Evaluating the Impact of Price Caps–Evidence from the European Roam-Like-at-Home Regulation. CESifo Working Paper No. 9303. https://www.cesifo.org/en/publications/2021/working-paper/evaluating-impact-price-caps-evidence-european-roam-home-regulation.10.2139/ssrn.3929197Search in Google Scholar

Chang, H., H. Koski, and S. K. Majumdar. 2003. “Regulation and Investment Behaviour in the Telecommunications Sector: Policies and Patterns in US and Europe.” Telecommunications Policy 27: 677–99. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.telpol.2003.08.005.Search in Google Scholar

Chen, Y., and M. Riordan. 2008. “Price-increasing Competition.” The RAND Journal of Economics 39: 1042–58. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1756-2171.2008.00049.x.Search in Google Scholar

Crandall, R. W., A. T. Ingraham, and H. J. Singer. 2004. “Do Unbundling Policies Discourage CLEC Facilities-based Investment.” Topics in Economic Analysis & Policy 4 (1): 1–23, https://doi.org/10.2202/1538-0653.1136.Search in Google Scholar

Fanti, L., and M. Scrimitore. 2019. “How to Compete? Cournot versus Bertrand in a Vertical Structure with an Integrated Input Supplier.” Southern Economic Journal 85 (3): 796–820, https://doi.org/10.1002/soej.12324.Search in Google Scholar

Federal Communications Commission. 1990. “Policy and Rules Concerning Rates for Dominant Carriers.” Second Report and Order in CC Docket No. 87–313. Washington, DC, October 4, 1990.Search in Google Scholar

Federal Communications Commission. 2016. “Business Data Services in an Internet Protocol Environment; Investigation of Certain Price Cap Local Exchange Carrier Business Data Services Tariff Pricing Plans; Special Access for Price Cap Local Exchange Carriers; et al.” Tariff Investigation Order and Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking in WC Docket Nos. 16–143; 15–247; 05–25; et al. Washington, DC, May 2, 2016.Search in Google Scholar

Federal Communications Commission. 2017. “Business Data Services in an Internet Protocol Environment; Technology Transitions; Special Access for Price Cap Local Exchange Carriers; et al.” Report and Order in WC Docket Nos. 16–143; 05–25; et al. Washington, DC, April 28, 2017.Search in Google Scholar

Fershtman, C., and K. L. Judd. 1987. “Equilibrium Incentives in Oligopoly.” American Economic Review 77: 927–40.Search in Google Scholar

Grajec, M., and L. Röller. 2012. “Regulation and Investment in Network Industries: Evidence from European Telecoms.” Journal of Law and Economics 55: 189–216. https://doi.org/10.1086/661196.Search in Google Scholar

Hausman, J. A., and J. G. Sidak. 2005. “Did Mandatory Unbundling Achieve its Purpose? Empirical Evidence from Five Countries.” Journal of Competition Law and Economics 1: 173–245. https://doi.org/10.1093/joclec/nhi005.Search in Google Scholar

Jullien, B., R. Patrick, and C. Saavedra. 2014. The Economics of Margin Squeeze. http://ssrn.com/abstract=2444927.Search in Google Scholar

Koning, K., and A. Yankelevich. 2018. “From Internet ‘Openness’ to ‘Freedom’: How Far Has the Net Neutrality Pendulum Swung?” Utilities Policy 54: 37–45. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jup.2018.07.004.Search in Google Scholar

Kourandi, F., and I. N. Pinopoulos. 2023. “Vertical Contracting between a Vertically Integrated Firm and a Downstream Rival?” Economic Theory: 1–37. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-023-01529-6.Search in Google Scholar

Krämer, J., and D. Schnurr. 2018. “Margin Squeeze Regulation and Infrastructure Competition.” Information Economics and Policy 45: 30–46. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.infoecopol.2018.09.001.Search in Google Scholar

Laffont, J. J., and J. Tirole. 2001. Competition in Telecommunications. Cambridge, MA, USA: MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar

Loertscher, S., and M. Reisinger. 2014. “Market Structure and the Competitive Effects of Vertical Integration.” The RAND Journal of Economics 45: 471–94. https://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12058.Search in Google Scholar

Mandy, D. M., J. W. Mayo, and D. E. M. Sappington. 2016. “Targeting Efforts to Raise Rivals’ Costs: Moving from ‘Whether’ to ‘Whom’.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 46: 1–15. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2016.01.002.Search in Google Scholar

Milliou, C., and E. Petrakis. 2019. “Vertical Integration and Knowledge Disclosure.” Economics Letters 177: 9–13. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2019.01.017.Search in Google Scholar

Moresi, S., and M. Schwartz. 2017. “Strategic Incentives when Supplying to Rivals with an Application to Vertical Firm Structure.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 51: 137–61. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2016.12.005.Search in Google Scholar

Muños-Acevedo, Á., and L. Grzybowski. 2023. “Impact of Roaming Regulation on Revenues and Prices of Mobile Operators in the EU.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 89: 102927. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2023.102927.Search in Google Scholar

Petulowa, M., and C. Saavedra. 2014. Margin Squeeze in a Regulatory Environment: An Application to Differentiated Product Markets. http://ssrn.com/abstract=2236258.10.2139/ssrn.2236258Search in Google Scholar

Quinn, M., M. G. Matos, and C. Peukert. 2022. The Welfare Effects of Mobile Internet Access–Evidence from Roam-Like-at-Home. CESifo Working Paper No. 9612. https://www.cesifo.org/en/publications/2022/working-paper/welfare-effects-mobile-internet-access-evidence-roam-home.10.2139/ssrn.4054117Search in Google Scholar

Reisinger, M., and E. Tarantino. 2015. “Vertical Integration, Foreclosure, and Productive Efficiency.” The RAND Journal of Economics 46: 461–79. https://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12093.Search in Google Scholar

Riordan, M. 1998. “Anticompetitive Vertical Integration by a Dominant Firm.” The American Economic Review 88: 1232–48.Search in Google Scholar

Rysman, M. 2016. Empirics of Business Data Services. White Paper. Appendix B in FCC 2016.Search in Google Scholar

Sappington, D. E. M. 2005. “On the Irrelevance of Input Prices for Make-or-Buy Decisions.” The American Economic Review 95: 1631–8. https://doi.org/10.1257/000282805775014344.Search in Google Scholar

Sappington, D. E. M. 2006. “On the Design of Input Prices: Can TELRIC Prices Ever be Optimal?” Information Economics and Policy 18: 197–215. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.infoecopol.2006.01.002.Search in Google Scholar

Uri, N. D. 1999. Appendix B, the 1999 Staff TFP Study. Available in FCC 1999.Search in Google Scholar

Willig, R. D., W. H. Lehr, J. P. Bigelow, S. B. Levinson. 2002. “Stimulating Investment and the Telecommunications Act of 1996.” Report filed by AT&T in FCC Docket 01–338, October 11, 2002. http://apps.fcc.gov/ecfs/document/view?id=6513295693.Search in Google Scholar


Supplementary Material

This article contains supplementary material (https://doi.org/10.1515/rne-2024-0003).


Received: 2024-01-12
Accepted: 2024-01-15
Published Online: 2024-02-12
Published in Print: 2024-10-26

© 2024 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 24.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/rne-2024-0003/html
Scroll to top button