Startseite Product Market Competition’s Effect on Earnings Management When Audit Quality Is Endogenous: Theory and Evidence
Artikel
Lizenziert
Nicht lizenziert Erfordert eine Authentifizierung

Product Market Competition’s Effect on Earnings Management When Audit Quality Is Endogenous: Theory and Evidence

  • Andrew Samuel und Jeremy Schwartz EMAIL logo
Veröffentlicht/Copyright: 10. April 2019
Veröffentlichen auch Sie bei De Gruyter Brill

Abstract

A long standing question is whether product market competition disciplines a firm’s incentive to engage in earnings management. This paper argues that this question cannot be investigated adequately without accounting for the quality of firms’ auditors, because auditors affect the probability of discovering earnings management. Since firms choose their auditor, a non-compliant firm can alter its own probability of being detected. Consequently, a firm’s decision to manage earnings is a function of its auditor’s quality, which is itself endogenously chosen by the firm. To study this issue we develop a game-theoretic model that captures the potential inter-relationship between industry competition, the firms’ choice of audit quality, and compliance with accounting regulations (or the degree of earnings manipulation). We show that the link between financial compliance and product market competition is affected by the endogenously chosen audit quality. We estimate this model’s structural parameters and find that greater competition reduces both compliance and the demand for high quality audits.

JEL Classification: L13; L15; K42

Acknowledgement

The authors would like to thank conference participants and discussants at the 2018 Center for Legal Theory and Empirical Jurisprudence Meetings, 2017 Canadian Law and Economics Conference, 2017 Public Economic Theory Conference (Paris), and seminar participants at the Judaical Behavior Seminar Series (Catholic University of Leuven), Towson University, and the brown bag workshop at Loyola University, Maryland. We also greatly appreciate Dr. Christoph Engel, Editor, Review of Law & Economics and an anonymous referee for their careful read of our paper and insightful comments. Finally, we acknowledge and are grateful for the generous support of the National Science Foundation (grant number 1626262) as part of the Major Research Instrument initiative that enabled some of the computational work forr this study. All remaining errors are ours.

A Theory Appendix

Proof of Lemma 1

The profit function for firm i is,

(10)πi=qiP+qi(1γi)b+Tai+Bγiaik0γik1γi22gai22

Solving backwards, the first order condition with respect to ai yields,

ai=T+γiBg.

Substituting ai into expression eq. (10), and yields,

qiαβqiβQi+(1γi)b+T+Bγi2g2k0γik1γi22

where Qi is the sum of all firm’s quantities except firm i. The first order condition for γi, equation (3) implies that

γi=TBgk0gk1B2gbgk1B2qi

Since the first order condition for γi eq. (3) is a function only of qi, we substitute eqs. (3) into (2) to derive the Nash equilibrium. Further note that since γi is a function of only qi since firms observe each other’s quantities, they can also infer each others level of compliance (when making their audit decisions in stage 3). Substituting eqs. (3) into (2) yields,

α2βb2ggk1B2δqiβQi+b1TBgk0gkB2C=0
αqiδβQi+C.

Summing N firms FOCs and solving for a symmetric q yields

q=α+Cδ+β(N1),

where π=β(q)2k(γ). Substituting the values for β and C into the expressions for q, γ and π yield the expressions identified in lemma 1.

Assumption 1

A standard Cournot assumption is that α > 0. Thus, when non-compliance generates a competition dependent benefit, i.e. b > 0, then the standard Cournot assumption is sufficient, and assumption 1 is redundant. When non-compliance generates a cost, i.e. b < 0, then Assumption 1 is required to ensure that firms do not shut-down for any value of γi.

Assumption 2

Assumption 2 is introduced in order to ensure that ai[0,1]. The derivative of profits with respect to ai is,

T+γiBgai.

Therefore, a sufficient condition to ensure that a>0 is that T>|B|. To ensure that a<1, at a = 1 we need

g>T+B.

Assumption 3

Assumption 3 ensures that the profit function is quasiconcave in qi and γi and also ensures that γi<1 in equilibrium. Conditions for quasiconcavity require,

2πiqi2=2β

which is negative since β > 0, and

2πiγi2=B2gk1.

is negative if gk1B2>0 which is the first part of Assumption 3.

Next

(2πiqi2)(2πiγi2)(2πiqiγi)2>0
(2β)(B2gk1)b2>0k1>gb2+β2B22gβkˆ

Next to ensure that γi1, we need

k1>(B2+BTk0g)β(1+N)αbgβ(1+N)gk,

which follows directly from the expression for γ. Since BTk0g must be positive for γ>0 and α+b>0 (from assumption 1) it follows that

(B2+BTk0g)β(1+N)+α|b|gβ(1+N)g>k,

regardless of whether b>/<0. The left hand side of the previous inequality is decreasing in N. Thus, if

(11)k1>gα|b|+(B2+BTk0g)2β2βg,

it is satisfied for all N. (That is, since it is decreasing in N if it is satisfied at N = 2 it is satisfied for all N > 2.) Finally, the right hand size of condition eq. (11) is greater than kʹ; that is,

gα|b|+2β(B2+BTk0g)2gβ>gb2+2βB22gβkˆ

Thus,

k1>(B2+BTk0g)β(1+N)+α|b|gβ(1+N)g,

is sufficient to ensure that both γ<1 and that the quasi-concavity assumption is satisfied.

Note that we derive the above sufficient condition so that we can make one assumption to characterize the interior, symmetric, Nash equilibrium of Lemma 1. However, these conditions are not necessary, therefore, are only relevant to our structural estimation if the parameters achieve a corner solution.

Proof of Proposition 1

The first claim in proposition 1, that γ is decreasing in N follows directly from taking the derivative of the expression for γ. Where

dγdN=bgβ(TBk0g)f+(gkB2)(α+b)D2

where D is the denominator of the expression for γ. Note that the term inside the square brackets is the numerator of q which is strictly positive under our assumptions. Thus, compliance is decreasing in N if b < 0. When b > 0, then γ is increasing in N. Without re-deriving the expression for γ, this can be observed directly from the first order condition for γ, equation (3). We know that qi is always decreasing in N. Therefore if b > 0, then when N increases qi decreases and γi increases.

The second claim follows directly from the expression for a. Specifically, a and γ move in the same (opposite) direction with respect to N when B > 0 (< 0).

References

Abbink, K. 2012. “Anti-Corruption Policies; Lessons from the Lab,” in D. Serra and L. Wantchekon, eds. Experimental Economics, 15 ed. Emerald Group Publishing. https://www.emeraldinsight.com/doi/abs/10.1108/S0193-2306%282012% 290000015006.10.2139/ssrn.1971779Suche in Google Scholar

Bagnoli, M., and S. G. Watts. 2010. “Oligopoly, Disclosure, and Earnings Management,” 85 (4)Accounting Review 1191–1214.10.2308/accr.2010.85.4.1191Suche in Google Scholar

Balakrishnan, K., and D. A. Cohen. 2013. “Competition and financial accounting misreporting,” Available at SSRN 1927427.10.2139/ssrn.2447882Suche in Google Scholar

Ball, R. 2007. “Infrastructure Requirements for an Economically Efficient System of Public Financial Reporting and Disclosure,” 2001(1) Brookings-Wharton Papers on Financial Services 127–169.10.1353/pfs.2001.0002Suche in Google Scholar

Becker, C., M. L. DeFond, J. Jiambalvo, and K. Subramanyam. 1998. “The Effect of Audit Quality on Earnings Management,” 15 (1)Contemporary Accounting Research 1–24.10.1111/j.1911-3846.1998.tb00547.xSuche in Google Scholar

Blokdijk, H., F. Drieenhuizen, D. A. Simunic, and M. Stein. 2006. “An Analysis of Cross-Sectional Differences in Big and Non-Big Public Accounting Firms’ Audit Programs,” 25(1) AUDITING: A Journal of Practice & Theory 27–48.10.2308/aud.2006.25.1.27Suche in Google Scholar

Branco, F., and J. M. Villas-Boas. 2015. “Competitive Vices,” 52 (6)Journal of Marketing Research 801–816.10.1509/jmr.13.0051Suche in Google Scholar

Bushman, R. M., B. E. Hendricks, and C. D. Williams. 2014. “The Effect of Bank Competition on Accounting Choices, Operational Decisions and Bank Stability: A Text Based Analysis,” Working Paper (June).10.2139/ssrn.2460371Suche in Google Scholar

Datta, S., M. Iskandar-Datta, and V. Singh. 2013. “Product Market Power, Industry Structure, and Corporate Earnings Management,” 37 (8)Journal of Banking and Finance 3273–3285.10.1016/j.jbankfin.2013.03.012Suche in Google Scholar

DeAngelo, L. E. 1981. “Auditor Size and Audit Quality,” 3 Journal of Accounting and Economics 189–199.10.1016/0165-4101(81)90002-1Suche in Google Scholar

Dechow, P., R. Sloan, and A. Sweeney. 1995. “Detecting Earnings Management,” 70 (2)Accounting Review 193–225.Suche in Google Scholar

DeFond, M. L., and J. Zhang. 2014. “A Review of Archival Auditing Research,” 58 (2–3)Journal of Accounting and Economics 275–326.10.1016/j.jacceco.2014.09.002Suche in Google Scholar

Dye, R. A. 2016. “Auditing Standards, Legal Liability, and Auditor Wealth,” 101 (5)Journal of Political Economy 887–914.10.1086/261908Suche in Google Scholar

Eshleman, J. D., and P. Guo. 2014. “Do Big 4 Auditors Provide Higher Audit Quality after Controlling for the Endogenous Choice of Auditor?” 33 (4)Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory 197–219.10.2308/ajpt-50792Suche in Google Scholar

Fama, E. F. 1980. “Agency Problems and the Theory of the Firm,” 88 (2)Journal of Political Economy 288–307.10.1086/260866Suche in Google Scholar

Francis, J. R., E. Maydew, and H. Sparks. 1999. “The Role of Big 6 Auditors in the Credible Reporting of Accruals,” 18 (2)Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory 17–34.10.2308/aud.1999.18.2.17Suche in Google Scholar

Frankel, R. M., M. F. Johnson, and K. K. Nelson. 2002. “Relation between Auditors’ Fees for Nonaudit Services and Earnings Management,” 77 The Accounting Review 71–105.10.2308/accr.2002.77.s-1.71Suche in Google Scholar

Holmstrom, B. 1982. “Moral Hazard in Teams,” 13 (2)The Bell Journal of Economics 324.10.2307/3003457Suche in Google Scholar

Hvide, H. K. 2009. “Oligopolistic Certification,” 9 (1)The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics 1–21.10.2202/1935-1704.1230Suche in Google Scholar

Jensen, M. C., and W. H. Meckling. 1976. “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure,” 3 Journal of Financial Economics 305–360.10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-XSuche in Google Scholar

Jiang, J. X., I. Y. Wang, and K. P. Wang. 2019. “Big N Auditors and Audit Quality: New Evidence from Quasi-Experiments,” 94 (1)The Accounting Review 205–227.10.2308/accr-52106Suche in Google Scholar

Jones, J. 1991. “Earnings Management During Import Relief Investigations,” 29 (2)Journal of Accounting Research 193–228.10.2307/2491047Suche in Google Scholar

Karuna, C., K. R. Subramanyam, and F. Tian. 2015. “Competition and Earnings Management,” (213) Working Paper 49.Suche in Google Scholar

Karuna, C., K. R. Subramanyam, and F. Tian. 2011. “Industry Product Market Competition and Earnings Management,” Annual Meeting of American Accounting Association.Suche in Google Scholar

Kedia, S., and T. Philippon. 2009. “The Economics of Fraudulent Accounting,” 22 (6)Review of Financial Studies 2169–2199.10.1093/rfs/hhm016Suche in Google Scholar

Kellogg, R. L. 1984. “Accountant’s Activities, Security Prices, and Class Action Law Suits,” 6 (3)Journal of Accounting & Economics 185–2024.10.1016/0165-4101(84)90024-7Suche in Google Scholar

Knechel, W. R., L. Niemi, and S. Sundgren. 2008. “Determinants of Auditor Choice: Evidence from a Small Client Market.” 12 (March)International Journal of Auditing 65–88.10.1111/j.1099-1123.2008.00370.xSuche in Google Scholar

Kothari, S. P., A. J. Leone, and C. E. Wasley. 2005. “Performance Matched Discretionary Accrual Measures,” 39 (1)Journal of Accounting & Economics 163–197.10.1016/j.jacceco.2004.11.002Suche in Google Scholar

Krishnan, G. V. 2003. “Does Big 6 Auditor Industry Expertise Constrain Earnings Management?” 17 (February)Accounting Horizons 1–16.10.2308/acch.2003.17.s-1.1Suche in Google Scholar

Mansi, S. A., W. F. Maxwell, and D. P. Miller. 2004. “Does Auditor Quality and Tenure Matter to Investors? Evidence from the Bond Market,” 42 (4)Journal of Accounting Research 755–793.10.1111/j.1475-679X.2004.00156.xSuche in Google Scholar

Marciukaityte, D., and J. C. Park. 2009. “Market competition and earnings management,” Available at SSRN 1361905.10.2139/ssrn.1361905Suche in Google Scholar

Markarian, G., and J. Santalo. 2014. “Product Market Competition, Information and Earnings Management,” 41 (5–6)Journal of Business Finance & Accounting 507–790.10.1111/jbfa.12064Suche in Google Scholar

Mendez, F. 2014. “Can Corruption Foster Regulatory Compliance,” 158 (1–2)Public Choice 189–207.10.1007/s11127-012-9958-4Suche in Google Scholar

Mookherjee, D., and I. P. L. Png. 1995. “Corruptible Law Enforcers: How Should They be Compensated,” 105 (428)Economic Jounral 145–159.10.2307/2235324Suche in Google Scholar

Nalebuff, B. J., and J. E. Stiglitz. 1983. “Prizes and Incentives: Towards a General Theory of Compensation and Competition,” 14 (1)The Bell Journal of Economics 21–43.10.2307/3003535Suche in Google Scholar

Palmrose, Z.-V., V. J. Richardson, and S. Scholz. 2004. “Determinants of Market Reactions to Restatement Announcements,” 37 Journal of Accounting & Economics 59–89.10.1016/j.jacceco.2003.06.003Suche in Google Scholar

Polinsky, A. M., and S. Shavell. 2001. “Corruption and Optimal Law Enforcement,” 81(1) Journal of Public Economics 1–24.10.1016/S0047-2727(00)00127-4Suche in Google Scholar

Press, E. G., and J. B. Weintrop. 1990. “Accounting-Based Constraints in Public and Private Debt Agreements. Their Association with Leverage and Impact on Accounting Choice,” 12 Journal of Accounting & Economics Economics 65–95.10.1016/0165-4101(90)90042-3Suche in Google Scholar

Samuel, A. 2009. “Preemptive Collusion among Corruptible Law Enforcers,” 71 (2)Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 441–450.10.1016/j.jebo.2009.04.013Suche in Google Scholar

Shleifer, A. 2004. “Does Competition Destroy Ethical Behavior?” 94 (2)American Economic Review 414–418.10.1257/0002828041301498Suche in Google Scholar

Singer, Z., and J. Zhang. 2018. “Auditor Tenure and the Timeliness of Misstatement Discovery,” 93 (2)The Accounting Review 315–338.10.2308/accr-51871Suche in Google Scholar

Stein, J. C. 2006. “Efficient Capital Markets, Inefficient Firms: A Model of Myopic Corporate Behavior,” 104 (4)The Quarterly Journal of Economics 655.10.2307/2937861Suche in Google Scholar

Stice, J. D. 1991. “Using Financial and Market Information to Identify Pre-Engagement Factors Associated with Lawsuits against Auditors,” 66 (3)The Accounting Review 516–533.Suche in Google Scholar

Wallace, W. 1987. “The Economic Role of the Audit in Free and Regulated Markets: A Review,” 1 Research in Accounting Regulation 1–34.Suche in Google Scholar

Watts, R. L., and J. L. Zimmerman. 1981. “The Markets for Independence and Independent Auditors.”Suche in Google Scholar

Watts, R. L., and J. L. Zimmerman. 1986. “Positive Accounting Theory,”Suche in Google Scholar

Xue, S., and S. Tinaikar. 2009. “Product Market Competition and Earnings Management: Some International Evidence.” Rutgers Business School 20th Anniversary Conference on Financial Economics and Accounting 1–51.10.2139/ssrn.1466319Suche in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2019-04-10

© 2019 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Heruntergeladen am 29.9.2025 von https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/rle-2018-0044/html
Button zum nach oben scrollen