Abstract
We analyze the decision of a firm to produce an input internally or to delegate the production to a better-informed supplier. The supplier can produce inputs of different qualities. As quality is not verifiable, a selfish supplier always produces the quality that minimizes his costs. A supplier that is motivated by reciprocity may instead produce the quality that maximizes the revenues of the buyer. Accordingly, reciprocity could increase the use of the market. To trigger reciprocal behavior the buyer must propose a contract that the seller perceives to be kind. We find that for reciprocal behavior to show up, it is enough that the supplier is moderately reciprocal. Lastly, we provide some intuitions about how our results change if the supplier is liquidity-constrained and must be granted non-negative profits in all circumstances.
Funding source: Università degli Studi di Udine
Award Identifier / Grant number: Reciprocity, social capital and the boundaries of the firm
Funding source: Programma operativo del Fondo sociale europeo 2014/2020 della Regione Friuli Venezia Giulia - Progetto “HEaD HIGHER EDUCATION AND DEVELOPMENT” OPERAZIONE 3 UNIUD
Award Identifier / Grant number: FP1619942003, canale di finanziamento 1420AFPLO3
Acknowledgement
This article is based on the second chapter of my Ph.D. dissertation discussed at Università degli Studi di Udine in 2019. The article has previously circulated as “Delegation in procurement: A theoretical model of reciprocity”. I thank Stefano Comino, David Pérez-Castrillo, Inés Macho-Stadler, Jernej Čopič, Clara Graziano, Fabio Pieri, Danilo Cavapozzi, Jan Bouckaert, Christoph Kuzmics; two anonimous referees; the participants to the XXXIV Jornadas de Economía Industrial 2019 in Madrid and seminar participants at Fachbereich Volkswirtschaftslehre-Karl-Franzens Universität (Graz) in November 2020 for valuable comments. This research has benefited from research stays at FAMNIT-Univerza na Primorskem, Koper (Slovenija) and at Fachbereich Volkswirtschaftslehre-Karl-Franzens-Universität, Graz (Austria). The research has benefitted from financial support by research fellowship “Reciprocity, social capital and the boundaries of the firm” (Università degli Studi di Udine) and by Programma operativo del Fondo sociale europeo 2014/2020 della Regione Friuli Venezia Giulia - Progetto “HEaD HIGHER EDUCATION AND DEVELOPMENT” OPERAZIONE 3 UNIUD (FP1619942003, canale di finanziamento 1420AFPLO3).
-
Research funding: This study was funded by Università degli Studi di Udine, grant number Reciprocity, social capital and the boundaries of the firm, Programma operativo del Fondo sociale europeo 2014/2020 della Regione Friuli Venezia Giulia - Progetto “HEaD HIGHER EDUCATION AND DEVELOPMENT” OPERAZIONE 3 UNIUD includes grant number FP1619942003, canale di finanziamento 1420AFPLO3.
Appendix A: Proofs
Proof of Lemma 1
If firm U does not produce the appropriate input in a given state of the world, his payoff equals
Next, suppose it is optimal for firm U to produce the appropriate input in a state
As by construction
It is immediate to verify that the left-hand side (LHS) of condition (4) is strictly smaller than the LHS of condition (5),
For the last part of the proof we require beliefs to be in equilibrium. After substituting
As
Proof of Proposition 1
First, we require beliefs to be in equilibrium:
After some algebra, the above expression simplifies to
After some algebra, the above expression simplifies to
Proof of Corollary 1
Consider the following input-contingent payments to be paid after the delivery of the input: p(q
i
) = c
i
. As U is then indifferent between producing any input,
□
Proof of Corollary 2
Consider the price identified in Proposition 1:
The first term, the expected production cost of firm U is decreasing in s′: as s′ increases, firm U produces the cheapest input instead of a more expensive appropriate input in more states of the world, thus his expected costs decrease. The second term,
Proof of Proposition 2
To begin with, we need to identify the value of s′ that maximizes the expected profits of firm D. Formally we are looking for
First, we rewrite the expected profits of firm D as follows:
We then apply Assumption 1 and substitute c i = c 1 − (i − 1)Δc in the above expression. After some algebra we obtain:
When
The abscissa of its vertex is:
Let
where
The condition for s ′* = n − 1 can be rearranged as follows:
This inequality holds for
The condition for s ′* = 0 can be rearranged as follows:
This inequality holds for
It is immediate to verify that for
As n ≥ 2, we have that
Proof of Corollary 3
The corollary follows directly from the Proof of Proposition 2, and in particular from (6) ad (7). □
Proof of Corollary 4
To begin with, note that
Proof of Proposition 3
To begin with, consider the case s
′* = n − 1. By (7) this is the case when
Consider now the case s
′* = 0. By (7) this is the case when
By (7), s
′* = s, s ∈ [1, …, n − 2] if
Summing up we have that μ
0 = ∞, while for any other s ∈ [1, …, n − 1], μ
s
is finite and can be expressed as
Proof of Remark 1
Let
As we are assuming that
Proof of Corollary 5
Consider two subsequent prices
Appendix B: Numerical Simulation
We first rewrite Eq. (3) from Proposition 1 considering that Δc is constant and plug in the simulated values:
To compute the optimal vale of s′ when U is not liquidity-constrained we apply (7) to the simulated values and get
References
Basov, S., and M. I. Bhatti. 2013. “Optimal Contracting Model in a Social Environment and Trust-Related Psychological Costs.” The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics 13 (1): 271–84. https://doi.org/10.1515/bejte-2012-0011.Search in Google Scholar
Beer, R., H.-S. Ahn, and S. Leider. 2018. “Can Trustworthiness in a Supply Chain Be Signaled?” Management Science 64 (9): 3974–94. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2017.2817.Search in Google Scholar
Berg, J., J. Dickhaut, and K. McCabe. 1995. “Trust, Reciprocity, and Social History.” Games and Economic Behavior 10 (1): 122–42. https://doi.org/10.1006/game.1995.1027.Search in Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. D., and M. D. Whinston. 1998. “Incomplete Contracts and Strategic Ambiguity.” The American Economic Review 88 (4): 902–32.Search in Google Scholar
Bierbrauer, F., and N. Netzer. 2016. “Mechanism Design and Intentions.” Journal of Economic Theory 163: 557–603. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jet.2016.02.013.Search in Google Scholar
Bouckaert, J., and G. Dhaene. 2004. “Inter-Ethnic Trust and Reciprocity: Results of an Experiment with Small Businessmen.” European Journal of Political Economy 20 (4): 869–86. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2003.08.006.Search in Google Scholar
Comino, S., A. Nicolò, and P. Tedeschi. 2010. “Termination Clauses in Partnerships.” European Economic Review 54 (5): 718–32. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2009.12.007.Search in Google Scholar
Conconi, P., D. R. DeRemer, G. Kirchsteiger, L. Trimarchi, and M. Zanardi. 2017. “Suspiciously Timed Trade Disputes.” Journal of International Economics 105: 57–76. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2016.12.001.Search in Google Scholar
De Chiara, A., and E. Manna. 2019. “Delegation with a Reciprocal Agent.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 35 (3): 651–95. https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewz009.Search in Google Scholar
Dufwenberg, M., and G. Kirchsteiger. 2004. “A Theory of Sequential Reciprocity.” Games and Economic Behavior 47 (2): 268–98. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2003.06.003.Search in Google Scholar
Du, S., T. Nie, C. Chu, and Y. Yu. 2014. “Reciprocal Supply Chain with Intention.” European Journal of Operational Research 239 (2): 389–402. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2014.05.032.Search in Google Scholar
Dufwenberg, M., and A. Patel. 2017. “Reciprocity Networks and the Participation Problem.” Games and Economic Behavior 101: 260–72. Special Issue in Honor of John O. Ledyard. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2015.08.006.Search in Google Scholar
Dufwenberg, M., A. Smith, and M. Van Essen. 2013. “Hold-up: With a Vengeance.” Economic Inquiry 51 (1): 896–908. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1465-7295.2010.00366.x.Search in Google Scholar
Dur, R. 2009. “Gift Exchange in the Workplace: Money or Attention?” Journal of the European Economic Association 7 (2–3): 550–60. https://doi.org/10.1162/jeea.2009.7.2-3.550.Search in Google Scholar
Dur, R., and H. Roelfsema. 2010. “Social Exchange and Common Agency in Organizations.” The Journal of Socio-Economics 39 (1): 55–63. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2009.07.011.Search in Google Scholar
Dur, R., A. Non, and H. Roelfsema. 2010. “Reciprocity and Incentive Pay in the Workplace.” Journal of Economic Psychology 31 (4): 676–86. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2010.05.001.Search in Google Scholar
Englmaier, F., and S. Leider. 2012. “Contractual and Organizational Structure with Reciprocal Agents.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 4 (2): 146–83. https://doi.org/10.1257/mic.4.2.146.Search in Google Scholar
Englmaier, F., and K. Schüßler. 2016. “Complementarities of Human-Resource Management Practices: A Case for a Behavioral-Economics Perspective.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 172 (2): 312–41. Symposium on Evidence-Based Management. https://doi.org/10.1628/093245616x14551719150681.Search in Google Scholar
Fahn, M. 2020. “Reciprocity in Dynamic Employment Relationships.” In CESifo Working Paper 8414.10.2139/ssrn.3646857Search in Google Scholar
Falk, A., and U. Fischbacher. 2006. “A Theory of Reciprocity.” Games and Economic Behavior 54 (2): 293–315. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2005.03.001.Search in Google Scholar
Fehr, E., and S. Gächter. 2000. “Fairness and Retaliation: The Economics of Reciprocity.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 14 (3): 159–81. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.14.3.159.Search in Google Scholar
Fehr, E., and K. M. Schmidt. 2006. “Chapter 8 the Economics of Fairness, Reciprocity and Altruism – Experimental Evidence and New Theories.” In Foundations, Volume 1 of Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity, edited by S.-C. Kolm, and J. M. Ythier, 615–91. Elsevier.10.1016/S1574-0714(06)01008-6Search in Google Scholar
Fehr, E., and J.-R. Tyran. 1996. “Institutions and Reciprocal Fairness.” Nordic Journal of Political Economy 23: 133–44.Search in Google Scholar
Fehr, E., G. Kirchsteiger, and A. Riedl. 1993. “Does Fairness Prevent Market Clearing? an Experimental Investigation.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (2): 437–59. https://doi.org/10.2307/2118338.Search in Google Scholar
Fehr, E., E. Kirchler, A. Weichbold, and S. Gächter. 1998a. “When Social Norms Overpower Competition: Gift Exchange in Experimental Labor Markets.” Journal of Labor Economics 16 (2): 324–51. https://doi.org/10.1086/209891.Search in Google Scholar
Fehr, E., G. Kirchsteiger, and A. Riedl. 1998b. “Gift Exchange and Reciprocity in Competitive Experimental Markets.” European Economic Review 42 (1): 1–34. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0014-2921(96)00051-7.Search in Google Scholar
Gil, R., and W. R. Hartmann. 2011. “Airing Your Dirty Laundry: Vertical Integration, Reputational Capital, and Social Networks.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 27 (2): 219–44. https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewp025.Search in Google Scholar
Grossman, S. J., and O. D. Hart. 1983. “An Analysis of the Principal-Agent Problem.” Econometrica 51 (1): 7–45. https://doi.org/10.2307/1912246.Search in Google Scholar
Grossman, S. J., and O. D. Hart. 1986. “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration.” Journal of Political Economy 94 (4): 691–719. https://doi.org/10.1086/261404.Search in Google Scholar
Hadjiyiannis, C., D. İriş, and C. Tabakis. 2012. “International Environmental Cooperation under Fairness and Reciprocity.” The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 12 (1). https://doi.org/10.1515/1935-1682.2917.Search in Google Scholar
Hahn, V. 2009. “Reciprocity and Voting.” Games and Economic Behavior 67 (2): 467–80. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2009.03.003.Search in Google Scholar
Han, J., and A. Rapoport. 2019. “Intention-based Fairness Preferences in Multi-Partner Project Teams.” Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics 81: 84–90. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2019.06.003.Search in Google Scholar
Harris, M., and A. Raviv. 1979. “Optimal Incentive Contracts with Imperfect Information.” Journal of Economic Theory 20 (2): 231–59. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(79)90073-5.Search in Google Scholar
Hart, O., and J. Moore. 1990. “Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm.” Journal of Political Economy 98 (6): 1119–58. https://doi.org/10.1086/261729.Search in Google Scholar
Hart, O., and J. Moore. 2008. “Contracts as Reference Points.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 123 (1): 1–48. https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.2008.123.1.1.Search in Google Scholar
Hölmstrom, B. 1979. “Moral Hazard and Observability.” The Bell Journal of Economics 10 (1): 74–91. https://doi.org/10.2307/3003320.Search in Google Scholar
İriş, D., and L. Santos-Pinto. 2013. “Tacit Collusion under Fairness and Reciprocity.” Games 4 (1): 50–65.10.3390/g4010050Search in Google Scholar
Jang, D., A. Patel, and M. Dufwenberg. 2018. “Agreements with Reciprocity: Co-Financing and MOUs.” Games and Economic Behavior 111: 85–99. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2018.06.004.Search in Google Scholar
Khan, H. 2020. “Optimal Incentives under Gift Exchange.” The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics 20 (1): 20180041.10.1515/bejte-2018-0041Search in Google Scholar
Klein, B., and K. B. Leffler. 1981. “The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance.” Journal of Political Economy 89 (4): 615–41. https://doi.org/10.1086/260996.Search in Google Scholar
Klein, B., R. G. Crawford, and A. A. Alchian. 1978. “Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process.” The Journal of Law and Economics 21 (2): 297–326. https://doi.org/10.1086/466922.Search in Google Scholar
Kozlovskaya, M., and A. Nicoló. 2019. “Public Good Provision Mechanisms and Reciprocity.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 167: 235–44. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2019.02.001.Search in Google Scholar
Livio, L., and A. De Chiara. 2019. “Friends or Foes? Optimal Incentives for Reciprocal Agents.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 167: 245–78. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2018.07.012.Search in Google Scholar
De Marco, G., and G. Immordino. 2013. “Partnership, Reciprocity and Team Design.” Research in Economics 67 (1): 39–58. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rie.2012.11.001.Search in Google Scholar
De Marco, G., and G. Immordino. 2014. “Reciprocity in the Principal–Multiple Agent Model.” The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics 14 (1): 445–82. https://doi.org/10.1515/bejte-2013-0022.Search in Google Scholar
Macaulay, S. 1963. “Non-contractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study.” American Sociological Review 28 (1): 55–67. https://doi.org/10.2307/2090458.Search in Google Scholar
Macneil, I. R. 1978. “Contracts: Adjustment of Long-Term Economic Relations under Classical, Neoclassical, and Relational Contract Law.” Northwestern University Law Review 72: 854–905.Search in Google Scholar
McCabe, K. A., S. J. Rassenti, and V. L. Smith. 1998. “Reciprocity, Trust, and Payoff Privacy in Extensive Form Bargaining.” Games and Economic Behavior 24 (1): 10–24. https://doi.org/10.1006/game.1998.0638.Search in Google Scholar
McMillan, J., and C. Woodruff. 1999. “Dispute Prevention without Courts in Vietnam.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 15 (3): 637–58. https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/15.3.637.Search in Google Scholar
Non, A. 2012. “Gift-Exchange, Incentives, and Heterogeneous Workers.” Games and Economic Behavior 75 (1): 319–36. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2011.10.003.Search in Google Scholar
Nyborg, K. 2018. “Reciprocal Climate Negotiators.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 92: 707–25. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2017.08.008.Search in Google Scholar
Rabin, M. 1993. “Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics.” The American Economic Review 83 (5): 1281–302.10.2307/j.ctvcm4j8j.15Search in Google Scholar
Sarkar, S. 2019. “Gratitude, Conscience, and Reciprocity: Models of Supplier Motivation when Quality is Non-Contractible.” European Journal of Operational Research 277 (2): 633–42. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2019.02.047.Search in Google Scholar
Sebald, A. 2010. “Attribution and Reciprocity.” Games and Economic Behavior 68 (1): 339–52. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2009.07.004.Search in Google Scholar
Segal, I. 1999. “Complexity and Renegotiation: A Foundation for Incomplete Contracts.” The Review of Economic Studies 66 (1): 57–82. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-937x.00078.Search in Google Scholar
Sliwka, D., and P. Werner. 2017. “Wage Increases and the Dynamics of Reciprocity.” Journal of Labor Economics 35 (2): 299–344. https://doi.org/10.1086/689189.Search in Google Scholar
Sloof, R., H. Oosterbeek, and J. Sonnemans. 2007. “Does Making Specific Investments Unobservable Boost Investment Incentives?” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 16 (4): 911–42. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1530-9134.2007.00162.x.Search in Google Scholar
Sobel, J. 2005. “Interdependent Preferences and Reciprocity.” Journal of Economic Literature 43 (2): 392–436. https://doi.org/10.1257/0022051054661530.Search in Google Scholar
von Siemens, F. A. 2009. “Bargaining under Incomplete Information, Fairness, and the Hold-Up Problem.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 71 (2): 486–94. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2009.02.007.Search in Google Scholar
von Siemens, F. A. 2013. “Intention-based Reciprocity and the Hidden Costs of Control.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 92: 55–65. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2013.04.017.Search in Google Scholar
Telser, L. G. 1980. “A Theory of Self-Enforcing Agreements.” The Journal of Business 53 (1): 27–44. https://doi.org/10.1086/296069.Search in Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York: Free Press.Search in Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1985. The Economic Intstitutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. New York: Free Press.Search in Google Scholar
© 2022 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Research Articles
- Duty to Read vs Duty to Disclose Fine Print. Does the Market Structure Matter?
- Cobb-Douglas Preferences and Pollution in a Bilateral Oligopoly Market
- Epsilon-Efficiency in a Dynamic Partnership with Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard
- Management Turnover, Strategic Ambiguity and Supply Incentives
- Uninformed Bidding in Sequential Auctions
- Arrowian Social Equilibrium: Indecisiveness, Influence and Rational Social Choices under Majority Rule
- Family Ties and Corruption
- Social Efficiency of Entry in a Vertical Structure with Third Degree Price Discrimination
- Insufficient Entry and Consumer Search
- Quality Competition and Market-Share Leadership in Network Industries
- The Effects of Introducing Advertising in Pay TV: A Model of Asymmetric Competition between Pay TV and Free TV
- Redistributive Unemployment Benefit and Taxation
- Constrained Persuasion with Private Information
- A Dynamic Graph Model of Strategy Learning for Predicting Human Behavior in Repeated Games
- Relative Income Concerns, Dismissal, and the Use of Pay-for-Performance
- Delegation in Vertical Relationships: The Role of Reciprocity
- Step by Step Innovation without Mutually Exclusive Patenting: Implications for the Inverted U
- Data and Competitive Markets: Some Notes on Competition, Concentration and Welfare
- Notes
- Optimality of a Linear Decision Rule in Discrete Time AK Model
- Equilibrium Pricing under Concave Advertising Costs
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Research Articles
- Duty to Read vs Duty to Disclose Fine Print. Does the Market Structure Matter?
- Cobb-Douglas Preferences and Pollution in a Bilateral Oligopoly Market
- Epsilon-Efficiency in a Dynamic Partnership with Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard
- Management Turnover, Strategic Ambiguity and Supply Incentives
- Uninformed Bidding in Sequential Auctions
- Arrowian Social Equilibrium: Indecisiveness, Influence and Rational Social Choices under Majority Rule
- Family Ties and Corruption
- Social Efficiency of Entry in a Vertical Structure with Third Degree Price Discrimination
- Insufficient Entry and Consumer Search
- Quality Competition and Market-Share Leadership in Network Industries
- The Effects of Introducing Advertising in Pay TV: A Model of Asymmetric Competition between Pay TV and Free TV
- Redistributive Unemployment Benefit and Taxation
- Constrained Persuasion with Private Information
- A Dynamic Graph Model of Strategy Learning for Predicting Human Behavior in Repeated Games
- Relative Income Concerns, Dismissal, and the Use of Pay-for-Performance
- Delegation in Vertical Relationships: The Role of Reciprocity
- Step by Step Innovation without Mutually Exclusive Patenting: Implications for the Inverted U
- Data and Competitive Markets: Some Notes on Competition, Concentration and Welfare
- Notes
- Optimality of a Linear Decision Rule in Discrete Time AK Model
- Equilibrium Pricing under Concave Advertising Costs