Abstract
In real life, winning a conflict sometimes does not end the conflict. Revenge motivations can stay and provide momentum to the conflict, thus leading to further escalation of the conflict. This is known as the value effect or vengeance effect of revenge. However, the presence of revenge can lead to de-escalation of the conflict out of self-deterrence and sometimes retaliation out of revenge is not possible if the combatant is incapacitated. Hence, the impact of revenge on the level of violence is a priori not clear. This paper is an attempt to answer that question. Using a two-period game of conflict this paper tries to show how desire and capabilities of the combatants to exact revenge can influence the intensity of the conflict. This paper shows the following: how the strategies of the combatants are influenced by the value effect of revenge, self-deterrence and incapacitation of the combatants; how the stronger combatant is in a favourable position in the conflict and can prevent its opponent from going into second period conflict out of revenge; when the combatants are equally strong the intensity of the conflict starts falling with time. It also lays out some real-life conflicts and existing empirical work to support the results.
Appendix A: When Desire for Revenge is Sensitive to the Destruction Suffered in the Previous Period
In this framework the revenge-capability function becomes,
The revenge-capability function can be written in the following way (considering the revenge-capability function of combatant A);
Like before when
The
If the desire for revenge is more sensitive to the destruction suffered in the previous period that is ϕ > 1 then the
The less the sensitivity (ϕ < 1), the lower the R P point and thus the incapacitation to level where it would have less incentive to retaliate is less.
If the sensitivity to previous destruction is low such that both the combatants can reach its opponent’s revenge peak point then from Proposition 5 we know that the intensity of the conflict falls with time. Thus, when the elasticity is low, the urge to go into second period conflict out of revenge depends mostly on the capability factor and otherwise when the sensitivity is high.
Appendix B: Proof of Proposition 1
We have to check for the second term in equation (31), since the first term is negative, as shown.
The second part of the equation can be written as:
Further simplifying the equations;
Let
Appendix C: Proof of Proposition 2
First period FOCs of the combatants can be written in the following way:
We can write (36) in the following way:
When xA1 = xB1 LHS = RHS of equation (37).
Total conflict X R is;
Appendix D: Proof of Proposition 3
In the benchmark case of no revenge, the payoffs are as follows:
The payoffs of A and B in the presence of revenge are as follows:
Comparing these with the payoffs in the benchmark case of no revenge, we get:
From equation (44) it is evident that if the first period equilibrium conflict investment of A is relatively very high from the first period conflict investment of B then the payoff of A is more in the presence of revenge. However, if the equilibrium conflict investment of B is relatively very high than that of A then payoff of A will be lower in the presence of revenge than without revenge. This shows if the B has incapacitated A to a high level in the first period conflict then A will not want to go into a second period conflict out of revenge. The comparison is similar for that of B.
When the capabilities of the combatants is similar we already know from Proposition 2 that the first period conflict investments of the combatants are equal and thus equation (44) becomes;
From Proposition 2 we know the value of
Now, putting this value of
When
If
Now, let us calculate the value of the first period conflict investment in the symmetric case when the combatants would be (better-off) worse-off in the presence of revenge.
Since this is a symmetric case and the equilibrium payoff of A equals that of B so re-writing (47) in terms of i where i = A, B and putting the value of
From equation (50), it is evident that when
Appendix E: Simplification of equation (25)
We can write equation (20) in the following way;
We know from the formulation of the revenge function that
References
Amegashie, A., and M. Runkel. 2012. “The Paradox of Revenge in Conflicts.” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 56 (2): 313–30. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022002711420971.Search in Google Scholar
Anderton, C. H., and J. R. Carter. 2009. Principles of Conflict Economics: A Primer for Social Scientists. New York, USA: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511813474Search in Google Scholar
Azam, J. P. 1995. “How to Pay for the Peace? A Theoretical Framework with References to African Countries.” Public Choice 83 (1–2): 173–84. https://doi.org/10.1007/bf01047691.Search in Google Scholar
Blattman, C. 2023. Why We Fight: The Roots of War and the Paths to Peace. UK: Penguin.Search in Google Scholar
Bolle, F., J. H. Tan, and D. J. Zizzo. 2014. “Vendettas.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 6 (2): 93–130. https://doi.org/10.1257/mic.6.2.93.Search in Google Scholar
Caruso, R. 2006. “Conflict and Conflict Management with Interdependent Instruments and Asymmetric Stakes, (The Good-Cop and the Bad-Cop Game).” Peace Economics, Peace Science and Public Policy 12 (1): 1–53, https://doi.org/10.2202/1554-8597.1091.Search in Google Scholar
Caruso, R. 2007. “Reciprocity in the Shadow of Threats.” International Review of Economics 55: 91–111. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-007-0029-y.Search in Google Scholar
Caruso, R., and J. Echevarria-Coco. 2022. “International Prices and Continuing Conflict: Theory and Evidence from Sub-saharan Africa (1980–2017).” Journal of Peace Research 60 (6): 889–905, https://doi.org/10.1177/00223433221116657.Search in Google Scholar
Chagnon, N. A. 1988. “Life Histories, Blood Revenge, and Warfare in a Tribal Population.” Science 239 (4843): 985–92. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.239.4843.9.Search in Google Scholar
Chen, J., and K. Siqueira. 2022. “The Presence of Revenge in Conflict and the Possibility of Complete Deterrence.” Defence and Peace Economics 33 (7): 805–17. https://doi.org/10.1080/10242694.2021.1873085.Search in Google Scholar
Chowdhury, S. M., and O. Gürtler. 2015. “Sabotage in Contests: A Survey.” Public Choice 164: 135–55. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2338077.Search in Google Scholar
Chowdhury, S. M., D. Kovenock, D. Rojo Arjona, and N. T. Wilcox. 2020. “Focality and Asymmetry in Multi-Battle Contests.” The Economic Journal 131 (636): 1593–619, https://doi.org/10.1093/ej/ueaa130.Search in Google Scholar
Chowdhury, S. M., and R. M. Sheremeta. 2011. “A Generalized Tullock Contest.” Public Choice 147: 413–20. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1755604.Search in Google Scholar
Dixit, A. 1987. “Strategic Behaviour in Contests.” The American Economic Review 77 (5): 891–8.Search in Google Scholar
Fearon, J. D. 1995. “Rationalist Explanations for War.” International Organization 49 (3): 379–414. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0020818300033324.Search in Google Scholar
Garfinkel, M. R., and S. Skaperdas. 2007. “Economics of Conflict: An Overview.” In Handbook of Defense Economics, 2, edited by T. Sandler, and K. Hartley, 649–709. Netherlands: North-Holland.10.1016/S1574-0013(06)02022-9Search in Google Scholar
Huth, P., and B. Russett. 1984. “What Makes Deterrence Work? Cases from 1900 to 1980.” World Politics 36 (4): 496–526. https://doi.org/10.2307/2010184.Search in Google Scholar
Huth, P., and B. Russett. 1988. “Deterrence Failure and Crisis Escalation.” International Studies Quarterly 32 (1): 29–45. https://doi.org/10.2307/2600411.Search in Google Scholar
Jaeger, D. A, and M. D. Paserman. 2008. “The Cycle of Violence? an Empirical Analysis of Fatalities in the Palestinian–Israel Conflict.” The American Economic Review 98 (4): 1591–604. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.98.4.1591.Search in Google Scholar
Jennings, C. 2016. “Group Support for Political Violence: The Role of Emotions and Expressive Choice in Creating Conflict or Providing Peace.” Defence and Peace Economics 27 (3): 404–22. https://doi.org/10.1080/10242694.2014.996005.Search in Google Scholar
Kreps, D. M., P. Milgrom, J. Roberts, and R. Wilson. 1982. “Rational Cooperation in the Finitely Repeated Prisoners’ Dilemma.” Journal of Economic Theory 27 (2): 245–52. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(82)90029-1.Search in Google Scholar
Kuznets, S. 1955. “Economic Growth and Income Inequality.” The American Economic Review 45 (1): 1–28.Search in Google Scholar
Liang, L., J. Chen, and K. Siquiera. 2020. “Revenge or Continued Attack and Defense in Defender–Attacker Conflicts.” European Journal of Operational Research 287: 1180–90. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2020.05.026.Search in Google Scholar
Löwenheim, O., and G. Heimann. 2008. “Revenge in International Politics.” Security Studies 17 (4): 685–724. https://doi.org/10.1080/09636410802508055.Search in Google Scholar
Mohammad, F., A. R. Thomas, and I. Tabassum. 2016. “Honor, Revenge in Socio-Geographic Space of Pashtuns.” Pakistan Journal of Criminology 8 (3): 74.Search in Google Scholar
Mukherjee, P., and S. Munshi. 2022. “Conflict with Third-Party Intervention and Revenge: A Game-Theoretic Exploration.” Defence and Peace Economics 34 (6): 767–90. https://doi.org/10.1080/10242694.2022.2065187.Search in Google Scholar
Munshi, S. 2020. “Violence Amidst Virus: A Game Theoretic Exploration of Conflict during a Pandemic.” Theoretical Economics Letters 10: 1292–306. https://doi.org/10.4236/tel.2020.106079.Search in Google Scholar
Organski, A. F. K., and J. Kugler. 1980. The War Ledger. US: The University of Chicago Press.10.7208/chicago/9780226351841.001.0001Search in Google Scholar
Rehman, F. U., M. Nasir, and M. Shahbaz. 2017. “What Have We Learned? Assessing the Effectiveness of Counterterrorism Strategies in Pakistan.” Economic Modelling 64: 487–95. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2017.02.028.Search in Google Scholar
Schelling, T. C. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Search in Google Scholar
Skaperdas, S. 1992. “Cooperation, Conflict, and Power in the Absence of Property Rights.” The American Economic Review 82 (4): 720–39.Search in Google Scholar
Tullock, G. 1980. “Efficient Rent Seeking.” In Toward A Theory of Rent Seeking Society, edited by J. Buchanan, R. Tollison, and G. Tullock, 97–112. College Station: A&M University Press.Search in Google Scholar
© 2024 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Research Articles
- Conflict Under Incapacitation and Revenge: A Game-Theoretic Exploration
- Group Grievances, Opportunity, and the Onset of Civil War: Some Theory and Tests of Competing Mechanisms, 1990–2017
- The Military Expenditure – Economic Growth Nexus Revisited: Evidence from the United Kingdom
- Why Americans Support Strict Counterterrorism Measures: Examining the Relationship between Concern about Terrorism and Public Support for Counterterrorism
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Research Articles
- Conflict Under Incapacitation and Revenge: A Game-Theoretic Exploration
- Group Grievances, Opportunity, and the Onset of Civil War: Some Theory and Tests of Competing Mechanisms, 1990–2017
- The Military Expenditure – Economic Growth Nexus Revisited: Evidence from the United Kingdom
- Why Americans Support Strict Counterterrorism Measures: Examining the Relationship between Concern about Terrorism and Public Support for Counterterrorism