Abstract
We provide a new reason for the consumer surplus and welfare raising cross ownership. We show that cross ownership reduces the tax rate, and increases consumer surplus and welfare under Cournot and Bertrand competition when the marginal social cost/benefit of public funds is less than unity. We further show that Cournot competition creates higher consumer surplus and welfare compared to Bertrand competition if the marginal social cost/benefit of public funds is less than unity, thus providing a new reason for the Cournot-Bertrand welfare reversal.
1 Introduction
Passive cross ownership, which refers to a situation where a firm holds non-controlling shares in other firms, has grown significantly in recent decades, and can be found in several industries, such as automobile (Alley 1997), IT (Gilo, Moshe, and Spiegel 2006), telecommunications (Brito, Cabral, and Vasconcelos 2014), banking (Azar, Raina, and Schmalz 2022), airline (Clayton and Jorgensen 2005), and cement industries (Davallou, Soltaninejad, and Tahmasebi 2015). While cross ownership among the rival firms reduces welfare by contracting outputs (Bresnahan and Salop 1986; O’Brien and Salop 2000; Reynolds and Snapp 1986; Shelegia and Spiegel 2012), it may increase welfare by reducing production inefficiency under asymmetric costs of production (Fanti 2015; Farrell and Shapiro 1990; Ma, Qin, and Zeng 2024), increasing R&D investments (López and Vives 2019), reducing input prices (Chen, Matsumura, and Zeng 2024; Symeonidis 2008), reallocating outputs through quality choice (Bayona and López 2018), and affecting horizontal product differentiation (Banerjee, Mukherjee, and Poddar 2024; Fang, Huang, and Zeng 2024).
We provide a new reason for the consumer surplus and welfare raising cross ownership in the presence of strategic tax/subsidy policies. It is well known that governments may use tax/subsidy policies to improve welfare by reducing the distortion of the imperfectly competitive product market (Hamilton 1999; Myles 1996). However, the literature on cross ownership did not pay much attention to the effects of strategic tax/subsidy policies. We fill this gap in the literature.
We show that a higher percentage of cross ownership increases the subsidy rate (or decreases the tax rate), and increases consumer surplus and welfare if the marginal social cost/benefit of public funds is less than unity.[1] We first show this result under symmetric cross ownership and Cournot competition. We then show that the result holds under asymmetric cross ownership, and Bertrand competition.
The reason for our result is as follows. For a given tax/subsidy rate, a higher percentage of cross ownership tends to reduce consumer surplus and welfare by increasing collusive behavior in the product market. On the other hand, a higher percentage of cross ownership tends to increase consumer surplus and welfare by increasing the subsidy rate (or decreasing the tax rate). The second effect can dominate the first effect and a higher percentage of cross ownership can increase consumer surplus and welfare if the marginal social cost/benefit of public funds is less than unity.
Using a specific demand function, we also show that consumer surplus and welfare can be higher under Cournot competition compared to Bertrand competition if the marginal social cost/benefit of public funds is less than unity. Thus, we contribute to the literature on Cournot-Bertrand welfare comparison (see, Arya, Mittendorf, and Sappington 2008; Mukherjee 2011; Singh and Vives 1984).
Liu, Mukherjee, and Wang (2015) showed consumer surplus and welfare raising horizontal merger in a Cournot oligopoly under pollution and strategic tax policy. In contrast, there is no pollution in our paper, and our result holds for partial cooperation between the firms due to cross ownership. Further, we show our results under both Cournot and Bertrand competition, and also contribute to the literature on Cournot-Bertrand welfare comparison.
Cheng, Wu, and Zeng (2024) showed that cross ownership might benefit the consumers under strategic tax policy provided the firms have asymmetric costs. Unlike that paper, we show our results under symmetric costs. The marginal social cost/benefit of public funds is important for our results. We also show the welfare implications and Cournot-Bertrand welfare reversal.
Fershtman and Judd (1987) showed that incentive delegation by the owners to the managers increases (decreases) welfare under Cournot (Bertrand) competition by encouraging the managers to produce more (less) outputs compared to no incentive delegation. In contrast, there is no incentive delegation in our paper but the owners of firms hold non-controlling shares in the rival firms. Cross ownership can increase consumer surplus and welfare under both Cournot and Bertrand competition by reducing the tax rates.
Hamilton and Requate (2004) consider the “third country” model of Brander and Spencer (1985) with domestic polluting input markets and vertical contracts between the domestic input suppliers and domestic final goods producers. Vertical contracts in their paper eliminate the need for export promotion policies to improve welfare of the countries. In contrast, there are no vertical contracts, no pollution, and no competition between different governments in our paper. In our analysis, cross ownership between the final goods producers reduce the tax rate to improve welfare.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the model under Cournot competition and shows the results. Section 3 shows the results under Bertrand competition. Section 4 provides Cournot-Bertrand welfare comparison. Section 5 concludes. The case of asymmetric cross ownership under Cournot competition is in the Online Appendix.
2 The Model: Cournot Competition
Assume that firms 1 and 2 produce horizontally differentiated products and compete in quantities. Each firm holds
Consider the utility function of a representative consumer as
We consider the following game. Given the cross ownership, the government determines the tax rate t (subsidy rate if t is negative) in the first stage to maximize social welfare. In the second stage, firms choose their outputs simultaneously and the profits are realized. We solve the game through backward induction.
In the second stage, firms 1 and 2 maximize the following expressions to determine q 1 and q 2 respectively:
The equilibrium outputs are determined by differentiating (1) and (2) with respect to q
1 and q
2 respectively and solving the first order conditions. However, given our symmetric structure, the symmetric equilibrium outputs, q, can be found from the following first order condition that is created by differentiating (1) by q
1, and using the conditions q
1 = q
2 = q and
where
Lemma 1:
Proof:
We get from (3),
and
■
The results shown in Lemma 1, i.e., a higher marginal cost as well as a higher percentage of cross ownership reduce the equilibrium outputs, are known. However, these results indicate that a higher percentage of cross ownership may increase consumer surplus and welfare if it reduces the tax rate. We will show below the required condition for this to happen.
Now look at the first stage where the government sets the tax rate. With the symmetric equilibrium outputs, we can write the utility function as
The welfare maximizing tax rate is determined from
Given the symmetric equilibrium outputs, we get
It follows from (5) that t < 0 for λ ≤ 1, but t can be positive for λ > 1.
We assume that the second order condition for welfare maximization holds, i.e.,
We assume that
Using the implicit function theorem, we get from (5)
where
The above discussion gives the following result immediately.
Lemma 2:
A higher percentage of cross ownership reduces the equilibrium tax rate, i.e.,
The above result suggests that a higher percentage of cross ownership reduces the tax rate, i.e.,
We consider
Now consider the effects of a higher percentage of cross ownership on the equilibrium consumer surplus and welfare. First, look at the effects on consumer surplus. The equilibrium consumer surplus is
Since
Proposition 1:
If
As mentioned in the introduction, a higher percentage of cross ownership tends to reduce consumer surplus by reducing the equilibrium output, i.e., due to
Now consider the effect on welfare. The equilibrium welfare is
Using (5), we get from (9),
Proposition 2:
Cross ownership increases (decreases) welfare if λ < (>)1.
The above result shows that cross ownership increases welfare if λ < 1, and it happens since cross ownership helps to increase the output by reducing the tax rate.
The roles of the strategic tax policy captured by
We have shown the above results under symmetric cross ownership. We show in the Online Appendix that the consumer surplus and welfare raising cross ownership can occur even under asymmetric cross ownership. We show it by considering a situation where only one firm holds non-controlling shares in the other firm.
3 Bertrand Competition
Now we consider a game similar to Section 2 with the exception that competition in the product market is characterised by Bertrand competition. Since the procedure is similar to that of in Section 2, we will skip the mathematical details and will mention the condition for the consumer surplus and welfare raising cross ownership.
Assume that the demand functions for firms 1 and 2 are respectively
Following the procedure of Section 2, we can find from the first order conditions of profit maximization that
We find
We find
Hence, the results for the consumer surplus and welfare raising symmetric cross ownership are the same under Bertrand and Cournot competition. Like Cournot competition, the effects of the strategic tax policy, capturing
4 Welfare Comparison Under Cournot and Bertrand Competition
Since a general welfare comparison is difficult, we use a specific demand function to compare welfare under Cournot and Bertrand competition. Assume that firm 1 and firm 2 face the demand functions P
1 = 1 − q
1 − γq
2 and P
2 = 1 − q
2 − γq
1 respectively, where
Given these demand functions, we can derive the following result.
Proposition 3:
Consider λ
C
< λ
. We get
Proof:
We get
We get
since
and
■
The government provides lower subsidy (or imposes higher tax) under Bertrand competition compared to Cournot competition. This happens since competition is fierce under Bertrand competition, and therefore, the need for the subsidy to tackle the product market distortion is lower under Bertrand competition compared to Cournot competition. Further, we get
5 Conclusions
Although cross ownership creates output contraction and makes the policy makers concerned about its adverse welfare effects, previous research found several factors which might help to improve welfare in the presence of cross ownership. We provide a new reason for the consumer surplus and welfare raising cross ownership.
We show that a higher degree of cross ownership increases consumer surplus and welfare under strategic tax/subsidy policy if the marginal social cost/benefit of public funds is less than unity, which may occur if the government maximizes a political support function that is a weighted average of welfare and political contributions. Hence, under certain conditions, the policy makers may prefer to encourage cross ownership in the presence of tax/subsidy policies to benefit the consumers and the society.
Our results hold under both Cournot and Bertrand competition, suggesting that the policy makers’ preference for cross ownership may not be affected by the type of competition. However, our analysis suggests that when cross ownership benefits the consumers and the society, the policy makers would prefer Cournot competition over Bertrand competition, i.e., they would prefer a product market characterized by less intense competition.
References
Alley, W. A. 1997. “Partial Ownership Arrangements and Collusion in the Automobile Industry.” The Journal of Industrial Economics 45: 191–205. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-6451.00043.Suche in Google Scholar
Arya, A., B. Mittendorf, and D. E. Sappington. 2008. “Outsourcing, Vertical Integration, and Price vs. Quantity Competition.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 26: 1–16. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2006.10.006.Suche in Google Scholar
Azar, J., S. Raina, and M. Schmalz. 2022. “Ultimate Ownership and Bank Competition.” Financial Management 51: 227–69. https://doi.org/10.1111/fima.12368.Suche in Google Scholar
Banerjee, S., A. Mukherjee, and S. Poddar. 2024. “Product Differentiation, Demand Expansion and the Welfare Effects of Cross Ownership.” Canadian Journal of Economics. Forthcoming.Suche in Google Scholar
Bayona, A., and Á. L. López. 2018. “Silent Financial Interests and Product Innovation.” Economics Letters 170: 109–12. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2018.06.007.Suche in Google Scholar
Brander, J. A., and B. J. Spencer. 1985. “Export Subsidies and International Market Share Rivalry.” Journal of International Economics 18: 83–100. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-1996(85)90006-6.Suche in Google Scholar
Bresnahan, T. F., and S. C. Salop. 1986. “Quantifying the Competitive Effects of Production Joint Ventures.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 4: 155–75. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-7187(86)90028-7.Suche in Google Scholar
Brito, D., L. Cabral, and H. Vasconcelos. 2014. “Divesting Ownership in a Rival.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 34: 9–24. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2014.02.007.Suche in Google Scholar
Chen, L., T. Matsumura, and C. Zeng. 2024. “Welfare Consequence of Common Ownership in a Vertically Related Market.” The Journal of Industrial Economics 72: 996–1004. https://doi.org/10.1111/joie.12380.Suche in Google Scholar
Cheng, H., X. Wu, and C. Zeng. 2024. “Can Cross-Holdings Benefit Consumers?” Journal of Economics 141: 245–73. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-023-00850-x.Suche in Google Scholar
Clayton, M. J., and B. N. Jorgensen. 2005. “Optimal Cross Holding with Externalities and Strategic Interactions.” Journal of Business 78: 1505–22. https://doi.org/10.1086/430867.Suche in Google Scholar
Davallou, M., M. Soltaninejad, and A. Tahmasebi. 2015. “Analyzing the Aspects of Cross Sharing Ownership.” Journal of Money and Economy 10: 83–106.Suche in Google Scholar
Fang, J., J. Huang, and C. Zeng. 2024. “Passive Cross-Holdings, Horizontal Differentiation, and Welfare.” Bulletin of Economic Research 76: 508–528. https://doi.org/10.1111/boer.12436.Suche in Google Scholar
Fanti, L. 2015. “Partial Cross-Ownership, Cost Asymmetries, and Welfare.” Economics Research International: 324507.10.1155/2015/324507Suche in Google Scholar
Farrell, J., and C. Shapiro. 1990. “Asset Ownership and Market Structure in Oligopoly.” The RAND Journal of Economics 21: 275–92. https://doi.org/10.2307/2555424.Suche in Google Scholar
Fershtman, C., and K. L. Judd. 1987. “Equilibrium Incentives in Oligopoly.” The American Economic Review 77: 927–40.Suche in Google Scholar
Gilo, D., Y. Moshe, and Y. Spiegel. 2006. “Partial Cross Ownership and Tacit Collusion.” The RAND Journal of Economics 37: 81–99. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1756-2171.2006.tb00005.x.Suche in Google Scholar
Hamilton, S. F. 1999. “Tax Incidence Under Oligopoly: A Comparison of Policy Approaches.” Journal of Public Economics 71: 233–45. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0047-2727(98)00066-8.Suche in Google Scholar
Hamilton, S. F., and T. Requate. 2004. “Vertical Structure and Strategic Environmental Trade Policy.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 47: 260–9. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0095-0696(03)00080-9.Suche in Google Scholar
Liu, C. C., A. Mukherjee, and L. F. Wang. 2015. “Horizontal Merger Under Strategic Tax Policy.” Economics Letters 136: 184–6. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2015.09.032.Suche in Google Scholar
López, Á. L., and X. Vives. 2019. “Overlapping Ownership, R&D Spillovers, and Antitrust Policy.” Journal of Political Economy 127: 2394–437. https://doi.org/10.1086/701811.Suche in Google Scholar
Ma, H., C. Z. Qin, and C. Zeng. 2024. “Incentive and Welfare Implications of Cross-Holdings in Oligopoly.” Economic Theory 77: 975–97. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-021-01398-x.Suche in Google Scholar
Mukherjee, A. 2011. “Competition, Innovation and Welfare.” The Manchester School 79: 1045–57. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9957.2010.02184.x.Suche in Google Scholar
Myles, G. D. 1996. “Imperfect Competition and the Optimal Combination of Ad Valorem and Specific Taxation.” International Tax and Public Finance 3: 29–44. https://doi.org/10.1007/bf00400145.Suche in Google Scholar
Neary, J. P., and D. Leahy. 2004. “Revenue-Constrained Strategic Trade and Industrial Policy.” Economics Letters 82: 409–14. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2003.09.019.Suche in Google Scholar
O’Brien, D. P., and S. C. Salop. 2000. “Competitive Effects of Partial Ownership: Financial Interest and Corporate Control.” Antitrust Law Journal 67: 559–614.Suche in Google Scholar
Reynolds, R. J., and B. R. Snapp. 1986. “The Competitive Effects of Partial Equity Interests and Joint Ventures.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 4: 141–53. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-7187(86)90027-5.Suche in Google Scholar
Shelegia, S., and Y. Spiegel. 2012. “Bertrand Competition when Firms Hold Passive Ownership Stakes in One Another.” Economics Letters 114: 136–8. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2011.09.003.Suche in Google Scholar
Singh, N., and X. Vives. 1984. “Price and Quantity Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly.” The RAND Journal of Economics 15: 546–54. https://doi.org/10.2307/2555525.Suche in Google Scholar
Symeonidis, G. 2008. “Downstream Competition, Bargaining, and Welfare.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 17: 247–70. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1530-9134.2008.00177.x.Suche in Google Scholar
Supplementary Material
This article contains supplementary material (https://doi.org/10.1515/bejeap-2024-0051).
© 2024 the author(s), published by De Gruyter, Berlin/Boston
This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Frontmatter
- Research Articles
- Selection Efficiency in Multiple-Prize Tournaments with Sabotage
- Priced Out: Do Adolescents from Low-Income Families Respond More to Cost-Sharing in Primary Care?
- International Commodity-Tax Competition and Asymmetric Producer Prices
- Letters
- Absolute versus Relative Poverty and Wealth: Cooperation in the Presence of Between-Group Inequality
- Cross Ownership Under Strategic Tax Policy
- Central Bank Digital Currencies: Experimental Evidence of Deposit Conversion
- Earthquakes and Intertemporal Preferences: A Field Study in Italy
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Frontmatter
- Research Articles
- Selection Efficiency in Multiple-Prize Tournaments with Sabotage
- Priced Out: Do Adolescents from Low-Income Families Respond More to Cost-Sharing in Primary Care?
- International Commodity-Tax Competition and Asymmetric Producer Prices
- Letters
- Absolute versus Relative Poverty and Wealth: Cooperation in the Presence of Between-Group Inequality
- Cross Ownership Under Strategic Tax Policy
- Central Bank Digital Currencies: Experimental Evidence of Deposit Conversion
- Earthquakes and Intertemporal Preferences: A Field Study in Italy