Abstract
This paper investigates the production decisions of firms with asymmetric environmental damages, and how their profits are affected by environmental regulation. We demonstrate that emission fees entail a negative effect on firms’ profits, since they increase unit production costs. However, fees can also produce a positive effect for a relatively inefficient firm, given that environmental regulation mitigates its cost disadvantage. If such a disadvantage is sufficiently large, we show that the positive effect dominates, thus leading this firm to actually favor the introduction of environmental policy, while the relatively efficient firm opposes regulation. Furthermore, we show that such support can originate from polluting companies.
Appendix – Emissions and Costs in Different Industries
Air emission factor ranges for freight truck and rail, in grams/tone-km.
Pollutant | Truck | Train |
---|---|---|
CO | 0.25–2.40 | 0.02–0.15 |
CO2 | 127–451 | 41–102 |
HC | 0.30–1.57 | 0.01–0.07 |
NOx | 1.85–5.65 | 0.20–1.01 |
SO2 | 0.10–0.43 | 0.07–0.18 |
Particulates | 0.04–0.90 | 0.01–0.08 |
VOC | 1.10 | 0.08 |
Source: OECD (1997).
Note: CO, carbon monoxide; CO
Estimated annualized cost of power with carbon controls (2008 US$).
Technology | Non-fuel cost | Fuel cost | SO2 and NOx cost | CO2 cost | Production tax credit | Capital return | Total cost per Mwh |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Coal: Pulverized | $5.57 | $11.13 | $0.61 | $0.00 | $0.00 | $45.79 | $63.10 |
Coal: IGCC | $5.46 | $10.41 | $0.10 | $0.00 | $0.00 | $67.02 | $82.99 |
Nuclear | $6.13 | $5.29 | $0.00 | $0.00 | ($3.18) | $74.99 | $83.22 |
Estimated annualized cost of power with carbon controls (2008 U.S. $).
Technology | Non-fuel cost | Fuel cost | SO2 and NOx cost | CO2 cost | Production tax credit | Capital return | Total cost per Mwh |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Coal: Pulverized | $5.57 | $11.13 | $0.61 | $33.80 | $0.00 | $49.58 | $100.69 |
Coal: Pulverized/CCS | $13.48 | $14.13 | $0.77 | $4.29 | $0.00 | $78.87 | $111.54 |
Coal: IGCC | $5.46 | $10.41 | $0.10 | $31.61 | $0.00 | $67.02 | $114.60 |
Coal: IGCC/CCS | $7.10 | $12.61 | $0.13 | $3.83 | $0.00 | $95.25 | $118.92 |
Nuclear | $6.13 | $5.29 | $0.00 | $0.00 | ($3.18) | $74.99 | $83.22 |
Source: U.S., Congressional Research Service (2008).
Note: Mwh, megawatt-hour; IGCC, integrated gasification combined cycles; CCS, carbon capture and sequestration (which assuming current technology, is capable of removing 90 % of CO
Acknowledgment
We thank the editor, Till Requate, and two reviewers for their useful insights and recommendations. We are also grateful to Ana Espinola-Arredondo and Hayley Chouinard, as well as participants of the 88th annual meeting of the Western Economic Association International for their helpful comments and suggestions.
References
Baker, P., and C. Davenport. 2014. “Obama Orders New Efficiency for Big Trucks,” The New York Times, 18 Feb. 2014. http://www.nytimes.com/2014/02/19/us/politics/obama-to-request-new-rules-for-cutting-truck-pollution.html?_r=0.Suche in Google Scholar
Baron, D. 2001. “Private Politics, Corporate Social Responsibility and Integrated Strategy.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 10:7–45.10.1162/105864001300122548Suche in Google Scholar
Baron, D. 2008. “Managerial Contracting and Corporate Social Responsibility.” Journal of Public Economics 92:268–88.10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.05.008Suche in Google Scholar
Besley, T., and M. Ghatak. 2007. “Retailing Public Goods: The Economics of Corporate Social Responsibility.” Journal of Public Economics 91 (9):1645–63.10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.07.006Suche in Google Scholar
Brunnermeier, S., and A. Levinson. 2004. “Examining the Evidence on Environmental Regulations and Industry Location.” Journal of Environment & Development 13:6–41.10.1177/1070496503256500Suche in Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. 1969. “External Diseconomies, Corrective Taxes and Market Structure.” American Economic Review 59:174–7.Suche in Google Scholar
Ederington, J., A. Levinson, and J. Minier. 2004. “Trade Liberalization and Pollution Havens.” Advances in Economic Analysis & Policy 4 (2):Article 6. Berkeley Electronic Press.10.3386/w10585Suche in Google Scholar
Espinola-Arredondo, A., and F. Munoz-Garcia. 2012. “When Do Firms Support Environmental Agreements?” Journal of Regulatory Economics 41 (3):380–401.10.1007/s11149-011-9170-3Suche in Google Scholar
Espinola-Arredondo, A., and F. Munoz-Garcia. 2015. “Why Do Firms Oppose Entry-Deterring Policies? Environmental Regulation and Entry Deterrence.” Environment and Development Economics 20 (2):141–60.10.1017/S1355770X14000138Suche in Google Scholar
Farzin, Y. H. 2003. “The Effects of Emission Standards on Industry.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 24:315–27.10.1023/A:1025654906988Suche in Google Scholar
Gaudet, G., and N. V. Long. 1996. “Vertical Integration, Foreclosure, and Profits in the Presence of Double Marginalization.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 5 (3):409–32.10.1111/j.1430-9134.1996.00409.xSuche in Google Scholar
Goeschl, T., and G. Perino. 2007. “Innovation Without Magic Bullets: Stock Pollution and R&D Sequences.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 54:146–61.10.1016/j.jeem.2007.03.001Suche in Google Scholar
Hart, O., and J. Tirole. 1990. “Vertical Integration and Market Foreclosure.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics 4:205–86.10.2307/2534783Suche in Google Scholar
Johnson, K. 2013. “Businesses Weigh Response If New Climate Rules Come.” The Wall Street Journal, 12 Feb. 2013, pp. A4 Print.Suche in Google Scholar
Krattenmaker, T. G., and S. C. Salop. 1986. “Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals’ Costs to Achieve Power Over Price.” The Yale Law Journal 96 (2):209–93.10.2307/796417Suche in Google Scholar
Kurtyka, O., and P. Mahenc. 2011. “The Switching Effect of Environmental Taxation Within Bertrand Differentiated Duopoly.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 62:267–77.10.1016/j.jeem.2011.01.002Suche in Google Scholar
Levin, D. 1985. “Taxation Within Cournot Oligopoly.” Journal of Public Economics 27:281–90.10.1016/0047-2727(85)90052-0Suche in Google Scholar
Loertscher, S., and M. Reisinger. 2014. “Market Structure and the Competitive Effects of Vertical Integration.” Rand Journal of Economics 45 (3):471–94.10.1111/1756-2171.12058Suche in Google Scholar
Maloney, M., and R. McCormick. 1982. “A Positive Theory of Environmental Quality Regulation.” Journal of Law and Economics 25 (1):99–124.10.1086/467009Suche in Google Scholar
Munoz-Garcia, F., and S. B. Akhundjanov. 2014. “Firm Preferences for Environmental Policy: Industry Uniform or Firm Specific?” Washington State University, School of Economic Sciences, Working paper 2014–8.Suche in Google Scholar
Neate, R. 2013. “Olympic Medal Mining Firm Rio Tinto Faces Air Pollution Lawsuit in US,” The Guardian, 24 Sept. 2013. http://www.theguardian.com/business/2013/sep/24/olympic-medal-mining-firm-rio-tinto-air-pollution-lawsuit-usSuche in Google Scholar
Ordover, J. A., G. Saloner, and S. C. Salop. 1990. “Equilibrium Vertical Foreclosure.” American Economic Review 80:127–42.Suche in Google Scholar
Ordover, J. A., and D. R. Willig. 1981. “An Economic Definition of Predation: Pricing and Product Innovation.” The Yale Law Journal 91 (1):8–53.10.2307/795848Suche in Google Scholar
Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 1997. The Environmental Effects of Freight. Paris: OECD.Suche in Google Scholar
Porter, M. E. 1991. “America’s Green Strategy.” Scientific American 264: pp. 168.10.1038/scientificamerican0491-168Suche in Google Scholar
Porter, M. E., and C. van der Linde. 1995a. “Green and Competitive: Breaking the Stalemate.” Harvard Business Review 73:120–34.Suche in Google Scholar
Porter, M. E., and C. van der Linde. 1995b. “Toward a New Conception of the Environment-Competitiveness Relationship.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 (4):97–118.10.1257/jep.9.4.97Suche in Google Scholar
Roth, A. 2008. “Railroads Roll With a Greener Approach: Industry Makes Case that Switch to Trains Is More Eco-Friendly.” The Wall Street Journal, 29 May 2008. http://online.wsj.com/article/SB121202944363728389.htm.Suche in Google Scholar
Salop, S. C., and D. T. Scheffman. 1983. “Raising Rivals’ Costs.” American Economic Review 73:267–71.Suche in Google Scholar
Salop, S. C., and D. T. Scheffman. 1987. “Cost-Raising Strategies.” Journal of Industrial Economics 26:19–34.10.2307/2098594Suche in Google Scholar
Sartzetakis, E. S. 1997. “Raising Rivals’ Costs Strategies via Emission Permits Markets.” Review of Industrial Organization 12:751–65.10.1023/A:1007763019487Suche in Google Scholar
Scott, J., and H. Sinnamon. 2006. Smokestacks on Rails: Getting Clean Air Solutions for Locomotives on Track. New York: Environmental Defense Fund.Suche in Google Scholar
Shear, M. D. 2013. “Administration Presses Ahead With Limits on Emissions From Power Plants.” The New York Times, Sep. 19, 2013, http://www.nytimes.com/2013/09/20/us/politics/obama-administration-announces-limits-on-emissions-from-power-plants.html?pagewanted=all.Suche in Google Scholar
Simpson, R. D. 1995. “Optimal Pollution Taxation in a Cournot Duopoly.” Environment and Resource Economics 6:359–69.10.1007/BF00691819Suche in Google Scholar
Ulph, A. 1996. “Environmental Policy and International Trade When Governments and Producers Act Strategically.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 30:265–81.10.1006/jeem.1996.0018Suche in Google Scholar
U.S. Congressional Research Service. 2008. “Power Plants: Characteristics and Costs (RL34746; Nov. 13), by Stan Kaplan.” Federation of American Scientists Digital Collection; Accessed February 15, 2013.Suche in Google Scholar
U.S. Congressional Research Service. 2013. “The 2010 Deepwater Horizon Oil Spill: Natural Resource Damage Assessment under the Oil Pollution Act (R41972; July 24), by Adam Vann and Robert Meltz.” Federation of American Scientists Digital Collection; Accessed July 23, 2014.Suche in Google Scholar
©2016 by De Gruyter
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Research Article
- Voting in Central Banks: Theory versus Stylized Facts
- Delinquency Reinforcement and Balance: Is Exposure to Delinquent Peers Always Risky?
- Can Polluting Firms Favor Regulation?
- Cannabis Control and Crime: Medicinal Use, Depenalization and the War on Drugs
- Coasean Quality of Regulated Goods
- Can Low-Wage Employment Help People Escape from the No-Pay – Low-Income Trap?
- Auctioning Emission Permits with Market Power
- Privatization, Unemployment, and Welfare in the Harris-Todaro Model with a Mixed Duopoly
- Does Eco-labeling of Services Matter? Evidence from Higher Education
- What Do Regulators Value?
- Strategic CSR, Heterogeneous Firms and Credit Constraints
- Regulations to Supplement Weak Environmental Liability
- Intergenerational Educational Persistence among Daughters: Evidence from India
- A Signal of Altruistic Motivation for Foreign Aid
- Has Creative Destruction become more Destructive?
- Is There a Role for Higher Education Institutions in Improving the Quality of First Employment?
- Contribution
- The Effects of School Closure Threats on Student Performance: Evidence from a Natural Experiment
- School Entry, Compulsory Schooling, and Human Capital Accumulation: Evidence from Michigan
- Topics
- Overeducation, Overskilling and Mental Well-being
- Process and Product Innovation and the Role of the Preference Function
- Letter
- Does Evasion Invalidate the Welfare Sufficiency of the ETI?
- How Lobbying Affects Representation: Results for Majority-Elected Politicians
- Consumers’ Misevaluation and Public Promotion
- Meet-the-competition clauses and the strategic disclosure of product quality
- Import Competition and Post-displacement Wages in Korea: Whom You Trade with Matters
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Research Article
- Voting in Central Banks: Theory versus Stylized Facts
- Delinquency Reinforcement and Balance: Is Exposure to Delinquent Peers Always Risky?
- Can Polluting Firms Favor Regulation?
- Cannabis Control and Crime: Medicinal Use, Depenalization and the War on Drugs
- Coasean Quality of Regulated Goods
- Can Low-Wage Employment Help People Escape from the No-Pay – Low-Income Trap?
- Auctioning Emission Permits with Market Power
- Privatization, Unemployment, and Welfare in the Harris-Todaro Model with a Mixed Duopoly
- Does Eco-labeling of Services Matter? Evidence from Higher Education
- What Do Regulators Value?
- Strategic CSR, Heterogeneous Firms and Credit Constraints
- Regulations to Supplement Weak Environmental Liability
- Intergenerational Educational Persistence among Daughters: Evidence from India
- A Signal of Altruistic Motivation for Foreign Aid
- Has Creative Destruction become more Destructive?
- Is There a Role for Higher Education Institutions in Improving the Quality of First Employment?
- Contribution
- The Effects of School Closure Threats on Student Performance: Evidence from a Natural Experiment
- School Entry, Compulsory Schooling, and Human Capital Accumulation: Evidence from Michigan
- Topics
- Overeducation, Overskilling and Mental Well-being
- Process and Product Innovation and the Role of the Preference Function
- Letter
- Does Evasion Invalidate the Welfare Sufficiency of the ETI?
- How Lobbying Affects Representation: Results for Majority-Elected Politicians
- Consumers’ Misevaluation and Public Promotion
- Meet-the-competition clauses and the strategic disclosure of product quality
- Import Competition and Post-displacement Wages in Korea: Whom You Trade with Matters