Home The Effects of Introducing Advertising in Pay TV: A Model of Asymmetric Competition between Pay TV and Free TV
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

The Effects of Introducing Advertising in Pay TV: A Model of Asymmetric Competition between Pay TV and Free TV

  • Helmut Dietl , Markus Lang ORCID logo EMAIL logo and Panlang Lin
Published/Copyright: March 3, 2022

Abstract

The television broadcasting industry is of crucial economic and social importance. Traditionally, this industry has been dominated by free-to-air TV (FTV) but due to technological progress, subscription-based pay TV (PTV) has emerged as a competing business model. A key question for the PTV broadcasters is whether to air commercials in addition to charging subscription fees. Based on a theoretical model of asymmetric competition between a PTV and an FTV broadcaster, we examine the effects of placing PTV advertising on broadcaster market strategies, viewer demands, broadcaster profits and consumer surplus. We find that introducing advertising on PTV can induce a higher viewer demand on this channel but a lower viewer demand on the FTV channel. Surprisingly, consumers can benefit through the introduction of advertising in PTV and broadcaster profits can increase if the viewer disutility of advertising is sufficiently large. Our study provides an analytical framework for choosing and implementing an optimal PTV strategy when an FTV competitor preexists in the market. Furthermore, our study derives implications for policymakers and regulatory authorities by showing that additional PTV advertising is not necessarily socially undesirable due to the strategic market reactions.

JEL Classification: D40; L10

Corresponding author: Markus Lang, Institute of Sport Sciences, University of Lausanne, 1015, Lausanne, Switzerland, E-mail:

Appendix A: Proofs

A.1 Proof of Lemma 1

First, we derive the second-order conditions. By noting that n p s p = 1 2 t , 2 n p s p 2 = 0 , n p a p = γ 2 t , 2 n p a p 2 = 0 , c a p > 0 and 2 c a p 2 > 0 , the second-order conditions for a maximum require

( a ) 2 π p ( s p ) 2 = 1 t < 0  and  2 π p a p 2 = k γ t 2 c a p 2 < 0 , ( b ) 2 π p s p 2 2 π p a p 2 2 π p s p a p 2 π p a p s p = 1 t k γ t + 2 c a p 2 k + γ 2 t 2 > 0 .

It is easy to see that (a) is satisfied by definition. To ensure that (b) is satisfied, we must assume that t > k γ 2 4 c a p * , where c ( a p ) = 2 c a p 2 .

Second, we derive the optimality conditions in Part (i). By solving π p s p = 0 for s p with n p s p = 1 2 t , we obtain s p * = 1 2 ( γ a f * ( k + γ ) a p * + t ) . Plugging s p * into π p a p = k n p * s p * , a p * + s p * + k a p * n p * a p c a p * = 0 and π f a f = k n f * a f * + k a f * n f * a f c a f * = 0 and rearranging these equations produces the optimality conditions for PTV and FTV.

Part (ii). To prove the existence and uniqueness of the equilibrium s p A , a p A , a f A , we proceed as follows. First, we show that the reaction function R f (a p ) of FTV is a monotonous decreasing function in a p and the reaction function R p (a f ) of PTV is a monotonous increasing function in a f . We rearrange the optimality conditions of PTV and FTV and we define

F p a p A , a f A = k γ 4 t ( γ a f A + ( k γ ) a p A + t ) c a p A , F f a p A , a f A = k 4 t ( 3 γ a f A ( k γ ) a p A + 3 t ) c a f A .

With the implicit function theorem, we derive

d a p A d a f = F p / a f F p / a p = γ ( k γ ) ( k γ ) 2 4 t c a p A > t > t S O C 0 , d a f A d a p = F f / a p F f / a f = k ( k γ ) 3 k γ + 4 t c a f A < 0 .

Hence, PTV reacts with a higher advertising level to an increase in the FTV advertising level, while the opposite is true for the reaction of FTV. We illustrate the reaction functions in Figure 2.

Figure 2: 
Reaction functions
Figure 2:

Reaction functions

We define a ̄ p as the advertising level, which PTV would have to set such that the FTV broadcaster has no incentives to places advertising on its channel, i.e. R f ( a ̄ p ) = 0 . Moreover, a ̲ p is the PTV advertising level if FTV refrains from advertising, i.e. a ̲ p = R p ( 0 ) . Now, we have to show that a ̄ p > a ̲ p . This guarantees that the monotonous reaction function have exactly one intersection point, which characterizes the unique equilibrium. Throughout the paper, we assume that the viewers’ disutility from advertising does not exceed the marginal return on advertising γk.

Because c a f A = k 4 t ( 3 γ a f A ( k γ ) a p A + 3 t ) is the optimality condition for FTV, we derive that if a p = 3 t k γ then a f = 0. Hence, a ̄ p ( t ) = 3 t k γ and thus a ̄ p t > 0 . Moreover, a ̲ p is implicitly characterized by the PTV’s optimality condition c ( a ̲ p ) = k γ 4 t ( ( k γ ) a ̲ p + t ) . With the implicit function theorem, we derive

a ̲ p t = a ̲ p ( k γ ) 2 t ( k γ ) 2 4 t c ( a ̲ p ) < 0 ,

for t sufficiently large. Because a ̄ p ( t ) is continuous and a monotonously increasing function in t and a ̲ p ( t ) is continuous and a monotonously decreasing function in t, there exists a value t eq such that a ̄ p ( t ) > a ̲ p ( t ) for all t > t eq. Hence, we have shown that for a sufficiently large differentiation parameter, i.e. t > t eq, an unique equilibrium a p A , a f A exists, which is implicitly defined by c a p A = k γ 4 t ( γ a f A + ( k γ ) a p A + t ) and c a f A = k 4 t ( 3 γ a f A ( k γ ) a p A + 3 t ) . Note that a p A is always larger than zero, while t has to be sufficiently large to ensure that a f A is larger than zero, i.e. a f A > 0 t > t a f γ a f A + k γ 3 a p A .

In a next step, we will derive the conditions under which a positive equilibrium subscription fee s p A exists and is unique. According to the first-order conditions, the subscription fee s p A is implicitly defined by s p A = 1 2 ( γ a f A ( k + γ ) a p A + t ) . Hence, s p A > 0 t > t s p k a p A + γ a p A a f A . Because for t > max { t eq , t a f , t S O C } , a unique equilibrium a p A , a f A exists and is positive, we conclude that t > t s p k a p A + γ a p A a f A ensures that a unique subscription fee exists and is positive.

For the PTV channel, the subscription fee s p A and advertising level a p A in equilibrium are implicitly given by

(24) s p A = 1 2 ( γ a f A ( k + γ ) a p A + t )  and  c a p A = k γ 4 t ( γ a f A + ( k γ ) a p A + t ) .

For example, for a quadratic cost function c(a) = 1/2a 2, the advertising level a ̲ p ( t ) is given by

a ̲ p ( t ) = t ( k γ ) 4 t ( k γ ) 2 ,

and thus

a ̄ p ( t ) > a ̲ p ( t ) t > t e q ( k γ ) 2 3 .

A.2 Proof of Proposition 1

To prove Part (i), we differentiate three cases:

  1. Suppose that γ = k. In this case, we derive c a p A = 0 and hence a p A = 0 . The subscription fee is then given by s p A = 1 2 k a f A + t and a f A is implicitly defined by c a f A = 3 k 4 t k a f A + t . To ensure that the FTV broadcaster sets a positive advertising level, it must hold t > k a f A and hence a f A > a p A for γ = k.

  2. Suppose that γ = 0. In this case, the subscription fee is given by s p A = 1 2 k a p A + t . To ensure a positive fee, we assume that t > k a p A . The advertising level a p A , a f A are then implicitly defined by c a p A = k 4 t k a p A + t and c a f A = k 4 t k a p A + 3 t . Since t > k a p A , the FTV broadcaster sets a positive advertising level because k a p A + 3 t > 0 . Next, we derive

    c a p A c a f A = k k a p A t 2 t < 0 ,

    because t > k a p A . It follows that a f A > a p A for γ = 0.

  3. Suppose that γ ∈ (0, k). We can show that a p A and a f A will never coincide in the interval γ ∈ (0, k). Suppose that a p A = a f A = a A and hence c a p A = c a f A such that k γ 4 t ( k a A + t ) = k 4 t ( 2 γ + k ) a A + 3 t . This equality is satisfied if and only if γ = − 2k, which is not in the interval of feasible γ.

From 1.–3., it follows that a f A > a p A for γ ∈ (0, k].

Moreover, we can rule out the case γ > k. To show this claim, we provide a proof by contradiction. We know that c a p A = k γ 4 t ( γ a f A + ( k γ ) a p A + t ) 0 . Now, suppose that γ > k. Hence, it must be the case that t + γ a f A ( γ k ) a p A . However, a positive subscription fee s p A > 0 implies t + γ a f A > ( γ + k ) a p A . That is, t + γ a f A ( ( γ + k ) a p A , ( γ k ) a p A ] , which cannot be satisfied in equilibrium. Therefore, our assumption was wrong and it must hold γk.

To prove the comparative statics result in Part (ii), we rearrange (15) and (14) and define F p γ , a p A = k γ 4 t ( γ a f A + ( k γ ) a p A + t ) c a p A = 0 and F f γ , a f A = k 4 t ( 3 γ a f A ( k γ ) a p A + 3 t ) c a f A = 0 . With the implicit function theorem, we derive

a f A γ = F f / γ F f / a f = 3 a f A a p A k 3 k γ + 4 t c a f A < 0 .

Hence, the advertising level on the FTV channel is always decreasing in γ. Regarding the advertising level on PTV, we derive

a p A γ = F p / γ F p / a p = a f A a p A ( 2 γ k ) + t + k a p A ( k γ ) 2 4 t c a p A .

The second-order conditions require 4 t c a p A > ( k γ ) 2 , which implies that the denominator is negative. Moreover, it is always the case that a f A > a p A . As a result, we derive that for γ < γ ̂ , the numerator will be negative, and hence,

a p A γ > 0 γ < γ ̂ k a f A 2 a p A t 2 a f A a p A .

A.3 Proof of Proposition 2

To show that n f A n p A γ [ 0 , k ] , we differentiate three cases:

  1. Suppose that γ = k. In this case, we derive n f A n p A = 1 2 t t k a f A > 0 because t > k a f A .

  2. Suppose that γ = 0. In this case, we derive n f A n p A = 1 2 t t k a p A > 0 because t > k a p A .

  3. Suppose that γ ∈ (0, k). To show that n f A n p A γ ( 0 , k ) , we provide a proof by contradiction. Suppose that n f A can fall below n p A in the interval γ ∈ (0, k). Note that n f A ( γ ) and n p A ( γ ) are both continuous functions in γ. Hence, it must be the case that n f A and n p A intersect twice in the interval γ ∈ (0, k) because n f A ( 0 ) > n p A ( 0 ) and n f A ( k ) > n p A ( k ) . However, only one point of intersection exists because

n f A = n p A = 1 2 γ = t k a p A a f A a p A .

It follows that the assumption was wrong and n f A n p A ∀γ ∈ (0, k).

A.4 Proof of Proposition 3

For Proposition 3, we calculate the equilibrium solutions in Regimes A and B for the quadratic cost function c ( a ) = θ 2 a 2 .

In Regime A, the maximization problems for the PTV and FTV broadcasters, respectively, are given by

max ( s p , a p ) > 0 π p = ( s p + k a p ) 1 2 1 + 1 t ( γ ( a f a p ) s p ) θ 2 a p 2 , max a f > 0 π f = k a f 1 2 1 + 1 t ( γ ( a p a f ) + s p ) θ 2 a f 2 .

By deriving the corresponding first-order conditions and solving the system of equations, it is straightforward to calculate the subscription fee s p A and the level of advertising a p A for the PTV broadcaster in Regime A as

s p A , a p A = 1 λ t 2 θ t + 3 k γ 2 θ t k 2 + k γ , 1 λ t 2 θ t + 3 k γ k γ ,

with λ = 8 θ 2 t 2 k k γ 2 γ 2 θ t k 2 5 k γ + γ 2 .

For the FTV broadcaster, the level of advertising a f A in Regime A is

a f A = 1 λ 2 k t 3 θ t k γ 2 .

The viewer demands on the PTV channel n p A and FTV channel n f A are

n p A = 1 λ θ t 2 θ t + 3 k γ  and  n f A = 1 λ 3 θ t k γ 2 2 θ t + k γ .

As in the general model, we assume that the differentiation parameter is sufficiently large with t > t A . This implies

(25) λ > 0 , 3 θ t > k γ 2 and  2 θ t + k γ > k 2 .

In Regime B, the maximizations problems for the PTV and FTV broadcasters, respectively, are given by

max s p > 0 π p = s p 1 2 1 + 1 t ( γ a f s p ) , max a f > 0 π f = k a f 1 2 1 + 1 t ( s p γ a f ) 1 2 θ a f 2 .

By deriving the corresponding first-order conditions and solving the system of equations, we calculate the subscription fee s p B for the PTV broadcaster in Regime B as

s p B = 2 θ t 2 + 3 k t γ 4 θ t + 3 k γ .

For the FTV broadcaster the level of advertising a f B in Regime B is

a f B = 3 k t 4 θ t + 3 k γ ,

so that the viewer demands in Regime B are given by

n p B = 2 θ t + 3 k γ 2 ( 4 θ t + 3 k γ )  and  n f B = 3 2 θ t + k γ 2 ( 4 θ t + 3 k γ ) .

To prove Part (i) of Proposition 3, we must show that

s p A = 1 λ t 2 θ t + 3 k γ 2 θ t k 2 + k γ < 2 θ t 2 + 3 k t γ 4 θ t + 3 k γ = s p B .

Rearranging of the inequality yields t 2 θ t + 3 k γ 2 θ t k 2 + k γ 4 θ t + 3 k γ λ 2 θ t 2 + 3 k t γ < 0 . We further simplify the inequality and obtain

t k γ 2 θ t + 3 k γ 2 θ t k + γ + k γ 2 k + γ < 0 ,

which proves the claim in Part (i).

To prove Part (ii) of Proposition 3, we must show that

a f A = 1 λ 2 k t 3 θ t k γ 2 < 3 k t 4 θ t + 3 k γ = a f B .

Rearranging of the inequality yields [ 2 k t ( 3 θ t k γ 2 ) ] 4 θ t + 3 k γ λ 3 k t < 0 . We further simplify the inequality and obtain

k t k γ 2 2 θ t + 3 k γ < 0 ,

which proves the claim in Part (ii).

To prove Part (iii) of Proposition 3, we must show that

n p A = 1 λ θ t 2 θ t + 3 k γ > 2 θ t + 3 k γ 2 ( 4 θ t + 3 k γ ) = n p B .

Rearranging of the inequality yields θ t 2 θ t + 3 k γ 2 ( 4 θ t + 3 k γ ) λ ( 2 θ t + 3 k γ ) > 0 . We further simplify the inequality and obtain

k γ 2 2 θ t + k γ 2 θ t + 3 k γ > 0 .

Because n f = 1 − n p it follows that n f A < n f B , which proves Part (iii) and thus completes the proof of the proposition.

A.5 Proof of Proposition 4

First, we will prove Part (i) of the proposition which states that aggregate consumer surplus is higher in Regime A than in Regime B, i.e. CS p A + CS f A > CS p B + CS f B .

In Regime A, we compute the aggregate consumer surplus CS A = CS p A + CS f A as

CS A = v 5 t 2 + θ t 2 ϕ λ 2

with

λ = 8 θ 2 t 2 k k γ 2 γ 2 θ t k 2 5 k γ + γ 2 . ϕ = θ t 2 θ t + 3 k γ 2 2 2 k 2 8 θ t 7 k γ + 2 γ 2 λ .

In Regime B, the aggregate consumer surplus CS B = CS p B + CS f B is given by

CS B = v 5 t 4 + θ t 2 13 θ t + 9 k γ 4 θ t + 3 k γ 2 .

To prove Part (i) of the proposition, we must show that CS A > CS B or equivalently

4 θ t 4 θ t + 3 k γ 2 ϕ 3 44 θ 2 t 2 + 52 θ k t γ + 15 k 2 γ 2 λ 2 > 0 .

We further rearrange this inequality as

k γ 2 τ 1 + τ 2 > 0

with

τ 1 = 45 k 4 γ 4 k γ 2 128 θ 5 t 5 + 16 θ 4 t 4 ( k 2 + γ 2 ) 52 k γ + 16 θ 3 t 3 k γ 8 ( k 2 + γ 2 ) 115 k γ , τ 2 = 24 θ 2 k 2 t 2 γ 2 11 ( k 2 + γ 2 ) 73 k γ + 12 θ t k 3 γ 3 16 ( k 2 + γ 2 ) 59 k γ .

Because of k > γ the above inequality simplifies to τ 1 + τ 2 < 0. After rearrangements and simplifications we obtain β 1 + β 2 + β 3 > 0 with

β 1 = 16 θ 4 t 4 8 θ t η 2 + 128 θ 3 t 3 k γ 3 θ t η 2 , β 2 = 264 θ 2 t 2 k 2 γ 2 3 θ t η 2 + 45 k 4 γ 4 3 θ t η 2 + 192 θ t k 3 γ 3 3 θ t η 2 , β 3 = 416 θ 4 t 4 k γ + 792 θ 3 t 3 k 2 γ 2 + 189 θ t k 4 γ 4 + 648 θ 2 t 2 k 3 γ 3 .

and η 1 = (k 2 + γ 2) and η 2 = k γ 2 . From our assumption t > t A it follows 3θt > η 2 (see Eq. (25)) and thus it holds β 1 + β 2 + β 3 > 0, which proves Part (i) of the proposition.

Second, we will prove Part (ii) of the proposition which states that fhe profit of the FTV (PTV) broadcaster is lower (higher) in Regime A than in Regime B, i.e. π f A < π f B and π p A > π p B .

In Regime A, we derive the profits of the PTV and FTV broadcasters, respectively, as

π p A = 1 2 λ 2 θ t 2 4 θ t k γ 2 2 θ t + 3 k γ 2 , π f A = 1 λ 2 2 k 2 t k γ 2 3 θ t 2 θ t + k γ ,

with

λ = 8 θ 2 t 2 k k γ 2 γ 2 θ t k 2 5 k γ + γ 2 .

In Regime B, the profits of the PTV and FTV broadcasters, respectively, are

π p B = t 2 θ t + 3 k γ 2 2 4 θ t + 3 k γ 2  and  π f B = 9 k 2 t θ t + k γ 2 4 θ t + 3 k γ 2 .

To prove the claim that the profits of the PTV broadcaster is higher in Regime A than in Regime B, we show

π p A = 1 2 λ 2 θ t 2 4 θ t k γ 2 2 θ t + 3 k γ 2 > t 2 θ t + 3 k γ 2 2 4 θ t + 3 k γ 2 = π p B .

After rearranging the inequality we get

θ t 2 4 θ t k γ 2 2 θ t + 3 k γ 2 2 4 θ t + 3 k γ 2 2 λ 2 t 2 θ t + 3 k γ 2 > 0 θ t 4 θ t k γ 2 4 θ t + 3 k γ 2 λ 2 > 0

After rearrangements

k γ 2 ξ > 0 .

with

ξ = 16 θ 3 t 3 + k 2 γ 2 k γ 2 + 4 θ 2 t 2 k 2 6 k γ + γ 2 + θ k t γ 4 k 2 11 k γ + 4 γ 2

Because k > γ the proof further simplifies to ξ < 0. After further rearrangements and by denoting η 2 = k γ 2 we obtain

4 θ 2 t 2 4 θ t η 2 2 k γ + 4 θ t k γ 6 θ t η 2 2 k γ + k 2 γ 2 11 θ t η 2 2 k γ + 2 k 3 γ 3 > 0

Again, we rearrange and simplify the inequality to

4 θ 2 t 2 4 θ t η 2 + 4 θ t k γ 4 θ t η 2 + k 2 γ 2 3 θ t η 2 > 0 .

From our assumption t > t A it follows 3θt > η 2 (see (25)) and thus the above inequality is larger than zero, which proves the claim.

Next, we show that the profits of the FTV broadcaster is lower in Regime A than in Regime B, i.e.

π f A = 1 λ 2 2 k 2 t k γ 2 3 θ t 2 θ t + k γ < 9 k 2 t θ t + k γ 2 4 θ t + 3 k γ 2 = π f B .

After rearranging the inequality we get

2 k 2 t k γ 2 3 θ t 2 θ t + k γ 2 4 θ t + 3 k γ 2 λ 2 9 k 2 t θ t + k γ < 0 .

We further simplify the inequality and obtain

k 2 t η 2 θ t + k γ 2 θ t + 3 k γ 48 θ 2 t 2 9 k η 2 γ 2 θ t 7 k 2 32 k γ + 7 γ 2 < 0 .

Thus, we only need to show that

48 θ 2 t 2 9 k η 2 γ 2 θ t 7 k 2 32 k γ + 7 γ 2 > 0 θ t 48 θ t 14 η 2 + k γ 36 θ t 9 η 2 > 0 .

From our assumption t > t A it follows 3θt > η 2 (see (25)) and thus the above inequality is larger than zero, which proves the claim. This completes the proof of Proposition 4.

Appendix B: Symmetric Competition Between Two FTV Broadcasters

In this appendix, we analyze an alternative benchmark: the symmetric competition between two FTV broadcasters, indexed i , j = 1,2 . We call this benchmark Regime C.

In Regime C, the maximization problems for the FTV broadcaster i = 1,2 is given by

max a f , i > 0 π f , i = k a f , i 1 2 1 + 1 t ( γ ( a f , j a f , i ) ) θ 2 a f , i 2 .

for the quadratic cost function c ( a ) = θ 2 a 2 .

By deriving the corresponding first-order conditions and solving the system of equations, it is straightforward to calculate the symmetric level of advertising a f , i C for the FTV broadcaster i in Regime C as

a f , i C = k t 4 θ t + k γ .

Given the symmetric competition, it is straightforward to derive viewer demands on the two FTV channels as

n f , i C = 1 2 .

The aggregate consumer surplus CS C = CS f , 1 C + CS f , 2 C is given by

CS C = v 5 t 4 + 4 θ t 2 4 θ t + k γ

and the profits of the FTV broadcaster i is

π f , i C = k 2 t 2 θ t + k γ 2 4 θ t + k γ 2 .

To compare between Regime A and Regime C, please note that the broadcaster indexed with 1 in Regime C is the FTV channel that decides to charge a subscription fee in addition to carrying ads and thus becomes a PTV channel in Regime A and is indexed with p.

The next proposition derives the impact on the advertising level and viewer demand through a switch from Regime C to Regime A:

Proposition 7

When the FTV channel 1 decides to charge a subscription fee in addition to carrying ads, the following results are true:

(i) The advertising level on this channel decreases and the advertising level on the other channel increases, i.e. a p A < a f , 1 C and a f A > a f , 2 C .

(ii) Viewer demand on this channel decreases and viewer demand on the other channel increases, i.e. n p A < n f , 1 C and n f A > n f , 2 C .

Proof

Remember that λ = 8 θ 2 t 2 k k γ 2 γ 2 θ t k 2 5 k γ + γ 2

To prove Part (i) of the proposition, we first show that

a p A = 1 λ t 2 θ t + 3 k γ k γ < k t 4 θ t + k γ = a f , 1 C

Rearranging this inequality yields

2 k t ( 6 θ t + ( k γ ) 2 ) 32 θ 2 t 2 + k ( k γ ) 2 γ + 4 θ t ( k 2 5 k γ + γ 2 ) > k t 4 θ t + k γ

Since t > k ( k γ ) 4 θ we can show that the inequality holds for all k > γ.

With a similar calculation, we can show that

a f A = 1 λ 2 k t 3 θ t k γ 2 > k t 4 θ t + k γ = a f , 2 C .

To prove Part (ii) of the proposition, we first show that

n p A = 1 λ θ t 2 θ t + 3 k γ < 1 2 = n f , 1 C

Rearranging this inequality yields

2 θ t ( 4 θ t + 3 k γ ) 32 θ 2 t 2 k ( k γ ) 2 γ 4 θ t ( k 2 5 k γ + γ 2 ) < 1 2

Since t > k ( k γ ) 4 θ we can show that the inequality holds for all k > γ.

With a similar calculation, we can show that

n f A = 1 λ 3 θ t k γ 2 2 θ t + k γ > 1 2 = n f , 2 C .

In the next proposition, we compare broadcaster profits and consumer surplus in Regime A and C:

Proposition 8

(i) Each broadcaster realizes more profits in Regime A than in Regime C, i.e. π p A > π f , 1 C and π f A > π f , 2 C .

(ii) Aggregate consumer surplus is higher in Regime A than in Regime C, i.e. CS A = CS p A + CS f A > CS f , 1 C + CS f , 2 C = CS C .

Proof

Remember that λ = 8 θ 2 t 2 k k γ 2 γ 2 θ t k 2 5 k γ + γ 2 .

To prove Part (i) of the proposition, we first show that

π p A = 1 2 λ 2 θ t 2 4 θ t k γ 2 2 θ t + 3 k γ 2 > k 2 t 2 θ t + k γ 2 4 θ t + k γ 2 = π f , 1 C

Rearranging this inequality yields

θ t 2 ( 8 θ t ( k γ ) 2 ) ( 4 θ t + 3 k γ ) 2 ( 32 θ 2 t 2 + k ( k γ ) 2 γ + 4 θ t ( k 2 5 k γ + γ 2 ) ) 2 > k 2 t ( 2 θ t + k γ ) 2 ( 4 θ t + k γ ) 2

Since t > k ( k γ ) 4 θ we can show that the inequality holds for all k > γ.

With a similar calculation, we can show that

π f A = 1 λ 2 2 k 2 t k γ 2 3 θ t 2 θ t + k γ > k 2 t 2 θ t + k γ 2 4 θ t + k γ 2 = π f , 2 C

To prove Part (ii), we show that

CS A = v 5 t 2 + θ t 2 ϕ λ 2 > v 5 t 4 + 4 θ t 2 4 θ t + k γ

with

λ = 8 θ 2 t 2 k k γ 2 γ 2 θ t k 2 5 k γ + γ 2 ϕ = θ t 2 θ t + 3 k γ 2 2 2 k 2 8 θ t 7 k γ + 2 γ 2 λ

Rearranging this inequality yields

ϕ λ 2 > 5 t 2 + 4 4 θ t + k γ

Since t > k ( k γ ) 4 θ we can show that the inequality holds for all k > γ. □

References

Ambrus, A., E. Calvano, and M. Reisinger. 2016. “Either or Both Competition: A “Two-Sided” Theory of Advertising with Overlapping Viewerships.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 8 (3): 189–222. https://doi.org/10.1257/mic.20150019.Search in Google Scholar

Anderson, S. P., and S. Coate. 2005. “Market Provision of Broadcasting: A Welfare Analysis.” The Review of Economic Studies 72: 947–72. https://doi.org/10.1111/0034-6527.00357.Search in Google Scholar

Anderson, S. P., and J. J. Gabszewicz. 2006. “The Media and Advertising: A Tale of Two-Sided Markets.” In Handbook on the Economics of Art and Culture, vol. 1, 567–614. North Holland: Oxford, UK.10.1016/S1574-0676(06)01018-0Search in Google Scholar

Anderson, S. P., J. Waldfogel, and D. Stromberg, eds. 2016. Handbook of Media Economics, 1A. Amsterdam, Netherlands: Elsevier.Search in Google Scholar

Anderson, S. P., Ø. Foros, and H. J. Kind. 2018. “Competition for Advertisers and for Viewers in Media Markets.” The Economic Journal 128 (608): 34–54. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecoj.12428.Search in Google Scholar

Armstrong, M. 2005. “Public Service Broadcasting.” Fiscal Studies 26 (3): 281–99. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-5890.2005.00013.x.Search in Google Scholar

Armstrong, M. 2006. “Competition in Two-Sided Markets.” The RAND Journal of Economics 37 (3): 668–91. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1756-2171.2006.tb00037.x.Search in Google Scholar

Bel, G., and J. Calzada. 2007. “Access Pricing to a Digital Broadcasting Platform.” The Journal of Media Economics 20 (1): 29–53. https://doi.org/10.1080/08997760709337018.Search in Google Scholar

Belleflamme, P., and M. Peitz. 2018. “Platforms and Network Effects.” In Handbook of Game Theory and Industrial Organization, II. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.10.4337/9781788112789.00019Search in Google Scholar

Blair, R. D., and R. E. Romano. 1993. “Pricing Decisions of the Newspaper Monopolist.” Southern Economic Journal 59 (4): 721–32. https://doi.org/10.2307/1059734.Search in Google Scholar

Budzinski, O., and B. Kuchinke. 2020. “Industrial Organization of Media Markets and Competition Policy.” In Management and Economics of Communication, 21–46. Berlin, Germany: De Gruyter Mouton.10.1515/9783110589542-002Search in Google Scholar

Caillaud, B., and B. Jullien. 2003. “Chicken & Egg: Competition Among Intermediation Service Providers.” The RAND Journal of Economics 34 (2): 309–28. https://doi.org/10.2307/1593720.Search in Google Scholar

Calvano, E., and M. Polo. 2020. “Strategic Differentiation by Business Models: Free-To-Air and Pay-Tv.” The Economic Journal 130 (625): 50–64. https://doi.org/10.1093/ej/uez037.Search in Google Scholar

Calzada, J. 2009. “Access Charges under Two-Tier Pricing.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 35 (3): 296–311. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-008-9081-0.Search in Google Scholar

Calzada, J., and T. M. Valletti. 2008. “Network Competition and Entry Deterrence.” The Economic Journal 118 (531): 1223–44. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2008.02167.x.Search in Google Scholar

Casadesus-Masanell, R., and F. Zhu. 2010. “Strategies to Fight Ad-Sponsored Rivals.” Management Science 56 (9): 1484–99. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1100.1199.Search in Google Scholar

Choi, J. P. 2006. “Broadcast Competition and Advertising with Free Entry: Subscription vs. Free-To-Air.” Information Economics and Policy 18 (2): 181–96. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.infoecopol.2005.12.002.Search in Google Scholar

Crampes, C., C. Haritchabalet, and B. Jullien. 2009. “Advertising, Competition and Entry in Media Industries.” The Journal of Industrial Economics 57 (1): 7–31. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6451.2009.00368.x.Search in Google Scholar

Dietl, H., R. Fort, and M. Lang. 2013. “International Sport League Comparisons.” In Routledge Handbook of Sport Management. London, UK: Routledge.10.4324/9780203807224.ch28Search in Google Scholar

Dietl, H., M. Lang, and P. Lin. 2013. “Advertising Pricing Models in Media Markets: Lump-Sum versus Per-Consumer Charges.” Information Economics and Policy 25 (4): 257–71. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.infoecopol.2013.06.003.Search in Google Scholar

Economides, N., and J. Tag. 2012. “Network Neutrality on the Internet: A Two-Sided Market Analysis.” Information Economics and Policy 24 (2): 91–104. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.infoecopol.2012.01.001.Search in Google Scholar

Gabszewicz, J. J., D. Laussel, and N. Sonnac. 2001. “Press Advertising and the Ascent of the “Pensee Unique.” European Economic Review 45 (4–6): 641–51. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0014-2921(01)00139-8.Search in Google Scholar

Gabszewicz, J. J., D. Laussel, and N. Sonnac. 2002. “Press Advertising and the Political Differentiation of Newspapers.” Journal of Public Economic Theory 4 (3): 317–34. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9779.00100.Search in Google Scholar

Gabszewicz, J. J., D. Laussel, and N. Sonnac. 2004. “Programming and Advertising Competition in the Broadcasting Industry.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 13 (4): 657–69. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1430-9134.2004.00027.x.Search in Google Scholar

Gabszewicz, J. J., D. Laussel, and N. Sonnac. 2012. “Advertising and the Rise of Free Daily Newspapers.” Economica 79 (313): 137–51. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0335.2010.00867.x.Search in Google Scholar

Gal-Or, E., and A. Dukes. 2003. “Minimum Differentiation in Commercial Media Markets.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 12 (3): 291–325. https://doi.org/10.1162/105864003322309491.Search in Google Scholar

Grossmann, M., M. Lang, and H. Dietl. 2021. “A Dynamic Contest Model of Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets.” Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research 16 (6): 2091–109. https://doi.org/10.3390/jtaer16060117.Search in Google Scholar

Guttmann 2020. Global TV Advertising - Statistics and Facts. https://www.statista.com/topics/5952/television-advertising-worldwide (accessed January 5, 2021).Search in Google Scholar

Kaiser, U., and M. Song. 2009. “Do media Consumers Really Dislike Advertising? an Empirical Assessment of the Role of Advertising in Print Media Markets.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 27 (2): 292–301. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2008.09.003.Search in Google Scholar

Kaiser, U., and J. Wright. 2006. “Price Structure in Two-Sided Markets: Evidence from the Magazine Industry.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 24 (1): 1–28. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2005.06.002.Search in Google Scholar

Kind, H., T. Nilssen, and L. Sorgard. 2009. “Business Models for Media Firms: Does Competition Matter for How They Raise Revenue?” Marketing Science 28 (6): 1112–28. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1090.0514.Search in Google Scholar

Lin, P. 2011. “Market Provision of Program Quality in the Television Broadcasting Industry.” The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 11 (1): 1–17. https://doi.org/10.2202/1935-1682.2805.Search in Google Scholar

Peitz, M., and T. M. Valletti. 2008. “Content and Advertising in the Media: Pay-Tv versus Free-To-Air.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 26 (4): 949–65. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2007.08.003.Search in Google Scholar

Reisinger, M. 2012. “Platform Competition for Advertisers and Users in Media Markets.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 30 (2): 243–52. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2011.10.002.Search in Google Scholar

Rochet, J. C., and J. Tirole. 2003. “Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets.” Journal of the European Economic Association 1 (4): 990–1029. https://doi.org/10.1162/154247603322493212.Search in Google Scholar

Rysman, M. 2004. “Competition between Networks: A Study of the Market for Yellow Pages.” The Review of Economic Studies 71 (2): 483–512. https://doi.org/10.1111/0034-6527.00512.Search in Google Scholar

Sun, H. M., C. M. Chen, and C. Z. Shieh. 2008. “Flexible-pay-per-channel: A New Model for Content Access Control in Pay-TV Broadcasting Systems.” IEEE Transactions on Multimedia 10 (6): 1109–20. https://doi.org/10.1109/tmm.2008.2001381.Search in Google Scholar

Tag, J. 2009. “Paying to Remove Advertisements.” Information Economics and Policy 21 (4): 245–52. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.infoecopol.2009.02.001.Search in Google Scholar

TVB. 2021. TVB Media Comparisons Study 2021. https://www.tvb.org/Public/Research/MediaComparisonsStudy.aspx (accessed January 28, 2021).Search in Google Scholar

Weyl, E. G. 2010. “A Price Theory of Multi-Sided Platforms.” The American Economic Review 100 (4): 1642–72. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.4.1642.Search in Google Scholar

Wilbur, K. 2008. “A Two-Sided, Empirical Model of Television Advertising and Viewing Markets.” Marketing Science 27 (3): 356–78. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1070.0303.Search in Google Scholar

Wright, J. 2004. “The Determinants of Optimal Interchange Fees in Payment Systems.” The Journal of Industrial Economics 52 (1): 1–26. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0022-1821.2004.00214.x.Search in Google Scholar

Received: 2021-05-18
Accepted: 2022-02-07
Published Online: 2022-03-03

© 2022 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 8.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2021-0068/html
Scroll to top button