Abstract
Actors, whether guilty or innocent, may invest in costly measures to reduce their likelihood of being audited. The value of these investments are increasing in the probability with which they expect to be found guilty conditional on being audited. Because strengthening the standard of proof reduces the probability of conviction, it also lowers the investments by actors to reduce their likelihood of being audited. Therefore, when balancing such avoidance costs and deterrence effects, it is optimal to employ a stronger standard than that which maximizes deterrence, namely stronger than preponderance of the evidence.
References
Becker, G. 1968. “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach,” 76 Journal of Political Economy 169–217.10.1086/259394Search in Google Scholar
Dechenaux, E., and A. Samuel. 2014. “Announced vs. Surprise Inspections with Tipping-off,” 34 European Journal of Political Economy 167–183.10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2014.01.001Search in Google Scholar
Demougin, D., and C. Fluet. 2006. “Preponderance of evidence,” 50 (4)European Economic Review 963–976.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2004.11.002Search in Google Scholar
Fluet, C., and M. C. Mungan. 2017. “The Signal-Tuning Function of Liability Regimes,” George Mason University Law and Economics Research Paper No. 17–37.10.2139/ssrn.3028318Search in Google Scholar
Kaplow, Louis. 2011. “On the Optimal Burden of Proof,” 119 (6)Journal of Political Economy 1104–1140.10.3386/w17765Search in Google Scholar
Langlais, E. 2008. “Detection Avoidance and Deterrence: Some Paradoxical Arithmetic,” 10 Journal of Public Economic Theory 371–382.10.1111/j.1467-9779.2008.00367.xSearch in Google Scholar
Malik, A. S. 1990. “Avoidance, Screening and Optimum Enforcement,” 21 RAND Journal of Economics 341–353.10.2307/2555613Search in Google Scholar
Mungan. M. 2011. “A Utilitarian Justification for Heightened Standards of Proof in Criminal Trials,” 167 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 352–370.10.1628/093245611796590030Search in Google Scholar
Mungan, M., and A. Samuel. 2019 “Mimicking, Errors, and the Optimal Standard of Proof,” 174 Economics Letters 18–21.10.1016/j.econlet.2018.10.002Search in Google Scholar
Polinsky, M., and S. Shavell. 2007. “The Theory of Public Enforcement of Law,” in M. Polinsky and S. Shavell, eds. Handbook of Law and Economics 403–454. North Holland: Elsevier.10.1016/S1574-0730(07)01006-7Search in Google Scholar
Rizzolli., M., and M. Saraceno. 2013. “Better that Ten Guilty Persons Escape: Punishment Costs Explain the Standard of Evidence,” 155 Public Choice 395–411.10.1007/s11127-011-9867-ySearch in Google Scholar
Sanchirico, C. W. 2010. “Detection Avoidance and Enforcement Theory: Survey and Assessment,” Institute for Law and Economics Research Paper No. 10–29, University of Pennsylvania Law School.10.2139/ssrn.1705406Search in Google Scholar
Tabbach, A. D. 2010. “The Social Desirability of Punishment Avoidance,” 26 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 265–289.10.1093/jleo/ewp037Search in Google Scholar
© 2020 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston
Articles in the same Issue
- Articles
- Laudatio: Francesco Parisi
- Law and Economics as We Grow Younger
- The Coase Theorem, the Nonempty Core, and the Legal Neutrality Principle
- The Optimal Standard of Proof with Adjudication Avoidance
- Political Insulation, Technical Expertise and the Technocrat’s Paradox
- Thinking Like (Law-And-) Economists – Legal Rules, Economic Prescriptions and Public Perceptions of Fairness
Articles in the same Issue
- Articles
- Laudatio: Francesco Parisi
- Law and Economics as We Grow Younger
- The Coase Theorem, the Nonempty Core, and the Legal Neutrality Principle
- The Optimal Standard of Proof with Adjudication Avoidance
- Political Insulation, Technical Expertise and the Technocrat’s Paradox
- Thinking Like (Law-And-) Economists – Legal Rules, Economic Prescriptions and Public Perceptions of Fairness