Home The Optimal Standard of Proof with Adjudication Avoidance
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

The Optimal Standard of Proof with Adjudication Avoidance

  • Murat C. Mungan EMAIL logo
Published/Copyright: October 17, 2019
Become an author with De Gruyter Brill

Abstract

Actors, whether guilty or innocent, may invest in costly measures to reduce their likelihood of being audited. The value of these investments are increasing in the probability with which they expect to be found guilty conditional on being audited. Because strengthening the standard of proof reduces the probability of conviction, it also lowers the investments by actors to reduce their likelihood of being audited. Therefore, when balancing such avoidance costs and deterrence effects, it is optimal to employ a stronger standard than that which maximizes deterrence, namely stronger than preponderance of the evidence.

JEL Classification: K00; K14; K42

References

Becker, G. 1968. “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach,” 76 Journal of Political Economy 169–217.10.1086/259394Search in Google Scholar

Dechenaux, E., and A. Samuel. 2014. “Announced vs. Surprise Inspections with Tipping-off,” 34 European Journal of Political Economy 167–183.10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2014.01.001Search in Google Scholar

Demougin, D., and C. Fluet. 2006. “Preponderance of evidence,” 50 (4)European Economic Review 963–976.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2004.11.002Search in Google Scholar

Fluet, C., and M. C. Mungan. 2017. “The Signal-Tuning Function of Liability Regimes,” George Mason University Law and Economics Research Paper No. 17–37.10.2139/ssrn.3028318Search in Google Scholar

Kaplow, Louis. 2011. “On the Optimal Burden of Proof,” 119 (6)Journal of Political Economy 1104–1140.10.3386/w17765Search in Google Scholar

Langlais, E. 2008. “Detection Avoidance and Deterrence: Some Paradoxical Arithmetic,” 10 Journal of Public Economic Theory 371–382.10.1111/j.1467-9779.2008.00367.xSearch in Google Scholar

Malik, A. S. 1990. “Avoidance, Screening and Optimum Enforcement,” 21 RAND Journal of Economics 341–353.10.2307/2555613Search in Google Scholar

Mungan. M. 2011. “A Utilitarian Justification for Heightened Standards of Proof in Criminal Trials,” 167 Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 352–370.10.1628/093245611796590030Search in Google Scholar

Mungan, M., and A. Samuel. 2019 “Mimicking, Errors, and the Optimal Standard of Proof,” 174 Economics Letters 18–21.10.1016/j.econlet.2018.10.002Search in Google Scholar

Polinsky, M., and S. Shavell. 2007. “The Theory of Public Enforcement of Law,” in M. Polinsky and S. Shavell, eds. Handbook of Law and Economics 403–454. North Holland: Elsevier.10.1016/S1574-0730(07)01006-7Search in Google Scholar

Rizzolli., M., and M. Saraceno. 2013. “Better that Ten Guilty Persons Escape: Punishment Costs Explain the Standard of Evidence,” 155 Public Choice 395–411.10.1007/s11127-011-9867-ySearch in Google Scholar

Sanchirico, C. W. 2010. “Detection Avoidance and Enforcement Theory: Survey and Assessment,” Institute for Law and Economics Research Paper No. 10–29, University of Pennsylvania Law School.10.2139/ssrn.1705406Search in Google Scholar

Tabbach, A. D. 2010. “The Social Desirability of Punishment Avoidance,” 26 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 265–289.10.1093/jleo/ewp037Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2019-10-17

© 2020 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 15.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/rle-2019-0019/html
Scroll to top button