Abstract
A previous study finds that increased competition in health care markets improves social welfare, although consumers use “too much” health care when they have health insurance. The analysis assumes that consumers have a constant Arrow-Pratt coefficient of absolute risk aversion. This note shows that this finding can be extended to the case where consumers are simply risk averse. Furthermore, if insurers offered insurance policies with slightly lower usage prices than the equilibrium level, social welfare would be improved.
1 Introduction
In the health economics literature, it is often suggested that particular distortions in health care markets imply that competition may not be socially desirable (Crew 1969). Health insurance often leads to out-of-pocket usage prices that are less than the marginal costs of medical services. Health insurance thus generates deadweight loss by encouraging too much consumption of the services. Therefore, reducing competition would raise usage prices that are “too low,” and thus may be desirable. Gaynor, Hass-Wilson, and Vogt (GHV) argue that this view cannot be correct if insurance markets are competitive or monopolistic. They find that “provided that price exceeds marginal cost in the medical market, the benefit to consumers of a price decrease outweighs the loss in profits suffered by the medical industry” (GHV 2000, 1001).
GHV’s (2000) finding has important policy implications in health care regulation. However, the analysis is based on a specific exponential Bernoulli utility function,
[1]
In a related paper, Wigger and Anlauf (2007) study the role of market power in health care markets. They consider a market with a monopolistic drug provider and competitive insurers. Consumers are either healthy or sick. In the latter case, they have demands for drugs. Consumers choose an insurance contract (characterized by a premium and a co-insurance rate) before the monopolist chooses a drug price. Wigger and Anlauf show that when the marginal cost of the drug is strictly positive, a marginal increase in the co-insurance rate, starting from the market equilibrium level, lowers social welfare. The present note shows that a marginal increase in the out-of-pocket usage price from the equilibrium level always reduces social welfare. The findings are in contrast to the view of Crew (1969).
2 Model
Consider a standard insurance model. There is a continuum of consumers who are homogeneous ex ante. They face independent health shocks. Each consumer has the following utility function:
In expression [1],
The game played in the market has the following timing. First, health care providers interact and determine the market price of health care. Second, insurance firms offer insurance policies. Third, consumers decide to accept or refuse the policies. Fourth, health states are realized and consumers choose their quantity demanded of health care. As in GHV (2000), the interaction among health care providers is not explicitly modeled here. A lower market price represents more intensive competition in the health care market.
3 Invisible hands are good hands
The model is solved through backward induction. Conditional on insurance policy
The demand for health care
Hence, the consumer’s ex post demand for health care
and
The Envelop Theorem implies that
At the second stage, the insurance firms offer the most attractive policy that is not money-losing. Given health care price
Constraint [9] must be binding because of competition. The problem can be rewritten as an unconstrained problem
where
If problem [8] or [10] has multiple (or a compact set of) solutions, we shall assumed that the insurers always choose the solution that has the lowest usage price (and the highest premium). Indeed, while the consumers and insurers are indifferent to any of the solutions, the health care providers strictly prefer the solution with the lowest usage price, which induces the highest consumption of health care. Hence, there is a unique Pareto optimal policy. Such a policy is written as
Given health care price
The solution of problem [10] satisfies the following first-order condition:
Since
The insurance makes health care providers better off by increasing consumer demand for health care. The insurance also makes consumers better off by (partially) insuring them from health shocks. Therefore, insurers bring a Pareto improvement to society.
When the health care market is highly competitive, it is likely that health insurance generates ex post deadweight loss. For example, if
Usage price
First we note that
However, with eq. [11],
This conflicts with eq. [12]. Hence,
The per capita health care industry’s expected profit is
Note that the consumer is only a representative of many consumers. She is unable to noticeably influence the per capita profits by adjusting her health care consumption. Hence she takes the per capita profits as exogenously given. Because of the separability inside
Corresponding to Proposition 2 of GHV (2000), the following result implies that social welfare
Expected social welfare
Let
The insurance policy is endogenous. From eq. [11], [4]
Substituting into eq. [16],
Since
From eq. [15], it can be seen that the price of health care p influences (expected) social welfare through and only through the usage price
This problem differs from problem [10] only by the
Given health care price
The socially optimal usage price is given by the following problem:
where
Since
Proposition 2 resembles a finding in Wigger and Anlauf (2007), but the two models differ in the number of health states, modeling of insurance contracts, and timing of the games. Wigger and Anlauf assume two health states (“healthy” and “sick”), an insurance contract is characterized by a premium and a co-insurance rate, and consumers choose an insurance contract before the monopolistic drug provider chooses a price. GHV (2000) and the present note, instead, assume a continuum of health states. An insurance contract is characterized by a premium and an out-of-pocket usage price, and based on the given health care price. Wigger and Anlauf (2007) find that a marginal increase in the co-insurance rate, starting from the market equilibrium level, leaves social welfare unaffected if the marginal cost of the drug is zero, and lowers social welfare if the marginal cost is positive. The present note finds that a marginal increase in the out-of-pocket usage price from the equilibrium level always lowers social welfare, whether the marginal cost is zero or positive.
4 Conclusion
Gaynor et al. (2000) find that “invisible hands are good hands” in health care industries. As the authors suggest, their model ignores income effects on consumer choices: “the separability inside (the Bernoulli utility function) v guarantees that there are no income effects ex post. The assumption of an exponential form for v guarantees that there are no income effects ex ante” (GHV 2000, 999).
I show that the assumption of “an exponential form for v” is unnecessary, i. e., the findings hold as long as consumers are risk-averse. Whether the assumption of “separability inside v” can also be dropped calls for future study. I also show that if competitive insurance firms offered policies with slightly lower usage prices than the equilibrium level, social welfare would be improved.
References
Crew, M. 1969. “Coinsurance and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care.” American Economic Review 59:906–8.Suche in Google Scholar
Gaynor, M., D. Hass-Wilson, and W. B. Vogt. 2000. “Are Invisible Hands Good Hands? Moral Hazard, Competition, and the Second-Best in Health Care Markets.” Journal of Political Economy 108:992–1005.10.3386/w6865Suche in Google Scholar
Mas-Colell, A., M. D. Whinston, and J. R. Green. 1995. Microeconomic Theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Suche in Google Scholar
Schmidt, K. D. 2003. “On the Covariance of Monotone Functions of a Random Variable.” Department of Mathematics, Technical University of Dresden. http://www.math.tu-dresden.de/sto/schmidt/dsvm/dsvm2003-4.pdf (accessed August 22, 2016).Suche in Google Scholar
Wigger, B. U., and M. Anlauf. 2007. “Do Consumers Purchase Too Much Health Insurance? The Role of Market Power in Health-Care Markets.” Journal of Public Economic Theory 9:547–61.10.1111/j.1467-9779.2007.00319.xSuche in Google Scholar
©2017 by De Gruyter
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Research Articles
- Economising, Strategising and the Vertical Boundaries of the firm
- Tight and Loose Coupling in Organizations
- Managerial Reputation, Risk-Taking, and Imperfect Capital Markets
- Simple Unawareness in Dynamic Psychological Games
- Better Product Quality May Lead to Lower Product Price
- Technology Licensing between Rival Firms in Presence of Asymmetric Information
- Risk-Averse Managers, Labour Market Structures, Public Policies and Discrimination
- Revisiting Multiplicity of Bubble Equilibria in a Search Model with Posted Prices
- Notes
- Welfare Analysis in an Extended Harris-Todaro Model: An Application of the Atkinson Theorem
- Are Invisible Hands Good Hands in Health Care Markets? Extension
- A Short Note on Discrimination and Favoritism in the Labor Market
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Research Articles
- Economising, Strategising and the Vertical Boundaries of the firm
- Tight and Loose Coupling in Organizations
- Managerial Reputation, Risk-Taking, and Imperfect Capital Markets
- Simple Unawareness in Dynamic Psychological Games
- Better Product Quality May Lead to Lower Product Price
- Technology Licensing between Rival Firms in Presence of Asymmetric Information
- Risk-Averse Managers, Labour Market Structures, Public Policies and Discrimination
- Revisiting Multiplicity of Bubble Equilibria in a Search Model with Posted Prices
- Notes
- Welfare Analysis in an Extended Harris-Todaro Model: An Application of the Atkinson Theorem
- Are Invisible Hands Good Hands in Health Care Markets? Extension
- A Short Note on Discrimination and Favoritism in the Labor Market