Startseite Management Turnover, Strategic Ambiguity and Supply Incentives
Artikel
Lizenziert
Nicht lizenziert Erfordert eine Authentifizierung

Management Turnover, Strategic Ambiguity and Supply Incentives

  • Nicolas Pasquier ORCID logo EMAIL logo und Pascal Toquebeuf
Veröffentlicht/Copyright: 23. Februar 2022

Abstract

When a firm appoints a new manager, it reopens the possibility of new contractual friction with its partners. We explore strategic ambiguity as a potential for friction with a supplier. The firm’s new manager probably has fuzzy expectations about the supplier’s strategy. An optimistic manager weights favorable strategies more heavily than detrimental ones, whereas a pessimistic manager does the opposite. We show that the manager’s degree of optimism is critical: above a threshold, it can cause the supplier to change the timing of its contracting and increase its profits. We also find that this threshold degree of optimism depends on the degree of product substitution: it is more stringent with imperfect substitutes than with perfect substitutes or unrelated goods.

JEL Classification: L14; L22; D8

Corresponding author: Nicolas Pasquier, Université Grenoble Alpes, CNRS, INRA, Grenoble INP, GAEL, 38000 Grenoble, France: and Department of Economics/NIPE, University of Minho, Campus de Gualtar, 4710-057 Braga, Portugal, E-mail:

Acknowledgements

We thank Ani Guerdjikova for insightful comments on a previous draft.

  1. Research funding: None declared.

  2. Conflict of interest statement: The authors declare that there is no conflict of interest.

  3. Author contribution: All the authors have accepted responsibility for the entire content of this submitted manuscript and approved submission.

Appendix A: Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium

A.1 SPNE without Ambiguity

We look for the symmetric SPNE where the two firms accept their contracts. By backward induction, we find that firms accept contracts whenever their profit is positive: π i (c) = (1 − q i γq j )q i f i . This happens whenever f i ≤ (1 − q i γq j )q i , for all i ∈ {1, 2}. At the contracting stage, the monopolist anticipates this decision, and sets each fixed so as to capture all the firms’ rents because its profit, π U = f i + f j , is increasing in f i . In addition, since we focus on the symmetric equilibrium, we have f i = f j = f and thus q i = q j = q/2 which leads to f = (1 − (q/2) − γ(q/2))(q/2) = (1 − (1 + γ)(q/2))(q/2). The monopolist then maximizes its profit π U = (1 − (1 + γ)(q/2))q. The First Order Condition gives dπ U /dq = 1 − (1 + γ)q = 0 and therefore: q i = q j = 1/[2(1 + γ)].

Substituting these values into the fixed fees, we have f i = f j = 1/[4(1 + γ)] which directly gives the monopolist’s profit π U = 1/[2(1 + γ)]. Symmetrically, the consumer surplus can be rewritten as: CS = (1 + γ)q 2 which gives CS = 1/[4(1 + γ)].□

A.2 SPNE with Strategic Ambiguity and Sequential Contracting

We look for the SPNE in pure strategies of the game and thus solve the game using backward induction. We now refer to the new manager and D 1 as the same entity to ease the explanation and notations. For the same reason we also do not write the history of strategies as functions of the history of past strategies.

When D 2 observes its offer, it also observes the previous contract offer and D 1’s decision. D 2 accepts the contract whenever its profit is positive. Formally, this means:

a 2 * ( c 2 , a 1 , c 1 ) = 1 if π 2 ( a 2 = 1 | c , a 1 ) 0 0 otherwise

where π 2(a 2 = 1|c, a 1) = (1 − q 2γa 1 q 1)q 2f 2. We focus on equilibria where the firms accept their offers, which means that the monopolist’s offer to D 2 must satisfy f 2 ≤ (1 − q 2γa 1 q 1)q 2.

When the monopolist makes the offer to D 2, it anticipates D 2’s decision, given its own previous decision and that of D 1. The monopolist thus maximizes π U = f 1 + f 2 where f 2 ≤ (1 − q 2γa 1 q 1)q 2 and f 1 is sunk (because already paid by D 1 at this stage). The profit is increasing in f 2 so the monopolist extracts all the rent and the profit rewrites π U = (1 − q 2γa 1 q 1)q 2. The monopolist maximizes this profit for any contract offer ( q 2 * ( a 1 , c 1 ) , f 2 * ( a 1 , c 1 ) ) such that

q 2 * ( c 1 , a 1 ) = 1 γ a 1 q 1 2 and f 2 * ( c 1 , a 1 ) = ( 1 γ a 1 q 1 ) 2 4

where q 2 * ( c 1 , a 1 ) is simply the Cournot best response to a 1 q 1.

When D 1 gets its offer c 1, it has to anticipate the other firms’ future decisions. This anticipation is critical. D 1 perfectly anticipates D 2’s decision, a 2 * . However, since D 1 is ambiguous towards the monopolist’s decision, it weighs up the best and worst outcome induced by all the strategies available to the monopolist at the next stage, c 2 C 2 .

More formally, and by applying Eq. (6), the result is that D 1’s expected profit from accepting the offer is E c 2 π 1 a 1 = 1 , c 2 , a 2 * | c 1 = ( 1 α ) max c 2 C 2 π 1 a 1 = 1 , c 2 , a 2 * | c 1 + α min c 2 C 2 π 1 a 1 = 1 , c 2 , a 2 * | c 1 . D 1 accepts whenever its expected profit is positive and we now formally get:

a 1 * ( c 1 ) = 1 if E c 2 π 1 a 1 = 1 , c 2 , a 2 * | c 1 0 0 otherwise

where the expected profit simplifies to E c 2 π 1 a 1 = 1 , c 2 , a 2 * | c 1 = ( 1 α ) ( 1 q 1 ) q 1 + α ( 1 γ q 1 ) q 1 f 1 if q 1 ≤ 1 − γ and E c 2 π 1 a 1 = 1 , c 2 , a 2 * | c 1 = ( 1 α ) ( 1 q 1 ) q 1 + 0 f 1 when q 1 ≥ 1 − γ.

Lemma 1

Upon acceptance, the worst outcome expected by the new manager of firm D 1 depends on the monopolist’s offer q 1 and product differentiation in the following way: if q 1 ≥ 1 − γ then min c 2 C 2 π 1 a 1 = 1 , c 2 , a 2 * | c 1 = 0 f 1 , and if q 1 ≤ 1 − γ then min c 2 C 2 π 1 a 1 = 1 , c 2 , a 2 * | c 1 = ( 1 q 1 ) q 1 f 1 .

Intuitively, given contract offer c 1 = (q 1, f 1), the best outcome appears in the event where the monopolist offers nothing to D 2, q 2 = 0, and requests nothing from them (so that D 2 accepts this contract). The worst outcome appears in the scenario where the monopolist offers the maximum quantity to D 2, i.e. q 2 = 1, which potentially drives the market price to zero, and requests nothing in exchange for such a quantity (so that again D 2 accepts). Under imperfect substitution, even if the monopolist gives the maximal quantity to the rival q 2 = 1, but provides a sufficiently low quantity to D 1, q 1 ≤ 1 − γ, the latter can expect at worst a positive market price and hence positive profits.

We focus on equilibria where the firms accept the contract, so the monopolist’s offer to D 1 must satisfy f 1 ≤ (1 − α)(1 − q 1)q 1 + α max{(1 − γq 1)q 1, 0}. When the monopolist decides on the offer for D 1, it anticipates the other firms’ strategies. The monopolist thus maximizes π U = f 1 + f 2 where f 2 ( 1 γ q 1 ) 2 4 and f 1 ≤ (1 − α)(1 − q 1)q 1 + α max{(1 − γq 1)q 1, 0}. The profit is increasing in the fees so, for a given level of pessimism α, the monopolist extracts all the rent.

A.2.1 Perfect Substitutes

SPNE with perfect substitutes and strategic ambiguity is characterized by Eq. (8).

At the time the monopolist enters into a contract with the first firm, it maximizes (remind γ = 1 in this case):

π U = ( 1 α ) ( 1 q 1 ) q 1 + 1 q 1 2 2 .

The first order condition and the second order condition gives respectively:

(13) π U q 1 = 0 ( 1 2 α ) ( 3 4 α ) q 1 = 0

(14) 2 π U 2 q 1 0 ( 1 α ) ( 2 ) + ( 1 / 2 ) 0

The FOC is satisfied when evaluated at q 1(α) = (1 − 2α)/(3 − 4α).

When 0 ≤ α ≤ 1/2, both Eqs. (13) and (14) hold. Therefore, q 1(α) = (1 − 2α)/(3 − 4α) ≥ 0 is a maximum. We then obtain that q 1 T ( α ) = ( 1 2 α ) / ( 3 4 α ) and f 1 T = ( 1 α ) ( 1 q 1 T ) q 1 T = 2 ( 1 α ) 2 ( 1 2 α ) / ( 3 4 α ) 2 when 0 ≤ α ≤ 1/2.

When α > 1/2, the SOC becomes positive (Eq. (14)). On the one hand, when 3/4 > α > 1/2, (∂π U /∂q 1) is negative. Therefore, the profit is decreasing on q 1 ∈ [0, 1] and we find that the maximum actually lies at q 1 = 0 in that case. On the other hand, when α > 3/4 > 1/2, (∂π U /∂q 1) is negative until q 1(α) = (1 − 2α)/(3 − 4α) ≥ 0 and positive above that. This time q 1(α) = (1 − 2α)/(3 − 4α) is thus a minimum. By computing the profit value at the extreme of the interval, we find that π U (1) = 0 and π U (0) = 1/4. Therefore, the maximum profit is again reached at q 1 = 0. To sum up, when α > 1/2, the maximum is reached at q 1 = 0. We then obtain that q 1 T ( α ) = 0 and f 1 T = 0 when α > 1/2.

Finally, q 2 T ( α ) is obtained by implementing the value of q 1 into the Cournot best response function of D 2, q 2 T ( α ) = [ 1 q 1 ( α ) ] / 2 = ( 1 α ) / ( 3 4 α ) if α < 1/2, and 1/2 otherwise. Similarly, the corresponding fixed fee f 2 T ( α ) is such that f 2 T ( α ) = ( 1 q 1 ) 2 / 4 = ( 1 α ) 2 / ( 3 4 α ) 2 when α < 1/2, and 1/4 otherwise.□

A.2.2 Imperfect Substitutes

At the time the monopolist enters into contract with the first firm, it maximizes

π U = 1 γ q 1 2 2 + ( 1 α ) ( 1 q 1 ) q 1 + α max { ( 1 γ q 1 ) q 1 , 0 }

We have two cases to consider, depending on if q 1 ≤ 1 − γ or q 1 ≥ 1 − γ.

Case 1. q 1 ≤ 1 − γ.

We have max{(1 − γq 1)q 1, 0} = (1 − γq 1)q 1, and the first order condition and the second order condition respectively are:

(15) π U q 1 = 0 1 2 ( 2 α + 1 ) γ + γ 2 4 q 1 + 2 = 0

(16) 2 π U 2 q 1 0 1 2 γ 2 4 0

The FOC is satisfied when evaluated at q 1 ( α , γ ) = 2 γ ( 1 + 2 α ) 4 γ 2 . Let us suppose q 1 L ( α , γ ) 2 γ ( 1 + 2 α ) 4 γ 2 . Equation (16) holds whenever (α, γ) ∈ [0,1]2. Therefore, q 1 L ( α , γ ) is always a maximum for π U . When α α ̄ ̄ ( γ ) 1 γ 1 2 , we have q 1 L ( α , γ ) 0 . q 1 L ( α , γ ) is thus the maximum in this region. When α > α ̄ ̄ ( γ ) 1 γ 1 2 , we find q 1 L ( α , γ ) < 0 . Since a quantity must be positive, the maximum on this region is 0. Last, q 1(α, γ) ≤ 1 − γ is satisfied as long as α 1 2 γ 2 + γ 2 γ + 3 and henceforth q 1(α, γ) = 1 − γ is the maximum on the region where α > 1 2 γ 2 + γ 2 γ + 3 . Figure 4 summarizes our findings. The red line refers to α ̄ ̄ ( γ ) and the blue line refers to 1 2 γ 2 + γ 2 γ + 3 .

Figure 4: 
The solution for q
1 < 1 − γ.
Figure 4:

The solution for q 1 < 1 − γ.

Case 2. q 1 ≥ 1 − γ.

We have max{(1 − γq 1)q 1, 0} = 0, and the first order condition and the second order condition respectively are:

(17) π U q 1 = 0 1 2 2 α γ + q 1 4 α + γ 2 4 + 2 = 0

(18) 2 π U 2 q 1 0 1 2 4 α + γ 2 4 0

The FOC is satisfied when evaluated at q 1 ( α , γ ) = 2 ( 1 α ) γ 4 ( 1 α ) γ 2 . Let us suppose q 1 H ( α , γ ) 2 ( 1 α ) γ 4 ( 1 α ) γ 2 . Equation (18) holds whenever γ ∈ [0, 1] and 0 α 1 4 4 γ 2 . Therefore, q 1 H ( α , γ ) is a maximum for π U when 0 < γ < 1 and 0 α 1 4 4 γ 2 , and a minimum otherwise. When 0 α 1 4 4 γ 2 , we find q 1 H ( α , γ ) 1 γ only if α ( γ 2 ) γ 2 + γ 1 2 4 γ . It implies that (i) q 1 H ( α , γ ) is the maximum in the area where α ( γ 2 ) γ 2 + γ 1 2 4 γ and (ii) q 1(α, γ) = 1 − γ is the maximum in the area where ( γ 2 ) γ 2 + γ 1 2 4 γ < α < 1 4 4 γ 2 . When α > 1 4 4 γ 2 , q 1 H ( α , γ ) is a minimum, we find that the value is higher than 1 − γ meaning that the maximum on this part is either in q 1(α, γ) = 1 or q 1(α, γ) = 1 − γ. It can be shown that the profit at q 1(α, γ) = 1 − γ is higher than that at q 1(α, γ) = 1 so that q 1(α, γ) = 1 − γ is the maximum on this area. Figure 5 summarizes our findings. The black line refers to (1/4)(4 − γ 2) and the blue line refers to ( γ 2 ) γ 2 + γ 1 2 4 γ .

Figure 5: 
The solution for q
1 ≥ 1 − γ.
Figure 5:

The solution for q 1 ≥ 1 − γ.

We now derive the best solution for the monopolist in each region.

A.3 Maximum Profit at Optimum Solutions

Let us denote by π U L the profit function when q 1 ≤ 1 − γ and π U H the profit function when q 1 ≥ 1 − γ. Note that the profits are the same at q 1 = 1 − γ. Several cases arise:

  1. In the area where α 1 2 γ 2 + γ 2 γ + 3 , i.e. below the blue line of Figure 4, we find that

π U L ( 1 γ ) π U H ( 1 γ ) = 0 π U L ( 1 γ ) π U H q 1 H

Therefore, q 1 H is the solution in this region.

  1. In the area where 1 2 γ 2 + γ 2 γ + 3 < α < ( γ 2 ) γ 2 + γ 1 2 4 γ , i.e. between the blue lines of Figures 4 and 5, we find that

π U L q 1 L π U H q 1 H = 2 ( 1 α γ ) + α ( α + 1 ) γ 2 γ 4 γ 2 ( 1 α ) ( 2 α γ ) 4 ( 1 α ) γ 2

This is positive whenever α > α ̄ ( γ ) 1 8 ( γ 2 ) 2 ( γ 1 ) 2 ( γ + 2 ) ( γ ( γ ( γ + 4 ) 3 ) + 2 ) γ 4 γ 2 4 γ 2 + γ + 8 γ and negative otherwise. The solution in this region is thus q 1 L ( α , γ ) when α > α ̄ ( γ ) and q 1 H ( α , γ ) , otherwise.

  1. In the area where α > α ̄ ̄ ( γ ) , above the red line of Figure 4, we find that

π U L ( 0 ) π U H ( 1 γ ) = 1 4 ( 1 γ ) γ ( 4 α ( 2 γ ) ( γ + 1 ) ) 0

The solution in this region is q 1(α, γ) = 0.

  1. In the last area, we find that

π U L q 1 L π U H ( 1 γ ) = ( γ ( 2 α + ( γ 1 ) γ 3 ) + 2 ) 2 4 4 γ 2 0

The solution in this region is q 1 L ( α , γ ) .

These thresholds are summarized in Figure 6 below, where q 1 T A = q 1 H ( α , γ ) , q 1 T B = 0 and q 1 T C = q 1 L ( α , γ ) .

Figure 6: 
(Equiv. Figure 1) Graph of solution partition.
Figure 6:

(Equiv. Figure 1) Graph of solution partition.

With management turnover and imperfect substitutes, the SPNE strategy of U jointly is:

q 1 T ( α , γ ) = 2 ( 1 α ) γ 4 ( 1 α ) γ 2 , if ( α , γ ) Area A 0 if ( α , γ ) Area B 2 γ ( 1 + 2 α ) 4 γ 2 otherwise ,

q 2 T ( α , γ ) = ( 1 α ) ( 2 γ ) 4 ( 1 α ) γ 2 , if ( α , γ ) Area A 1 2 if ( α , γ ) Area B 2 γ ( 1 α γ ) 4 γ 2 otherwise ,

f 1 T ( α , γ ) = ( 1 α ) ( 2 ( 1 α ) γ ) ( ( 2 γ ) ( 1 + γ ) 2 α ) ( 4 ( 1 α ) γ 2 ) 2 , if ( α , γ ) Area A 0 if ( α , γ ) Area B ( 1 α ) ( 2 ( 1 α γ ) γ ) ( 2 ( 1 + α γ ) + γ γ 2 ) ( 4 γ 2 ) 2 otherwise ,

f 2 T ( α , γ ) = ( 1 α ) 2 ( 2 γ ) 2 ( 4 ( 1 α ) γ 2 ) 2 , if ( α , γ ) Area A 1 4 if ( α , γ ) Area B ( 2 ( 1 α γ ) γ ) 2 ( 4 γ 2 ) 2 otherwise

where Area A′ denotes the subset { ( α , γ ) [ 0,1 ] × ( 0,1 ) : α < α ̄ ( γ )  and  1 > γ > 1 2 ( 5 1 ) } such that α ̄ ( γ ) = ( 1 / 8 ) ( γ 2 ) 2 ( γ 1 ) 2 ( γ + 2 ) ( γ ( γ ( γ + 4 ) 3 ) + 2 ) / γ 4 γ 2 4 / γ 2 + ( γ + 8 ) / γ , Area B′ denotes the subset { ( α , γ ) [ 0,1 ] × ( 0,1 ) : α ̄ ̄ ( γ ) < α < 1  and  1 > γ > 2 / 3 } such that α ̄ ̄ ( γ ) = 1 / γ 1 / 2 and Area C′ denotes the rest of the set of parameters.□

Appendix B. Proofs

B.1 Proof of Proposition 1

Denote by π U (α) the profit of the monopolist under strategic ambiguity. By the results under perfect substitutes obtained in the above proof and displayed in Eq. (8) (or in Lemma 2 in the proof of Proposition 4), we have:

(19) π U ( α ) = f 1 ( α ) + f 2 ( α ) = ( 1 α ) 2 3 4 α ,

as long as α ≤ 1/2. For higher values of α, π U is equal to 1/4. The monopoly profit with perfect substitutes is π U M = 1 / 4 . We then get:

π U ( α ) π U M = ( 1 2 α ) 2 4 ( 3 4 α ) when α < 1 / 2 , and 0 otherwise

which is strictly positive as long as α < 1/2 and null otherwise.□

B.2 Proof of Proposition 3

Take for example α = 1 and a sufficiently high γ, say γ > γ′, so that we are in area B. We get f 1 T + f 2 T = 1 / 4 while the monopoly profit is π M = π U B = 1 / ( 2 + 2 γ ) . With imperfect substitutes, we have γ′ < γ < 1, which implies that f 1 T + f 2 T = 1 / 4 < 1 / ( 2 + 2 γ ) = π M .□

B.3 Proof of Proposition 4

Remember that π U B = 1 / ( 2 ( 1 + γ ) ) is the benchmark profit without management turnover. Let us now denote by π U T the profit of the monopolist with management turnover. Lemma 2 summarizes the monopolist’s SPNE strategies according to the parameter values.

Lemma 2

With management turnover, the monopolist’s SPNE strategy jointly depends on the new manager’s level of optimism α and the product substitution γ such that:

q 1 T ( α , γ ) = 2 ( 1 α ) γ 4 ( 1 α ) γ 2 , i f ( α , γ ) A r e a A 0 i f ( α , γ ) A r e a B 2 γ ( 1 + 2 α ) 4 γ 2 o t h e r w i s e , q 2 T ( α , γ ) = ( 1 α ) ( 2 γ ) 4 ( 1 α ) γ 2 , i f ( α , γ ) A r e a A 1 2 i f ( α , γ ) A r e a B 2 γ ( 1 α γ ) 4 γ 2 o t h e r w i s e , f 1 T ( α , γ ) = ( 1 α ) ( 2 ( 1 α ) γ ) ( ( 2 γ ) ( 1 + γ ) 2 α ) ( 4 ( 1 α ) γ 2 ) 2 , i f ( α , γ ) A r e a A 0 i f ( α , γ ) A r e a B ( 1 α ) ( 2 ( 1 α γ ) γ ) ( 2 ( 1 + α γ ) + γ γ 2 ) ( 4 γ 2 ) 2 o t h e r w i s e , f 2 T ( α , γ ) = ( 1 α ) 2 ( 2 γ ) 2 ( 4 ( 1 α ) γ 2 ) 2 , i f ( α , γ ) A r e a A 1 4 i f ( α , γ ) A r e a B ( 2 ( 1 α γ ) γ ) 2 ( 4 γ 2 ) 2 o t h e r w i s e

where Area A denotes the subset { ( α , γ ) [ 0,1 ] 2 : α < α ̄ ( γ )  and  1 > γ > 1 2 ( 5 1 ) } such that α ̄ ( γ ) = ( 1 / 8 ) ( γ 2 ) 2 ( γ 1 ) 2 ( γ + 2 ) ( γ ( γ ( γ + 4 ) 3 ) + 2 ) / γ 4 γ 2 4 / γ 2 + ( γ + 8 ) / γ , Area B denotes the subset { ( α , γ ) [ 0,1 ] 2 : α ̄ ̄ ( γ ) < α < 1  and  1 > γ > 2 / 3 } such that α ̄ ̄ ( γ ) = 1 / γ 1 / 2 and Area C denotes the rest of the set of parameters.□

Since on these SPNE, firms always accept the contract, we have our next lemma which displays the monopolist’s equilibrium profits with respect to the parameter values.

Lemma 3

With management turnover, the monopolist earns

(20) π U T ( α , γ ) = ( 1 α ) ( 2 α γ ) 4 ( 1 α ) γ 2 i f ( α , γ ) A r e a A 1 / 4 i f ( α , γ ) A r e a B 2 ( 1 α γ ) + α ( 1 + α ) γ 2 γ 4 γ 2 o t h e r w i s e

We then get:

(21) π U T ( α , γ ) π U B ( γ ) = ( 1 α ) ( 2 α γ ) 4 ( 1 α ) γ 2 1 2 ( 1 + γ ) if ( α , γ ) Area A 1 γ 4 ( γ + 1 ) if ( α , γ ) Area B γ ( 2 α ( γ + 1 ) ( α γ + γ 2 ) + γ 2 ) 2 ( γ + 1 ) γ 2 4 otherwise

which is positive whenever α < α ̃ a ( γ ) 1 2 ( γ 2 ) γ 3 + 1 ( γ + 1 ) 2 γ 2 γ + 1 + 3 and negative otherwise in area A, always negative in area B and positive whenever α < α ̃ c ( γ ) γ 2 γ 4 5 γ 2 + 4 + γ + 2 2 γ 2 + γ while negative otherwise in area C. Figure 2 summarizes our findings and is redisplayed below (Figure 7).

  1. Let’s additionnally prove that the thresholds are inferior to 1/2 for γ ∈ (0, 1),

    1. Consider α ̃ c ( γ ) = γ 2 γ 4 5 γ 2 + 4 + γ + 2 2 γ 2 + γ 1 / 2 . It is equivalent to 2 + γ γ 2 4 5 γ 2 + γ 4 ( 1 / 2 ) 2 ( γ + γ 2 ) 2 2 γ 2 4 5 γ 2 + γ 4 4 ( 1 γ 2 ) 2 4 5 γ 2 + γ 4 4 8 γ 2 4 γ 4 4 5 γ 2 + γ 4 which is true for γ ∈ (0, 1).

    2. For α ̃ a ( γ ) = 1 2 ( γ 2 ) γ 3 + 1 ( γ + 1 ) 2 γ 2 γ + 1 + 3 1 / 2 , we have ( γ 2 ) γ 3 + 1 ( γ + 1 ) 2 γ 2 γ + 1 + 3 1 γ 2 γ + 1 + 3 1 ( γ 2 ) γ 3 + 1 ( γ + 1 ) 2 γ γ 2 γ + 1 ( γ 2 ) γ 3 + 1 ( γ + 1 ) 2 γ γ 2 ( γ 2 ) γ 3 + 1 ( γ γ 2 ) 2 1 + γ 4 2 γ 3 γ 2 2 γ 3 + γ 4 1 2 γ 3 + γ 4 which is true for γ ∈ (0, 1).

Figure 7: 
(Equiv. Figure 2) The monopolist’s profits.
Figure 7:

(Equiv. Figure 2) The monopolist’s profits.

B.4 Proof of Eq. 11

From π U T ( α ̃ ( γ ) , γ ) π U B ( γ ) = 0 , we get:

d α ̃ d γ ( γ ) = π U T γ π U B γ d π U T d α

We can then decompose the profits. First, using π U T ( q 2 * ( q 1 ) , q 1 ) at q 1 T ( α , γ ) , we have

π U T γ = π U T q 1 q 1 T γ + π U T γ | q 1 = q 1 T

At this point π U T / q 1 ( q 1 T ) = 0 , the expression simplifies to

π U T γ = 0 + f 1 γ | q 1 = q 1 T + f 2 γ | q 1 = q 1 T

Because f 1 q 1 T = ( 1 α ) 1 q 1 T q 1 T + 1 q 1 T < 1 γ α 1 γ q 1 T q 1 T and f 2 q 1 T = ( 1 / 4 ) ( 1 γ q 1 T ) 2 , we find

(22) π U T γ = 1 q 1 T < 1 γ α . q 1 T 1 2 q 1 T 1 γ q 1 T < 0

By the same process, we obtain

(23) π U T α = 1 q 1 T q 1 T + 1 q 1 T < 1 γ 1 γ q 1 T q 1 T < 0

Finally, it is easy to see that π U B q 1 * , q 2 * implies the same derivative irrespective of the area considered. We get

(24) π U B γ = 1 2 ( 1 + γ ) 2 < 0

From Eqs. (22)(24), we find that:

sign d α ̃ d γ = sign π U T γ π U B γ = sign f 2 γ q 1 T + 1 q 1 T < 1 γ f 1 γ q 1 T π U B γ

This is Eq. (11) in our main text.

In area A, where q 1 T = q 1 T A we have:

sign d α ̃ d γ = sign ( 1 α ) ( 2 γ ) ( 2 α + γ 2 ) 4 α + γ 2 4 2 + 1 2 ( γ + 1 ) 2

And the sign is positive.

In area C, where q 1 T = q 1 T C we have:

sign d α ̃ d γ = sign α 2 ( γ 2 ) 2 ( α + 1 ) 2 ( γ + 2 ) 2 + 1 2 ( γ + 1 ) 2

And the sign can be positive or negative. However, evaluating the sign at α = α ̃ c ( γ ) we find that

sign d α ̃ d γ = sign 2 γ 4 5 γ 2 + 4 2 + γ γ 2 + 2 γ 4 5 γ 2 + 4 + 4 γ 4 2 γ ( γ + 1 ) 2 γ 2 4

which is negative provided 0 < γ < 1 + 3 0.730 . This threshold is lower than the threshold at which α ̃ intersects area A, γ ≈ 0.784. Therefore, the slope is slightly positive above γ = 1 + 3 and negative below.□

B.5 Proof of Proposition 5

  1. It is straightforward to see that the firms make no profit in the case without management turnover.

  2. With management turnover, the monopolist takes advantage of ambiguity when the manager is sufficiently optimistic ( α α ̃ ( γ ) ) . This area encompasses a sub-part of Area A and Area C. From Eq. (12), we find that:

    1. in the intersection of Area A with the area where α α ̃ ( γ ) , the profit of Firm 1 is:

(25) π 1 = 1 q 1 T A γ q 2 T A q 1 T A ( 1 α ) 1 q 1 T A q 1 T A

(26) = q 1 T A α 1 q 1 T A γ q 2 T A

It can be shown through Mathematica that α 1 q 1 T A γ q 2 T A < 0 in the area of interest. Therefore the profit is nil in this area.

  1. in the intersection of Area C with the area where α α ̃ ( γ ) , the profit of Firm 1 is:

(27) π 1 = 1 q 1 T C γ q 2 T C q 1 T C ( 1 α ) 1 q 1 T C q 1 T C α 1 q 1 T C γ q 2 T C q 1 T C

(28) = 1 q 1 T C q 1 T C γ q 2 T C q 1 T C 1 q 1 T C q 1 T C + α 1 q 1 T C q 1 T C α 1 q 1 T C q 1 T C + α γ q 2 T C q 1 T C

(29) = ( 1 α ) γ q 1 T C q 2 T C < 0

Overall, we indeed find that Firm 1’s profit is negative in the region where the monopolist would take advantage of strategic ambiguity (i.e. α < α ̃ ( γ ) ). It is obvious to compute that Firm 2 makes zero profit.

From (i) and (ii), we find that Firm 1 is worse off with management turnover whereas Firm 2 is indifferent.[6]

B.6 Proof of Proposition 6

Let CS denote the consumer surplus. With a linear demand, the consumer surplus simplifies to:

CS ( q 1 , q 2 ) = ( q 1 ) 2 + ( q 2 ) 2 + 2 γ q 1 q 2 2

From the benchmark optimal quantity we find that the consumer surplus without management turnover is CSB = 1/(4(1 + γ)). Let CST denote the consumer surplus with management turnover. By Lemma 2, we have:

Lemma 4

With management turnover, the consumer surplus is:

(30) CS T ( α , γ ) = α 2 ( ( 4 3 γ ) γ + 8 ) 2 α ( γ 4 ) ( γ 2 ) ( γ + 1 ) + 2 ( γ 3 ) γ 2 + 8 2 4 α + γ 2 4 2 i f ( α , γ ) A r e a A 1 / 8 i f ( α , γ ) A r e a B γ α 2 γ 4 3 γ 2 2 α ( γ 2 ) 2 ( γ + 1 ) + 2 ( γ 3 ) γ + 8 2 γ 2 4 2 o t h e r w i s e

We then get (omiting writing CS as functions):

(31) CS T CS B = α 2 ( ( 4 3 γ ) γ + 8 ) 2 α ( γ 4 ) ( γ 2 ) ( γ + 1 ) + 2 ( γ 3 ) γ 2 + 8 2 4 α + γ 2 4 2 1 4 ( 1 + γ ) if ( α , γ ) Area A 1 γ 8 ( γ + 1 ) if ( α , γ ) Area B γ α 2 γ 4 3 γ 2 2 α ( γ 2 ) 2 ( γ + 1 ) + 2 ( γ 3 ) γ + 8 2 γ 2 4 2 1 4 ( 1 + γ ) otherwise

which is always positive in area A, always negative in area B and positive if α < ( γ 2 ) 2 ( γ + 1 ) 4 γ 3 γ 3 γ 2 4 2 2 γ 3 γ 2 2 γ + 2 γ 2 ( γ + 1 ) 3 γ 2 4 2 2 α ̂ ( γ ) while negative otherwise in area C. Figure 3 summarizes our findings and is redisplayed below (Figure 8).□

Figure 8: 
(Equiv. Figure 3) The consumer surplus.
Figure 8:

(Equiv. Figure 3) The consumer surplus.

B.7 Proof of Extension “Ambiguity Towards the Rival”

We suppose the manager feels ambiguity towards the rival and not the supplier. In addition, we focus on the case of perfect substitutes. We solve the sequential contracting game using backward induction.

Obviously, the interesting situation arises when the firm with the new manager, say firm 1, meets the supplier first. Otherwise, the firm knows about the rival decision before contracting with the supplier.

At stage 2, the supplier thus meets with firm 2. It sets (q 2, f 2) so as to maximize its expected profit U = f 1 + f 2, given firm 2’s acceptance decision f 2 ≤ (1 − q 2q 1)q 2. This gives the same continuation contract offer as in our model ( q 2 * ( q 1 ) , f 2 * ( q 1 ) ) where q 2 * is the Cournot best response to q 1 (i.e. q 2 * = ( 1 q 1 ) / 2 ).

At stage 1, the supplier meets with firm 1 and firm 1 forms expectations about firm 2’s acceptance decision. In the worst case scenario, firm 2 accepts and firm 1 expects to find q 2 * ( q 1 ) on the market. In the best case scenario, firm 2 rejects and firm 1 expects to be a monopolist. Firm 1 accepts the supplier’s offer whenever f 1 ( 1 q 1 α q 2 * ( q 1 ) ) q 1 . The supplier acknowledges this behavior and sets (q 1, f 1) so as to maximize its expected profit E π U = f 2 * ( q 1 ) + f 1 . Due to the supplier’s bargaining power, it simplifies to E π U = f 2 * ( q 1 ) + ( 1 q 1 α q 2 * ( q 1 ) ) q 1 . The derivative writes d E π U / d q 1 = 1 2 ( α + ( 2 α 3 ) q 1 + 1 ) and gives q 1 * = 1 α 3 2 α (SOC is −(3/2) + α < 0). The monopolist does not serve firm 1 when α = 1. We then find q 2 * = 2 α 6 4 α , f 1 * = ( 2 α ) 2 ( 1 α ) 2 ( 3 2 α ) 2 , and f 2 * = ( 2 α ) 2 4 ( 3 2 α ) 2 . Finally, we compute the supplier’s equilibrium profit π U * = ( 2 α ) 2 12 8 α which is always greater than the monopoly profit (1/4) whenever 1 > α > 0 (i.e. the ambiguity attitude is not extreme).□

Appendix C: Illustration Upstream Competition

Caprice (2006) is the closest framework to such an extension in our model. The author extends Rey and Tirole (2007)’s model with upstream competition by adding a competitive fringe in the upstream market.

Thus, we suppose there is a competitive fringe and rename the established supplier as the incumbent. Furthermore, we assume that all contracts are non-exclusive and perfectly observable by everyone. In particular, upon contracting with a supplier, each firm can observe any rival supplier’s offer to the rival firm. Last, we assume the incumbent prefers to deter poaching, and the firms prefer to buy from the incumbent rather than from the fringe when they offer the same quantity and nil fixed fees.

C.1 The Benchmark Situation

Let us first study the benchmark situation without management turnover. We find that the symmetric equilibrium changes. Even though the incumbent still supplies both firms, the quantities increase, whereas the fixed fees decrease.

C.1.1 Intuition of the Proof

Fixed fees. Suppose the incumbent offers half the monopoly quantity to each firm in exchange for half monopoly profit. Then, the fringe can provide the same quantity in exchange for a lower fixed fee, which at best is nil. Therefore, the incumbent supplier prefers to quote a fixed fee equal to 0 so that the fringe cannot poach the firms by undercutting the fixed fee.

Quantities. Regarding the quantities, suppose the incumbent freely offers half the monopoly quantity to each firm. The fringe can then freely offer more quantity, say up to the deviation quantity (i.e.), to at least one firm. The firm would accept, and the rival would still get input from the incumbent (the latter’s expected profits remain positive). To avoid such poaching, the incumbent delivers half the Cournot quantity to the firms (which also leads us back to a symmetric equilibrium). Then, the fringe cannot offer more quantity to the firms.

C.2 Management Turnover and Optimism

Now let us consider the situation with management turnover when the manager is sufficiently optimistic so that a monopoly supplier prefers sequential contracting. The following additional assumptions are needed: (i) the manager is also ambiguous about what the fringe will offer in the future to D2 (but not in the present); (ii) the fringe can meet with D2 when the incumbent meets with D1, and this contract is observable.

The incumbent does not benefit from ambiguity anymore as it cannot extract the total expected revenues of D1. It is indifferent between sequential and simultaneous contracting.

C.2.1 Intuition of the Proof

Fringe does not meet D2 while incumbent meets D1. We use backward induction. When the incumbent meets with D2, the fringe can propose the same offer but a nil fixed fee. The incumbent thus has to set a nil fixed fee as well. To prevent poaching, the incumbent also delivers the Cournot best response to D2. When meeting with D1, a similar behavior occurs. The incumbent freely provides the “optimistic quantity”. At equilibrium, the incumbent quotes a nil fixed fee for the two firms and supplies the same quantities as in our previous setting.

Fringe meets D2 while incumbent meets D1. Suppose now that the incumbent wants to meet with D1 and the fringe decides to meet with D2 meanwhile. Then ambiguity is muted as D1 observes D2’s offer. Therefore, there is no reason for the incumbent to meet D1 first. The incumbent turns back to simultaneously contracting with the two firms: it sets the same equilibrium as in the simultaneous contracting case to prevent the fringe from poaching.

Then if we compare both settings, the incumbent earns the same profit of zero in the two settings due to the presence of the fringe. It becomes indifferent between the two settings. In particular, upstream competition can mute ambiguity as the fringe can meet with the rival while the incumbent meets with D1.

References

Armstrong, M., and S. Huck. 2010. “Behavioral Economics as Applied to Firms: A Primer.” CESifo Working Paper, No. 2937.10.2139/ssrn.1553645Suche in Google Scholar

Arrow, K. J., and L. Hurwicz. 1972. “An Optimality Criterion for Decision-Making under Ignorance.” In Uncertainty and Expectations in Economics: Essays in Honour of G.L.S. Shackle., 1–11. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.10.1017/CBO9780511752940.015Suche in Google Scholar

Caprice, S. 2006. “Multilateral Vertical Contracting with an Alternative Supply: The Welfare Effects of a Ban on Price Discrimination.” Review of Industrial Organization 28 (1): 63–80. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-006-0008-6.Suche in Google Scholar

Chateauneuf, A., C. Ventura, and V. Vergopoulos. 2020. “A Simple Characterization of the Hurwicz Criterium under Uncertainty.” Revue Économique 71 (2): 331–6. https://doi.org/10.3917/reco.712.0331.Suche in Google Scholar

Eichberger, J., D. Kelsey, and B. C. Schipper. 2007. “Granny versus Game Theorist: Ambiguity in Experimental Games.” Theory and Decision 64 (2–3): 333–62. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-007-9053-3.Suche in Google Scholar

Eichberger, J., D. Kelsey, and B. C. Schipper. 2009. “Ambiguity and Social Interaction.” Oxford Economic Papers 61 (2): 355–79. https://doi.org/10.1093/oep/gpn030.Suche in Google Scholar

Englmaier, F., and M. Reisinger. 2014. “Biased Managers as Strategic Commitment.” Managerial and Decision Economics 35 (5): 350–6. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.2619.Suche in Google Scholar

Gilo, D., and Y. Yehezkel. 2020. “Vertical Collusion.” The RAND Journal of Economics 51 (1): 133–57. https://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12308.Suche in Google Scholar

Hurwicz, L. 1951. Optimality Criteria for Decision Making under Ignorance, Cowles Commission Discussion Paper No. 370.Suche in Google Scholar

Ivanov, A. 2011. “Attitudes to Ambiguity in One-Shot Normal-form Games: An Experimental Study.” Games and Economic Behavior 71 (2): 366–94. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2010.05.009.Suche in Google Scholar

Kauffeldt, T. F., and B. R. Wiesenfarth. 2018. “Product Design Competition under Different Degrees of Demand Ambiguity.” Review of Industrial Organization 53 (2): 397–420. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-018-9620-5.Suche in Google Scholar

Król, M. 2012. “Product Differentiation Decisions under Ambiguous Consumer Demand and Pessimistic Expectations.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 30 (6): 593–604. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2012.05.004.Suche in Google Scholar

McAfee, R. P., and M. Schwartz. 1994. “Opportunism in Multilateral Vertical Contracting: Nondiscrimination, Exclusivity, and Uniformity.” The American Economic Review 84 (1): 210–30.10.1257/0002828041464632Suche in Google Scholar

Meccheri, N. 2021. “Biased Managers in Vertically Related Markets.” Managerial and Decision Economics 42 (3): 724–36. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.3268.Suche in Google Scholar

Munster, J., and M. Reisinger. 2017. “Sequencing Bilateral Negotiations with Externalities.” In Working Paper.Suche in Google Scholar

Rey, P., and J. Tirole. 2007. “A Primer on Foreclosure.” Handbook of Industrial Organization 3: 2145–220. https://doi.org/10.1016/s1573-448x(06)03033-0.Suche in Google Scholar

Ryall, M., and R. Sampson. 2009. “Formal Contracts in the Presence of Relational Enforcement Mechanisms: Evidence from Technology Development Projects.” Management Science 55 (6): 906–25. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1090.0995.Suche in Google Scholar

Received: 2021-05-20
Revised: 2021-10-04
Accepted: 2021-11-18
Published Online: 2022-02-23

© 2022 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Heruntergeladen am 19.9.2025 von https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2021-0070/html
Button zum nach oben scrollen