Abstract
Following the creation of the Alliance for Progress in 1961, several structural reforms were implemented in Latin America in response to the political effects of the Cuban Revolution. Among these, land reform was arguably the most important policy. Using a unique dataset of land expropriations, and a plausible exogenous variation in land concentration, this paper studies the causal effects this policy had on political support for the incumbent party in the central government. In a context where the incumbent was losing political support (and the power of the left wing was rising), municipalities affected by land reform voted by 3–5 percentage points higher for the incumbent than municipalities not affected by this process. Although it did not prevent the first democratically elected Marxist government, land reform decreased the political support for the left wing party. I discuss several theoretical mechanisms that can explain this empirical result.
Acknowledgments
I thank Carlos Alvarado, Luis Bértola, Ignacio Cuesta, José Díaz, Claudio Ferraz, Francisco Gallego, Cristián Larroulet, Rolf Luders, Guillermo Marshall, Tomás Rau, Raimundo Soto, Matías Tapia, Arístides Torche, and Gert Wagner for useful comments and suggestions. I also thank seminar participants at the Department of Economics (PUC-Chile), Political Sciences Department (PUC-Chile), the Annual Meeting of the Chilean Economic Society (SECHI), the Annual Meeting of the Latin American and the Caribbean Economic Association (LACEA), the Southern Hemisphere Economic History Summer School (EHSS), and the Millennium Nuclei Research in Social Sciences. All errors are mine.
Appendix
Definition and sources.
Definition and source | |
Main variables | |
Christian Democratic Party | Percentage of votes for Eduardo Frei 1958 and for Radomiro Tomic in 1970 (Electoral Service, SERVEL). |
Radical Party | Percentage of votes for Luis Bossay in 1958 (Electoral Service, SERVEL). |
Right Wing Party | Percentage of votes for Jorge Alessandri in 1958 and 1970 (Electoral Service, SERVEL). |
Left Wing Party | Percentage of votes for Salvador Allende and Antonio Zamorano in 1958 and only for Salvador Allende in 1970 (Electoral Service, SERVEL). |
Political participation | Number of voters in t over population. Data from the Electoral Service (SERVEL). |
Land Reform | Expropriations over agricultural county surface (both in physical hectares) from the Agrarian Reform Corporation (CORA) files. |
Neighbor | Identification of borders across municipalities with Cartographica (GIS) using data from GIS Chile (http://www.rulamahue.cl/mapoteca/catalogos/chile.html). |
Agricultural workers | Percentage of “Skilled agricultural workers” over labor force from the 1970 and 1960 Housing Census (IPUMS). |
Rurality | Percentage of people living in rural areas from the 1970 and 1960 Housing Census (IPUMS). |
Land concentration | Gini coefficient using information about agricultural population, agricultural surface, agricultural workers and number and size of exploitations (1955 Agricultural Census). |
Left wing votes | Percentage of votes for Salvador Allende and Antonio Zamorano in 1958 and percentage of votes for Salvador Allendo in 1970 (Electoarl Service, SERVEL). |
Conditions and Public Goods | Average years of education, percentage of people who know how to read and write, and percentage of houses with electricity, water supply, and hot water (1970 and 1960 Housing Census, IPUMS). |
Income Related | Percentage of houses with at least 1 car and 1 television (1970 Housing Census, IPUMS) and with at least 1 radio (1960 and 1970 Housing Census, IPUMS). |
Auxiliary variables | |
Parliamentary elections | Information available by political party (Electoral Service, SERVEL) |
Presidential election 1964 | The Christian Democratic Party and the Right Wing Party are represented by Eduardo Frei. The Left Wing Party is represented by Salvador Allende (Electoral Service, SERVEL). |
Geography | Annual rainfall and average temperature from DirecciÓn MeteorolÓgica de Chile (Meteorological Directorate of Chile). Identification of landlocked municipalities with Cartographica (GIS). Agricultural surface from the 1955 and 1965 Agricultural Census |
Exploitations in 1920 | Number of landowners by municipality (1920 Housing Census, available at: www.INE.cl). |
Exploitations in 1955 | Number of plots with agricultural activities by municipality (1955 Agricultural Census) |
Agricultural output | Own construction using all the available information on production from the 1955 Agricultural Census. Also used in Cuesta et al. (2011). |
Log agricultural workers | Total agricultural workers (1955 Agricultural Census). |
Log agricultural populations | Total agricultural population (1955 Agricultural Census). |
Summary statistics for auxiliary variables.
Mean | Standard deviation | N | ||
Politics | ||||
Parliamentary election 1953: Christian Democratic Party | 0.375 | (0.104) | 210 | |
Presidential election 1964: Christian Democratic Party | 0.540 | (0.113) | 210 | |
Presidential election 1964: Radical Party | 0.063 | (0.043) | 210 | |
Parliamentary election 1965: Christian Democratic Party | 0.375 | (0.104) | 210 | |
Geography | ||||
Annual rainfall | 1,031 | (727) | 210 | |
Average temperature | 13.43 | (1.45) | 210 | |
Landlocked | 0.743 | (0.438) | 210 | |
Agricultural surface | 71,777 | (68,280) | 210 | |
Agriculture | ||||
Log agricultural output 1955 | 12.95 | (0.680) | 210 | |
Log agricultural workers 1955 | 7.61 | (0.766) | 210 | |
Log agricultural population 1955 | 7.91 | (0.844) | 210 | |
Exploitations 1920 | 1,149 | (876) | 172 | |
Exploitations 1955 | 519 | (512) | 210 |
Notes: See Table A.1 for sources and definitions.

General sketch map of Chile. Within the square are located regions IV to X (Collier and Sater 2004).
References
Acemoglu, Daron. 2009. “Theory, General Equilibrium, Political Economy and Empirics in Development Economics.” Journal of Economic Literature (forthcoming).10.3386/w15944Search in Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and James Robinson. 2006. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy.Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511510809Search in Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, and Eliana La Ferrara. 2005. “Preferences for Redistribution in the Land of Opportunities.” Journal of Public Economics89:897–931.10.1016/j.jpubeco.2004.05.009Search in Google Scholar
Aliaga, Fernando. 1961. “Documentos de la Conferencia Episcopal Chilena.” El Campesino, Letter from priests to the President Alessandri about the agrarian problem, June, 16.Search in Google Scholar
Angrist, Joshua, and Jorn-Steffen Pischke. 2009. Mostly Harmless Econometrics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9781400829828Search in Google Scholar
Baraona, Rafael. 1960. Valle de Putaendo. Santiago.Search in Google Scholar
Bardhan, Pranab, and Dilip Mookherjee. 2010. “Determinants of Redistributive Politics: An Empirical Analysis of Land Reforms in West Bengal, India.” American Economic Review.10.1257/aer.100.4.1572Search in Google Scholar
Barraclough, Solon, and José, Fernández. 1974. Diagnóstico de la Reforma Agraria ANDEZ: Chilena.CORA.Search in Google Scholar
Barraclough, Solon. 1971. “Reforma Agraria: Historia y Perspectivas.” Cuader-nos de Realidad Nacional CEREN(7).Search in Google Scholar
Barros Arana, Diego. 1884. “Historia General de Chile.”Search in Google Scholar
Bauer, ArnoldJ. 1975. La Sociedad Rural Chilena. Cambridge University Press.Search in Google Scholar
Bauer, ArnoldJ. 1995. “Landloard and Campesino in the Chilean Road to Democracy.” In Agrarian Structure and Political Power, edited by Evelyne Huber and Frank Safford. University of Pittsburgh Press.Search in Google Scholar
Berger, Daniel, William Easterly, Nathan Nunn, and Shanker Satyanath. Forthcoming. “Commercial Imperialism? Political Influence and Trade During the Cold War.” American Economic Review.Search in Google Scholar
Black, Duncan. 1948. “On the Rationale of Group Decision-Making.” The Journal of Political Economy56(1):23–34.10.1086/256633Search in Google Scholar
Bruhn, Miriam, and Francisco Gallego. 2010. “Good, Bad, and Ugly Colonial Activities: Do They Matter for Economic Development.” Economic History and Cliometrics Lab Working Paper No. 6.Search in Google Scholar
Carvallo, Marcelo, Fernando Fuenzalida, and Sergio Maturana. 1960. Aspectos Econèmicos y Sociales del Inquilinaje en San Vicente de Tagua Tagua. Department of Agricultural Economics, Department of Agriculture, Republic of Chile.Search in Google Scholar
Castillo, Leonardo, and David Lehmann. 1982. “Chile’s Three Agrarian Reforms: The Inheritors.” Bulletin of Latin American Research1(2):21–43.10.2307/3338538Search in Google Scholar
CEPAL. 1954.Estudio Econòmico de Amèrica Latina. Centro de Estudios para América Latina.Search in Google Scholar
Cerda, Rodrigo, and Rodrigo Vergara.2007. “Business Cycle and Political Election Outcomes: Evidence from the Chilean Democracy.” Public Choice132(1–2): 125–36.10.1007/s11127-006-9138-5Search in Google Scholar
Cerrutti, Marcela, and Rodolfo Bertoncello. 2003. Urbanization and Internal Migration Patterns in Latin America. Argentina: Centro de Estudios de Poblacióon.Search in Google Scholar
Chonchol, Jacques. 1976. “La Reforma Agraria en Chile (1964–1973).” Trimestre EconómicoXLIII(171): 600.Search in Google Scholar
CIDA. 1966. Chile: Tenencia de la Tierra y Desarrollo Socioeconómico del Sector Agrícola. Inter-American Committee for Agricultural Development (CIDA).Search in Google Scholar
Collier, Simon, and William Sater. 2004. A History of Chile, 1808–2002. Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511991189Search in Google Scholar
Conley, Timothy. 1999. “GMM Estimation with Cross Sectional Dependence.” Journal of Econometrics1–45.10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00084-0Search in Google Scholar
Conley, Timothy, Christian Hansen, and Peter Rossi. 2010. “Plausibly Exogenous.” The Review of Economic and Statistics.Search in Google Scholar
Conning, Jonathan, and James Robinson. 2007. “Property Rights and the Political Organization of Agriculture.” Journal of Development Economics82: 416–47.10.1016/j.jdeveco.2005.08.001Search in Google Scholar
Correa, Sofia, Alfredo Jocelyn-Holt, Claudio Rolle, Manuel Vicuna, and Consuelo Figueroa. 2001. Historia del Siglo XX Chileno. Su-damericana.Search in Google Scholar
Cox, J., D. Friedman, and S. Gjerstad. 2007. “A Tractable Model of Reciprocity and Fairness.” Games and Economic Behavior.10.1016/j.geb.2006.05.001Search in Google Scholar
Cruz-Coke, Ricardo. 1984. Historia electoral de Chile (1925–1973). Editorial Jurídica de Chile.Search in Google Scholar
Cuesta, José Ignacio, Francisco Gallego, and Felipe González.2011. “Local Impacts of Trade Liberalization: Evidence from the Chilean Agricultural Sector.”Search in Google Scholar
De Gorter, Harry, and David Zilberman. 1990. “On the Political Economy of Public Goods Inputs in Agriculture.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics72(1):131–7.10.2307/1243152Search in Google Scholar
Dong, Yingying. 2010. “Endogenous Regressor Binary Choice Models Without Instruments, with an Application to Migration.” Economic Letters.10.1016/j.econlet.2009.12.017Search in Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper Collins..Search in Google Scholar
Drazen, Allan, and Marcela Eslava. 2006. “Pork Barrel Cycles.” NBER Working Paper No. 12190.10.3386/w12190Search in Google Scholar
Dube, Arindrajit, Ethan Kaplan, and Suresh Naidu. 2011. “Coups, Corporations, and Classified Information.” Quarterly Journal of Economics.10.3386/w16952Search in Google Scholar
Echenique, J. 1970. “Las Expropiaciones y la Organización de Asentamientos en el período 1965–1970.” ICIRA.Search in Google Scholar
Eckstein, Susan. 1986. “The Impact of the Cuban Revolution: A Comparative Perspective.” Comparative Studies in Society and History28(3): 502–34.10.1017/S0010417500014031Search in Google Scholar
Episcopate. 1961. “La Iglesia y el Problema del Campesinado Chileno.” Pastoral Colectiva.Search in Google Scholar
Fair, RayC. 1978. “The Effect of Economic Events on Votes for President.” The Review of Economic and Statistics LX(2).10.2307/1924969Search in Google Scholar
Farber, Samuel. 2006. The Origins of the Cuban Revolution Reconsidered. The University of North Carolina Press.Search in Google Scholar
Finan, Frederico, and Laura Schechter. Forthcoming. “Vote-Buying and Reciprocity.” Econometrica.Search in Google Scholar
Flores, Edmundo. 1963. Land Reform and the Alliance for Progress. Center of International Studies, Princenton University.Search in Google Scholar
Freeman, Richard. 2003. “What Do Unions Do... to Voting?” NBER Working Paper No. 9992.10.3386/w9992Search in Google Scholar
Garrido, José. 1988. “Historia de la Reforma Agraria en Chile.” Universitaria.Search in Google Scholar
Grayson, GeorgeW. 1968. “The Chilean Christian Democratic Party: Genesis and Development.” Buenos Aires; Santiago de Chile; Francisco de Aguirre.Search in Google Scholar
Grayson, GeorgeW. 1969. “Chile’s Christian Democratic Party: Power, Factions, and Ideology.” The Review of Politics31(2):147–71.10.1017/S0034670500009463Search in Google Scholar
Hahn, Jinyong, and Jerry Hausman. 2003. “Weak Instruments: Diagnosis and Cures in Empirical Econometrics.” American Economic Review.10.1257/000282803321946912Search in Google Scholar
Hamuy, Eduardo. 1958. “Investigacièn Pre-Electoral, Elecciones Presidenciales.” FLACSO-Chile, July August.Search in Google Scholar
Hellinger, Daniel. 1978. “Electoral Change in the Chilean Countryside: The Presidential Elections of 1958 and 1970.” The Western Political Quarterly31(2): 253–73.10.1177/106591297803100208Search in Google Scholar
Herrick, BruceH. 1966. Urban Migration and Economic Development in Chile. The MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar
Hibbs, DouglasA. 2006. “Voting and the Macroeconomy.” In The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy, edited by BarryR. Weingast and Donald Wittman, 565–86. Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar
Hotelling, Harold. 1929. “Stability in Competition.” The Economic Journal39(153):41–57.10.2307/2224214Search in Google Scholar
Hudson, RexA. 1994. Chile: A Country Study. Washington, DC: GPO for the Library of Congress.Search in Google Scholar
Huerta, Maria Antonieta. 1989. Otro Agro para Chile: la Historia de la Reforma Agraria en el Proceso Social y Político. CISEC-CESOC.Search in Google Scholar
ICIRA. 1978. “Anàlisis de la situaciòn de los Asignatarios de Tierras a Junio de 1978.” Instituto de Capacitaciòn e Investigacièn Reforma Agraria.Search in Google Scholar
Kennan, John, and James R.Walker. 2011. “The Effect of Expected Income on Individual Migration Decisions.” Econometrica.Search in Google Scholar
Kramer, GeraldH. 1971. “Short-Term Fluctuations in U.S. Voting Behavior, 1896–1964.” The American Political Science Review65(1): 131–43.10.2307/1955049Search in Google Scholar
Leigh, Andrew. 2006. “How Do Unionists Vote? Estimating the Causal Impact of Union Memership on Voting Behaviour from 1966 to 2004.” Australian Journal of Political Science.10.2139/ssrn.891890Search in Google Scholar
Levitt, StevenD., and James M.Snyder. 1997. “The Impact of Federal Spending on House Election Outcomes.” Journal of Political Economy105(1): 30–53.10.1086/262064Search in Google Scholar
Loveman, Brian. 1976. Struggle in the Countryside: Politics and Rural Labor in Chile, 1919–1973. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press.Search in Google Scholar
Manacorda, Marco, Edward Miguel, and Andrea Vigorito. 2011. “Government Transfers and Political Support.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics.10.1257/app.3.3.1Search in Google Scholar
McBride, JorgeM. 1970. Chile: Land and Society. ICIRA.Search in Google Scholar
Meltzer, Allan, and Scott Richard. 1981. “A Rational Theory of the Size of Government.” Journal of Political Economy89(5):914–27.10.1086/261013Search in Google Scholar
Mikusheva, Anna, and Brian Poi. 2006. “Tests and Confidence Sets with Correct Size When Instruments are Potentially Weak.” The Stata Journal6(3):335–47.10.1177/1536867X0600600303Search in Google Scholar
Moreira, Marcelo. 2003. “A Conditional Likelihood Ratio Test for Structural Models.” Econometrica71(4):1027–048.10.1111/1468-0262.00438Search in Google Scholar
Nunn, Nathan. 2008. “Slavery, Inequality, and Economic Development in the Americas: An Examination of the Engerman-Sokoloff Hypothesis.” In Institution and Economic Performance, edited by E. Helpman. Harvard University Press.10.2307/j.ctv21hrgnz.8Search in Google Scholar
Nunn, Nathan, and Nancy Qian. 2012. “Aiding Conflict: The Impact of U.S. Food Aid on Civil War.”10.3386/w17794Search in Google Scholar
Oliart, Francisco, and José EmilioG. Araujo.1974. Agrarian Reform in Latin America 1974. Perspectives and Possibilities. IICA Biblioteca Venezuela.Search in Google Scholar
Pérez-Stable, Marifeli. 1999. The Cuban Revolution: Origins, Course, and Legacy. Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar
Petras, James, and Maurice Zeitlin. 1968. “Agrarian Radicalism in Chile.” The British Journal of Sociology19(3): 254–70.10.2307/588831Search in Google Scholar
Petras, James, and Maurice Zeitlin. 1970. “The Working-Class Vote in Chile: Christian Democracy versus Marxism.” The British Journal of Sociology21(1):16–29.10.2307/588268Search in Google Scholar
Pop-Eleches, Cristian, and Grigore Pop-Eleches. 2010. “Government Spending and Pocketbook Voting: Quasi-Experimental Evidence from Romania.”Search in Google Scholar
Robinson, James, and Jean-Marie Baland. 2008. “Land and Power: Theory and Evidence from Chile.” American Economic Review98(5): 1737–65.10.1257/aer.98.5.1737Search in Google Scholar
Salazar, Carlos. 1987. “Los Programas de los Candidatos Allende y Tomic en la Elecciòn Presidencial de 1970.” Pontificia CatÒlica de Chile.Search in Google Scholar
San Francisco, Alejandro and Angel Soto. 2005. Camino a La Moneda: Las Elecciones Presidenciales en la Historia de Chile 1920–2000. Centro de Estudios Bicentenario.Search in Google Scholar
Schady, NorbertR. 2000. “The Political Economy of Expenditures by the Peruvian Social Fund (FONCODES), 1991–1995.” American Political Science Review94(2).10.2307/2586013Search in Google Scholar
Shi, M., and J.Svensson.2006. “Political Budget Cycles: Do They Differ Across Countries and Why?” Journal of Public Economics63:119–45.Search in Google Scholar
Sobel, J.2005. “Interdependent Preferences and Reciprocity.” Journal of Economic Literature.10.1257/0022051054661530Search in Google Scholar
Stigler, GeorgeJ.1973. “General Economic Conditions and National Elections.” American Economic Review63(2): 160–7.Search in Google Scholar
Stock, J., J.Wright, and M.Yogo.2002 “A Survey of Weak Instruments and Weak Identification in Generalized Method of Moments.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics.10.1198/073500102288618658Search in Google Scholar
Taffet, F. Jeffrey. 2007. Foreign Aid as Foreign Policy: The Alliance for Progress in Latin America. Routledge Taylar and Francis Group.Search in Google Scholar
Tello, Carlos. 1965. “El Sector Agrícola y el Desarrollo Económico de los Países Latinoamericanos.” El Trimestre Económico.Search in Google Scholar
Thomas, Hugh. 1963. “The Origins of the Cuban Revolution.” The World Today.Search in Google Scholar
Torres, Enrique. 1968. “Nueva Ley Chilena de la Reforma Agraria.” ICA/ICIRA (Institutode Capacitaciòn e Investigación en Reforma Agraria).Search in Google Scholar
Urzùa,, Germàn. 1988. “Los Partidos Polìcos Chilenos: las Fuerzas Polìcas.” Editorial Jurìdica.Search in Google Scholar
Urzúa, German. 1992. Historia Política de Chile y su Evolución Electoral desde 1810 a 1992. Editorial Jurídica de Chile.Search in Google Scholar
Wooldridge, JeffreyM.2003. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar
Wright, ThomasC.2000. Latin America in the Era of the Cuban Revolution: Revise Edition. Praeger Paperback.Search in Google Scholar
- 1
More than 3 million hectares were expropriated from the hands of landowners before that date, which accounts for approximately 12.5% of Chile’s main agricultural area (the so-called “center valley,” regions IV to X, see Figure A.1). This is big when compared to the 310 thousand hectares expropriated in Venezuela by 1973 and the 135 thousand hectares expropriated in Colombia by 1969, which represents 0.33% and 0.12% of each territory, respectively (Oliart and Araujo 1974).
- 2
There are better identification strategies to estimate the causal effect of a redistributive policy (typically government transfers) on political support for the incumbent (e.g. Pop-Eleches and Pop-Eleches 2010; Manacorda Miguel, and Vigortio 2011). This is mainly because they rely on more plausible identification assumptions by exploiting a manipulated regression discontinuity design.
- 3
See Kramer (1971), Stigler (1973), Fair (1978), Hibbs (2006) and Cerda and Vergara (2007) for the former literature and Levitt and Snyder (1997), Schady (2000), Manacorda, Miguel, and Vigortio (2011), Pop-Eleches and Pop-Eleches (2010) for the latter.
- 4
See Dube, Kalpan and Naidu (2011), Berger et al. (forthcoming) and Nunn and Qian (2012) for examples. To the best of my knowledge, the hypothesis that motivates this research, i.e. that land reform had political effects, is entirely original. Therefore, there are no prior beliefs among historians or economists about the potential answers to this question for the Chilean case.
- 5
As McBride (1970) puts it: “Chile’s social structure was built on land bases, and the entire life of the nation had to be shaped in relation to land (...) The condition of each person was determined by the ownership or not ownership of an hacienda.”
- 6
Indeed, Conning and Robinson (2007) calculate that land gini coeffient in Chile was about 0.94 in 1965. Other land gini coefficients are: Argentina 0.79, Brazil 0.84, Bolivia 0.94, Bangladesh 0.42, India 0.62, France 0.54, and United States 0.73. Many historians hypothesized that this high land concentration has its origins in colonial times (e.g. Bauer 1975 and Baraona 1960).
- 7
Flores (1963) puts it clearly: “Fidel Castro has claimed to be the indirect promoter of the Alianza [Alliance for Progress]; and there is some truth in his boast, since without the Cuban Revolution Latin America would not be in the headlines today (...) Without Castro, few outside Latin America would care about the region’s economic stagnation [and] its political instability.”
- 8
Taffet (2007) succinctly says: “new policies were necessary because the successes of the Cuban Revolution suggested that the entire region was vulnerable to communism.”
- 9
Chile went from being a net exporter of agricultural products in the 1930s, to a growing trade deficit at the beginning of the 1960s. Indeed, during years 1936–1938, there was a trade surplus in agricultural products of 1.1 million US dollars, while in 1963 the annual deficit was around 124 million US dollars (Chonchol 1976).
- 10
Huerta (1989) offers a good description of this process: “There is a total resistance to an structural Agrarian Reform before the fifties. The reason is clear, it implies transmission of power, social modifications, and more political participation. Even though the agrarian problem start as an economic issue, it soon transformed into a political problem (...) Agricultural workers have been absent as participants of the national problems, they do not have means of expression.”
- 11
The main objectives of this law were to give access to land to agricultural workers, to im-prove the living standards of the rural population, and to increase agricultural production and soil productivity (Law 15.020 art. 3, Diario Oficial N.25, November 27, 1962).
- 12
The general agreement about the need for a more intense land reform was reflected in the 94% approval rating at the Congress (Barraclough 1971).
- 13
In fact, several historians refer to these agrarian reform period of Jorge Alessandri as “Reforma de Macetero” (Pot Reform), in direct reference to the small amount of reformed land (e.g. Correa et al. 2001).
- 14
This political migration of the Radicals between 1958 and 1970 is fairly well documented by Collier and Sater (2004).
- 15
This pattern is clear for both the 1958 and the 1970 presidential elections (see Table 2) as well as in other elections (see Table 1). The exception is the 1964 presidential election and the 1961 parliamentary election due to the alliance of the right wing with the center due to the threat of a potential Marxist government.
- 16
Wright (2000) is an exception and argues that the revolution was indeed something desired by the majority of Latin Americans; thus, it was an immediate precedent for the guerrillas and revolutions that came after it.
- 17
As we will see, the period 1964–1970 was the most intense period of land reform and we could use the 1964 presidential election as the election before land reform implementation. However, a political episode known as “Naranjazo” greatly affected the actions of the right wing and they joined the center in order to avoid a potential government of Salvador Allende.
- 18
Descriptive statistics for auxiliary variables are presented in Table A.2 in the Appendix. Aux-iliary variables are defined as (i) secondary controls and (ii) those used in the robustness checks.
- 19
See Figure 2 for a graphical analysis of land reform heterogeneity at the municipal level. A bar represents the percentage of land expropriated in each of the 210 municipalities. Results are robust if I use (i) expropriation divided by agricultural surface instead of total surface and (ii) the amount of land expropriated only under the government of the Christian Democrat Eduardo Frei.
- 20
The change in the percentage of agricultural workers is probably not accurate, as the increase from 21% to 51% seems somehow implausible. This is probably because the 1960 and the 1970 IPUMS sample did not targeted representation of different labor forces. However, this is not a problem for this particular paper because I am not comparing the change in the level of the share in the same municipality but rather across municipalities.
- 21
The average number of cars and the percentage of houses with television and radio are ob-viously a crude proxy of income. However, to the best of my knowledge, there are not any other measures of income at the municipality level for this period.
- 22
Land concentration is constructed with information from the 1955 Agricultural Census. This information is at the municipality level, but we know how many plots there are in each municipality and what is their approximate size (12 categories, in physical hectares). Therefore, we can construct a land gini coefficient. This coefficient equals 0 if all physical hectares in the municipality are equally divided among its entire population, and equals 1 if one person is the owner of all physical hectares.
- 23
Nevertheless, there seems to be a statistically significant correlation between land reform and political support for the Radical Party: a one standard deviation increase (0.10) decreases land reform by 0.02 (–0.19×0.10, 0.12 standard deviations). If there is some political targeting, the Christian Democratic Party seems to have targeted radical voters, either intentionally or unintentionally.
- 24
Indirectly, this empirical analysis documents a well-known stylized fact: a political migration of voters from the Christian Democratic Party (political center) to the left and right wing. This occurred after the peak of the Christian Democrats in the middle of the sixties, where they reach a political support of more than 50%.
- 25
Alternatively, I could have used a panel dataset including the 1964 presidential election. However, I prefer this empirical strategy because (i) the instrument I use only varies between municipalities, (ii) there is no data for the control variables in 1964, thus I would have to use linear interpolations, and (iii) there is no candidate from the Right Wing Party in 1964. Nevertheless, results do not change using this alternative strategy (results available upon request).
- 26
There are other empirical strategies I could have used. For example: (i) Conley (1999) spatial standard errors and (ii) the same dummy in eq. [1] weighted by the distance to a municipality with land reform. Qualitative and quantitative similar results are obtained with both strategies.
- 27
The covariate Δ rurality also helps to control for internal rural-urban migration, which seems to be changing in a different way during the sixties (Herrick 1966, and Cerrutti and Bertoncello 2003).
- 28
It is not straightforward to compare coefficients and. We need to multiply these coeffi-cients by the standard deviation of land reform and neighbor to be able to compare them.
- 29
The variable land reform is normalized in order facilitate the interpretation of. Thus, the coefficient of interest indicates the change, in percentage points, in the corresponding dependent variable.
- 30
A one standard deviation increase (0.486) increases political support for the Political Center by 0.5 percentage points (0.486 × 0.011). In all specifications hereafter, the effect is larger based on the closeness of the neighbor municipalities, but never as bigger as the direct effect, and zero when they are far away from each other. I use centroids to calculate distances. Results not shown for parsimony but available upon request.
- 31
The first two are valid concerns, but the last one is not because only 12 out of the 5,422 expropriations have missing date of expropriation and, thus, are missing in the data set. Among these, only six were bigger than 100 physical hectares.
- 32
Bauer (1975), for example, states that “From the 17th century there was a tendency to have large haciendas, and these were notably stable until the nineteenth century.” The translation is mine.
- 33
Next subsection provides evidence supporting this assumption. Figure 3 shows the persis-tence of land concentration at the municipality level by plotting the logarithm of total exploitations at the municipality level in 1920 and in 1955. The main idea is that, because a municipality’s territory is constant over time, a persistent land concentration should be translated into a positive correlation between the number of plots with agricultural activities in two different points in time.
- 34
This suggests an absence of a weak instrument problem (Hahn and Hausman, 2003) according to the statistical tables in Stock, Wright, and Yogo (2002).
- 35
An exploitation is a plot with agricultural activities. The 1920 variable is therefore interpreted as a proxy for number of exploitations. This variable also incorporates landowners in the urban areas and it is only available for 172 municipalities out of the 210. However, it is the best available measure for land concentration at the municipality level before 1955. To the best of my knowledge there are no other measures at the municipality level prior to this period.
- 36
Ideally I would like to look at the change in the CDP vote share between the 1952 and 1958 presidential elections. However, there is not clear distinction of left, center, and right wing and the CDP did not exist in 1952. This is why I use non-left wing and parliamentary elections in 1953 and 1961. This non-left wing is called Falange Nacional and is actually the main political force from the center of the political spectrum during the 1950s.
- 37
I use non-left here because at the 1964 presidential elections, the right and the political center were represented by only one candidate. This happened mostly due to the fear of the right wing of a left wing government (Collier and Sater 2004). See Table 1 for details.
- 38
When θk ≠ 0 a violation to perfect exogeneity has taken place. Until now I have assumed that θk = 0, but it is not a testable assumption.
- 39
A local to zero approach, i.e.
but
, results in a
and a confidence interval of [0.137, 0.782] (without normalization). Using different support assumptions for Θ, with, I find out that θ0 must be in order to have a zero effect of land reform on voting patters. I argue that because this is a large effect this provides further evidence for the IV approach.
- 40
Regions are historically named by a roman number: region I, II, III, and so on until region XII. The exception is the metropolitan region (MR), the capital. My analysis is on the geographic area named Central Valley, were regions IV, V, VI, VII, VIII, IX, X, and MR are located.
- 41
Provinces are administrative units bigger than municipalities but smaller than regions. Cur-rently, there are 15 regions, 54 provinces, and 345 municipalities in Chile.
- 42
The main de jure objective at this stage was to: (i) efficiently exploit the expropriated land, (ii) prepare peasants to assume their responsibilities as owners and agricultural entrepreneurs, (iii) guide and promote the community’s development, (iv) promote agricultural activities as the main source of income among peasants, (v) build the minimum infrastructure necessary for the exploitation of the plot.
- 43
I would like to thank an anonymous referee for mentioning this potential mechanism.
- 44
However, empirical support for this theory is mixed, with some studies finding positive and other modest or insignificant results. The empirical evidence is equally mixed in the United States, Western Europe, and developing countries. See Pop-Eleches and Pop-Eleches (2010) for a review.
- 45
Leigh (2006) tries to disentangle socioeconomic and unions effects with panel data and finds evidence of a union-effect. However, the author does not explain why this pattern is found.
- 46
However, Freeman (2003) is not able to disentangle the voting effects of being unionized from just being different in socio-economic aspects, because workers in unions are different from those who are not.
- 47
There is research arguing that agricultural workers and rural areas voted relatively more for the Christian Democratic Party (e.g. Petras and Zeitlin 1968, 1970)
- 48
Higher support for the Christian Democrats is defined as those municipalities with more than 17% of votes (the median) for Eduardo Frei in the 1958 presidential election. Results are robust to different definitions.
©2013 by Walter de Gruyter Berlin / Boston
Articles in the same Issue
- Masthead
- Masthead
- Contributions
- Women Rule: Preferences and Fertility in Australian Households
- Can Land Reform Avoid a Left Turn? Evidence from Chile after the Cuban Revolution
- Incentive Effects of Parents’ Transfers to Children: An Artefactual Field Experiment
- Reclassification and Academic Success among English Language Learners: New Evidence from a Large Urban School District
- Fairness, Search Frictions, and Offshoring
- The Incentive Effect of Equalization Grants on Tax Collection
- Why Have Labour Market Outcomes of Youth in Advanced Economies Deteriorated?
- A Commitment Theory of Subsidy Agreements
- The Effects of Transactions Costs and Social Distance: Evidence from a Field Experiment
- Syphilis Cycles
- Impact of Voucher Design on Public School Performance: Evidence from Florida and Milwaukee Voucher Programs
- Topics
- Outsourcing and Innovation: An Empirical Exploration of the Dynamic Relationship
- Economies of Scope, Entry Deterrence and Welfare
- Can Horizontal Mergers Without Synergies Increase Consumer Welfare? Cournot and Bertrand Competition Under Uncertain Demand
- Institutions and information in multilateral bargaining experiments
Articles in the same Issue
- Masthead
- Masthead
- Contributions
- Women Rule: Preferences and Fertility in Australian Households
- Can Land Reform Avoid a Left Turn? Evidence from Chile after the Cuban Revolution
- Incentive Effects of Parents’ Transfers to Children: An Artefactual Field Experiment
- Reclassification and Academic Success among English Language Learners: New Evidence from a Large Urban School District
- Fairness, Search Frictions, and Offshoring
- The Incentive Effect of Equalization Grants on Tax Collection
- Why Have Labour Market Outcomes of Youth in Advanced Economies Deteriorated?
- A Commitment Theory of Subsidy Agreements
- The Effects of Transactions Costs and Social Distance: Evidence from a Field Experiment
- Syphilis Cycles
- Impact of Voucher Design on Public School Performance: Evidence from Florida and Milwaukee Voucher Programs
- Topics
- Outsourcing and Innovation: An Empirical Exploration of the Dynamic Relationship
- Economies of Scope, Entry Deterrence and Welfare
- Can Horizontal Mergers Without Synergies Increase Consumer Welfare? Cournot and Bertrand Competition Under Uncertain Demand
- Institutions and information in multilateral bargaining experiments