Home Household saving in Australia
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

Household saving in Australia

  • Richard Finlay EMAIL logo and Fiona Price
Published/Copyright: April 3, 2015

Abstract

This paper investigates household saving behavior in Australia, as well as the drivers behind the recent rise in the aggregate household saving ratio. Our results explaining differences in saving behavior across households are consistent with theory and previous findings. As might be expected, households’ saving ratios tend to increase with income, but decrease with wealth and gearing. More at-risk households such as single-parent and migrant households tend to save more than other households, all else being equal. While saving differs substantially across age groups we find that, at least in part, this reflects differing circumstances. Our results suggest that the rise in household saving between 2003/2004 and 2009/2010 was driven by changes in behavior rather than changes in population characteristics: in particular, more educated households, as well as households with high debt and/or wealth increased their propensity to save. Our interpretation of these results is that a reduction in future income growth expectations for more highly educated households after the financial crisis, and an associated effort to rebuild wealth and repay debt, drove to the aggregate rise in household saving.

JEL classification numbers: D14; E21

Corresponding author: Richard Finlay, Reserve Bank of Australia, 65 Martin Place, NSW 2000, Australia; and School of Economics, University of New South Wales, NSW 2052, Australia, e-mail:

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank Tiago Cavalcanti, Alex Heath, Jonathan Kearns, Christopher Kent, Gianni La Cava, Peter Tulip and an anonymous referee for helpful comments. Any errors are our own. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Reserve Bank of Australia.

Appendix A: A simple model of age, cohort and time effects

This model follows the approach of Deaton and Paxson (1994) and Chamon and Prasad (2010), and provides a simple way to disentangle age and birth cohort effects to find their “pure” effect on saving.[11]

With no shocks to income and a constant real interest rate, the life-cycle hypothesis suggests household consumption can be expressed as:

Cab;h=f(a)×Wb×eεab;h.

Here Cab;h denotes consumption for household h where the household head is aged a and belongs to birth cohort b, f(a) describes how consumption varies with age, Wb denotes the average lifetime resources of households from birth cohort b, and eεab;h is a (multiplicative) household-specific idiosyncratic shock.

Taking logs and averaging consumption over households in the same age (a) and birth cohort (b) gives

ln(Cab)¯=lnf(a)¯+lnWb¯,

where the age effect – f(a) – is assumed to depend on age but not birth cohort, while lifetime resources – Wb – are assumed to depend on birth cohort but not age. We then use dummy variables to decompose the age, birth cohort and time (i.e., unexplained) components of consumption

ln(Cab)¯=Daαc+Dbβc+Dtγc,

Where Da, Db and Dt correspond to age, birth cohort and time dummy variables, and αc, βc and γc correspond to the coefficients capturing age, birth cohort and time effects on consumption.

Since a household’s birth cohort is simply a function of the survey year and their age, we need to place some restrictions on the coefficients in this model to enable identification. Following Chamon and Prasad (2010), the birth cohort effects are constrained to sum to zero and be orthogonal to a linear trend:[12]

Σi=1nβc(i)=0andΣi=1n(βc(i)×i)=0.

Household income (Y) can be modeled in a similar way as

ln(Yab)¯=Daαy+Dbβy+Dtγy,

where αy, βy and γy correspond to the coefficients capturing age, birth cohort and time effects on income. Similar constraints apply: Σiβy(i)=0 and Σi(βy(ii)=0.

Combining the results of the income and consumption models gives the effect that age, birth cohort and time have on household saving, where household saving ratios are calculated as the difference between the fitted values of the dependent income and consumption variables. Figures A1–A3 show the estimated effect of age, birth cohort and time respectively, assuming the other effects are held constant. Our reference household for this analysis is a household head aged 30–34 surveyed in 2009/2010. Note that the level of saving shown in the figures depends on the reference household chosen, but the profile of saving does not, so one should focus on how saving changes for different age, birth cohort or time groups, rather than the level of saving per se.

Focusing on the age effect, Figure A1 shows how the average household’s saving ratio varies with age, holding the survey year and birth cohort constant. The distribution of the age effect partially exhibits the concave relationship predicted by the standard life-cycle model; saving is low early and late in life, and high during a household’s working years. One anomaly stands out from the standard life-cycle prediction, however: the dip around middle-age (30–50 years), when households reduce their saving before building it back up when they enter the pre-retirement age group.[13]

Figure A1: Effect of age on saving.Notes: Gross of depreciation; average by group; survey year=2009/2010, birth cohort=1975–1980.Sources: ABS; authors’ calculations.
Figure A1:

Effect of age on saving.

Notes: Gross of depreciation; average by group; survey year=2009/2010, birth cohort=1975–1980.

Sources: ABS; authors’ calculations.

A possible explanation for this that accords with a slightly amended life-cycle model is simply that costs increase around middle age. Younger households have relatively few living costs and so are able to save for a down-payment on a house, while middle-aged households have children and must pay mortgage interest. The behavior is also consistent with a myopic model of household behavior. For example, Thaler and Shefrin (1981) argue that hyperbolic discounting can explain why younger households tend not to save enough for retirement, while Carroll and Samwick (1997) argue that younger households place more weight on saving for large purchases and emergencies to smooth near-term consumption rather than saving for longer-term (retirement) consumption.

Figure A2 shows how the average household saving ratio varies with birth cohort, holding the survey year and age of the household head constant; the effects are less clear than those for age, although they suggest that the baby boomer cohort (born between 1946 and 1964) saves more than other birth cohorts throughout their lives.

Figure A2: Effect of birth cohort on saving.Notes: Gross of depreciation; average by group; survey year=2009/2010, age=30–34.Sources: ABS; authors’ calculations.
Figure A2:

Effect of birth cohort on saving.

Notes: Gross of depreciation; average by group; survey year=2009/2010, age=30–34.

Sources: ABS; authors’ calculations.

Time effects in this model represent all determinants of saving not relating to age or birth cohort. Between the 1998/1999 and 2003/2004 Surveys, the time effect on saving is found to be negligible; on the other hand, the time effect between the 2003/2004 and 2009/2010 Surveys is large and positive (Figure A3).

Figure A3: Effect of survey year on saving.Notes: Gross of depreciation; average by group; birth cohort=1975–1980, age=30–34.Sources: ABS; authors’ calculation.
Figure A3:

Effect of survey year on saving.

Notes: Gross of depreciation; average by group; birth cohort=1975–1980, age=30–34.

Sources: ABS; authors’ calculation.

Appendix B: Auxiliary regressions

B.1 Permanent income model

Since we cannot observe a household’s permanent level of income, we estimate it by separately regressing current labor income (for those in the labor force) and non-labor income on proxies for permanent income, and taking the fitted values as measuring permanent income (Table B1).

Table B1

Permanent income models.

Coefficients
Variable2003/20042009/2010
Labor incomeNon-labor incomeLabor incomeNon-labor income
Highly educated0.1***–0.1***0.2***0.0
Migrant–0.1*0.0–0.2***0.0
Female–0.2***0.2***–0.1*0.2***
State
 – Vic–0.10.2***0.0–0.1***
 – Qld–0.1*0.2***–0.1–0.1**
 – SA–0.2*0.4***–0.10.1
 – WA–0.3***0.2***0.0–0.2***
 – TAS0.00.3***–0.30.1
 – ACT and NT0.00.3**0.4***0.1
Non-urban–0.4***0.1**–0.2***–0.1***
Middle-skilled occupation–0.3***–0.3***
Low-skilled occupation–0.3***–0.2***
Young0.2***–0.4***0.2***–0.3***
Pre-retired–0.2***0.5***–0.1**0.5***
Old–2.2***0.7***–1.0***0.8***
Number in work1.0***1.1***
Household size0.4***0.5***
Self-funded retiree0.6***0.4***
Small business owner1.2***1.2***
Non-financial wealth1.6***0.1***
Financial wealth0.3***0.8***
Government payments1.3***1.0***
Constant5.9***2.9***5.8***3.9***
R20.150.420.130.30

***, ** and * indicate significance at the 1, 5 and 10% level, respectively.

Sources: ABS; authors’ calculations.

B.2 Risk of unemployment model

For households with no unemployed members and a household head aged >65 years, the risk of unemployment variable is set equal to one if the fitted value of a logit regression of unemployment status on a range of household characteristics is >10%. In particular, for unemployedit representing a dummy variable that equals one if household i has at least one unemployed person in survey t, and zero otherwise, we model unemployedit using a number of independent variables as detailed in Table B2.

Table B2

Risk of unemployment models.

Coefficients
Variable2003/20042009/2010
Highly educated–0.6***–0.2
Migrant0.3*0.4***
Female0.5***0.4***
State
 – Vic–0.10.0
 – Qld0.00.1
 – SA0.10.1
 – WA0.10.0
 – TAS0.00.1
 – ACT and NT–0.2–0.7**
Non-urban0.00.1
Young0.20.1
Pre-retired0.00.4**
Old–1.0***–1.6***
Household size0.3***0.4***
Constant–3.3***–4.0***
R20.060.07

***, ** and * indicate significance at the 1, 5 and 10% level, respectively.

Sources: ABS; authors’ calculations.

B.3 Median and mean regression models

Tables B3 and B4 present full median and mean regression outputs for two models: the model used in the main text [Model (1)], and an alternate model where we drop the income variable [Model (2)]. For both tables, ***, ** and * indicate significance at the 1, 5 and 10% level, respectively, where 300 repetitions of bootstrapped HES household weights are used to obtain standard errors.

Table B3

Median regression models.

Coefficients
Variable2003/20042009/2010
(1)(2)(1)(2)
Income elasticity0.04***na0.04***na
Highly educated–4.7***–4.7***1.91.6
Income (>20%)
 – Business8.4***3.54.3–2.9
 – Salary10.6***16.3***2.812.7***
 – Government–4.5*–3.3–0.8–0.5
 – Other–5.1**–6.2**–10.1***–6.8***
Risk of unemployment0.70.9–1.0–2.2
Low-skilled occupation–5.1**–5.5***–2.5–1.6
Middle-skilled occupation–6.5***–7.2***–2.9**–2.3
Not in the labor force–9.1**–2.3–9.9**0.7
Self-funded retiree–19.0***–15.9***–8.3**–3.4
Pensioner–10.2**–4.4–11.7***–3.4
Household size2.7***2.4***2.3**2.6**
Share of children–23.0***–22.5***–24.4***–22.9***
Female–3.8***–4.8***–3.4**–3.0**
Single-parent household8.0**10.7***5.2**5.4**
Married–3.9**–4.6**–0.4–1.9
Migrant2.42.32.8*2.5
Wealth-to-income ratio–0.10.0–0.2***–0.1*
Gearing ratio–13.8***–15.8***–2.4–2.0
Mortgage–2.93.5*–3.9*2.8
Own home outright1.26.1***3.99.0***
Credit constrained2.92.20.10.3
Worse off than a year ago–6.3***–5.6***–4.1***–3.8***
No of credit cards–1.8***–1.6***–0.9–0.7
Personal debt–14.6***–15.8***–15.6***–17.9***
State
 – Vic–0.7–0.70.20.6
 – Qld1.01.41.41.6
 – SA1.41.05.6***6.3***
 – WA0.20.14.1**4.8***
 – TAS–0.9–1.1–0.6–1.9
 – ACT and NT–3.6–4.4*4.7**4.9**
Non-urban0.61.1–0.4–0.3
Young–0.8–0.1–0.32.0
Pre-retired0.3–0.76.8***5.1***
Old10.1**7.5*7.9*7.1*
Constant17.0***9.0**14.7***–0.3
R20.060.050.060.05
Table B4

Mean regression models.

Coefficients
Variable2003/20042009/2010
(1)(2)(1)(2)
Income elasticity0.05***na0.04***na
Highly educated–2.5**–2.6**3.0***3.0***
Income (>20%)
 – Business11.4***6.5***9.9***5.1***
 – Salary4.2*14.3***2.611.4***
 – Government–9.5***–8.5***–3.0*–1.3
 – Other–12.7***–12.2***–13.8***–12.2***
Risk of unemployment1.41.9–0.6–0.3
Low-skilled occupation–4.6***–5.0***2.51.8
Middle-skilled occupation–5.1***–5.6***–1.1–1.5
Not in the labor force–12.9***–2.6–8.5***–0.4
Self-funded retiree–8.4***–8.3***3.4*2.6
Pensioner–7.0*–1.4–9.9***–4.7*
Household size2.0***1.3*2.8***2.5***
Share of children–21.4***–20.8***–28.5***–27.7***
Female–3.9***–4.4***–2.5**–3.1***
Single-parent household8.8***11.4***4.8**5.1**
Married–3.0*–2.8*0.3–0.7
Migrant2.5*2.24.6***4.7***
Wealth-to-income ratio–0.1***–0.1***–0.1***0.0
Gearing ratio–15.9***–15.9***–10.1***–9.7***
Mortgage–3.8**2.6*–1.54.0***
Own home outright1.26.3***3.6**7.1***
Credit constrained1.31.5–2.2–1.7
Worse off than a year ago–5.1***–5.2***–3.0***–3.3***
No of credit cards–1.1**–0.9*–0.3–0.2
Personal debt–17.5***–19***–15.4***–17.3***
State
 – Vic–0.1–0.4–1.3–1.4
 – Qld–0.7–0.4–0.4–0.2
 – SA–0.4–0.14.7***4.8***
 – WA0.40.72.32.4
 – TAS–1.0–1.7–1.6–1.0
 – ACT and NT–2.1–1.94.33.9
Non-urban0.71.2–0.8–0.6
Young–1.1–0.31.22.8**
Pre-retired–0.5–1.54.4***3.9***
Old4.35.75.8**6.2**
Constant19.8***7.3**8.5***–3.0
R20.120.100.120.09

References

ABS (Australian Bureau of Statistics). 2008. “Experimental Estimates of Imputed Rent Australia.” Information Paper, ABS Cat No 6525.0.Search in Google Scholar

Alan, S., T. Crossley, and H. Low. 2012. “Saving on a Rainy Day, Borrowing for a Rainy Day.” IFS Working Paper W12/11.10.1920/wp.ifs.2012.1211Search in Google Scholar

Attanasio, O. P. 1999. “Consumption.” In Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1B, edited by J. B. Taylor and M. Woodford, 741–812. Handbooks in Economics 15, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.10.1016/S1574-0048(99)10019-3Search in Google Scholar

Attanasio, O. P., and G. Weber. 1994. “The UK Consumption Boom of the Late 1980s: Aggregate Implications of Microeconomic Evidence.” The Economic Journal 104 (427): 1269–1302.10.2307/2235449Search in Google Scholar

Attanasio, O. P. and G. Weber. 2010. “Consumption and Saving: Models of Intertemporal Allocation and Their Implications for Public Policy.” Journal of Economic Literature 48 (3): 693–751.10.1257/jel.48.3.693Search in Google Scholar

Berger-Thomson, L., E. Chung, and R. McKibbin. 2009. “Estimating Marginal Propensities to Consume in Australia Using Micro Data.” RBA Research Discussion Paper No 2009-07.10.1111/j.1475-4932.2010.00660.xSearch in Google Scholar

Blinder, A. S. 1973. “Wage Discrimination: Reduced Form and Structural Estimates.” The Journal of Human Resources 8 (4): 436–455.10.2307/144855Search in Google Scholar

Browning, M., and A. Lusardi. 1996. “Household Saving: Micro Theories and Micro Facts.” Journal of Economic Literature 34 (4): 1797–1855.Search in Google Scholar

Brzozowski, M., and T. F. Crossley. 2011. “Viewpoint: Measuring the Well-Being of the Poor with Income or Consumption: A Canadian Perspective.” The Canadian Journal of Economics 44 (1): 88–106.10.1111/j.1540-5982.2010.01624.xSearch in Google Scholar

Carroll, C. D. 1992. “The Buffer-Stock Theory of Saving: Some Macroeconomic Evidence.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1992 (2): 61–156.10.2307/2534582Search in Google Scholar

Carroll, C. D., and A. A. Samwick. 1997. “The Nature of Precautionary Wealth.” Journal of Monetary Economics 40 (1): 41–71.10.1016/S0304-3932(97)00036-6Search in Google Scholar

Chamon, M. D. and E. S. Prasad. 2010. “Why are Saving Rates of Urban Households in China Rising?.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2 (1): 93–130.10.1257/mac.2.1.93Search in Google Scholar

Deaton, A. S. 1991. “Saving and Liquidity Restraints.” Econometrica 59 (5): 1221–1248.10.2307/2938366Search in Google Scholar

Deaton, A. S., and C. H. Paxson. 1994. “Saving, Growth, and Aging in Taiwan.” In Studies in the Economics of Aging, edited by D. A. Wise, 331–357. National Bureau of Economic Research Project Report, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.10.3386/w4330Search in Google Scholar

Dvornak, N., and M. Kohler. 2003. “Housing Wealth, Stock Market Wealth and Consumption: A Panel Analysis for Australia.” RBA Research Discussion Paper No 2003-07.Search in Google Scholar

Dynan, K. E., and D. L. Kohn. 2007. “The Rise in US Household Indebtedness: Causes and Consequences.” In The Structure and Resilience of the Financial System, edited by C. Kent and J. Lawson, 84–113. Proceedings of a Conference, Reserve Bank of Australia, Sydney.10.17016/FEDS.2007.37Search in Google Scholar

Dynan, K. E., J. Skinner, and S. P. Zeldes. 2004. “Do the Rich Save More?.” Journal of Political Economy 112 (2): 397–444.10.1086/381475Search in Google Scholar

Finlay, R., and J. P. Jääskelä. 2014. “Credit Supply Shocks and the Global Financial Crisis in Three Small Open Economies.” Journal of Macroeconomics 40: 270–276.10.1016/j.jmacro.2014.01.006Search in Google Scholar

Harris, M. N., J. Loundes, and E. Webster. 2002. “Determinants of Household Saving in Australia.” Economic Record 78 (241): 207–223.10.1111/1475-4932.00024Search in Google Scholar

Iacoviello, M. 2004. “Consumption, House Prices, and Collateral Constraints: A Structural Econometric Analysis.” Journal of Housing Economics 13 (4): 304–320.10.1016/j.jhe.2004.09.004Search in Google Scholar

Islam, A., J. Parasnis, and D. Fausten. 2013. “Do Immigrants Save Less than Natives? Immigrant and Native Saving Behaviour in Australia.” Economic Record 89 (284): 52–71.10.1111/1475-4932.12000Search in Google Scholar

Meyer, B. D., and J. X. Sullivan. 2011. “Viewpoint: Further Results on Measuring the Well-Being of the Poor using Income and Consumption.” The Canadian Journal of Economics 44 (1): 52–87.10.1111/j.1540-5982.2010.01623.xSearch in Google Scholar

Muellbauer, J. 2007. “Housing and Personal Wealth in a Global Context.” WIDER (World Institute for Development Economics Research) Research Paper No 2007/27.Search in Google Scholar

Oaxaca, R. 1973. “Male-Female Wage Differentials in Urban Labor Markets.” International Economic Review 14 (3): 693–709.10.2307/2525981Search in Google Scholar

Reserve Bank of Australia. 2008. “Financial Stability Review.” September. Available at: http://www.rba.gov.au/publications/fsr/2008/sep/pdf/0908.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Sabelhaus, J., and J. A. Groen. 2000. “Can Permanent-Income Theory Explain Cross-Sectional Consumption Patterns?.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 82 (3): 431–438.10.1162/003465300558920Search in Google Scholar

Thaler, R. H., and H. M. Shefrin. 1981. “An Economic Theory of Self-Control.” Journal of Political Economy 89 (2): 392–406.10.1086/260971Search in Google Scholar

Windsor, C., J. Jääskelä, and R. Finlay. 2015. “Housing Wealth Effects: Evidence from an Australian Panel.” Economica forthcoming.10.1111/ecca.12137Search in Google Scholar

Yates, J., and S. Whelan. 2009. Housing Wealth and Consumer Spending, AHURI Final Report No 132, Melbourne: Australian Housing and Urban Research Institute.Search in Google Scholar

Zeldes, S. P. 1989. “Consumption and Liquidity Constraints: An Empirical Investigation.” Journal of Political Economy 97 (2): 305–346.10.1086/261605Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2015-4-3
Published in Print: 2015-7-1

©2015 by De Gruyter

Downloaded on 21.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejm-2014-0077/html?lang=en
Scroll to top button