Startseite Parental Transfers, Intra-household Bargaining and Fertility Decision
Artikel
Lizenziert
Nicht lizenziert Erfordert eine Authentifizierung

Parental Transfers, Intra-household Bargaining and Fertility Decision

  • Emin Gahramanov EMAIL logo , Khusrav Gaibulloev und Javed Younas
Veröffentlicht/Copyright: 12. Oktober 2018

Abstract

This paper examines the role of parental transfers on family size. We introduce a simple theoretical model of fertility decision where preferences towards children may differ between female and male spouses. Parental transfers increase both the household income and the bargaining power of the recipient spouse. Therefore, transfers from wife’s and husband’s parents may have dissimilar effects on the number of children. Our empirical result, based on a unique household-level data for Japan, supports this hypothesis. In particular, received transfers from the wife’s parents are negatively associated with the demand for children. In contrast, both received and expected transfers from the husband’s parents are positively associated with the demand for children. These results hold important policy implications.

JEL Classification: D10; D64; J13

Acknowledgements

We acknowledge the Osaka University program’s contributors Yoshiro Tsutsui, Fumio Ohtake and Shinsuke Ikeda. We are indebted to Editor Mariapia Mendola, two anonymous referees, Charles Horioka, participants of a seminar held at the American University of Sharjah, the 2018 Royal Economic Society Annual Conference, and the 38th Middle East Economic Association Annual Meeting for their helpful comments and suggestions. All errors are our own.

A Appendix

Table 6:

Descriptive statistics: holding the sample size constant.

VariableObs.MeanStd. Dev.MinMax
Number of children1,8312.100.7905
Transfer Rec.1,8310.470.5001
Transfer Exp.1,8310.330.4701
Transfer Rec. (W)1,8310.230.4201
Transfer Rec. (H)1,8310.330.4701
Transfer Exp. (W)1,8310.170.3701
Transfer Exp. (H)1,8310.230.4201
Marriage duration1,83134.128.55156
Net wealth1,83134.4737.05−31.25200
Below high school (W)1,8310.130.3401
High school (W)1,8310.570.5001
Associate (W)1,8310.200.4001
Bach. or higher (W)1,8310.100.3101
Below high sch. (H)1,8310.160.3601
High school (H)1,8310.450.5001
Associate (H)1,8310.050.2201
Bach. or higher (H)1,8310.340.4701
Religiosity1,8311.961.1315
  1. Notes: H stands for husband and W denotes wife. Abbreviations Rec., Exp. and Bach. stand for “received,” “expected” and “bachelor,” respectively.

Table 7:

Poisson regressions: holding the sample size constant.

VariableModel 1Model 2Model 3Model 4Model 5
Transfer Rec.−0.006
(0.018)
Transfer Exp.0.032
(0.021)
Transfer Rec. (W)−0.060***−0.057***−0.051**
(0.021)(0.022)(0.022)
Transfer Rec. (H)0.034*0.031*0.036**
(0.018)(0.018)(0.018)
Transfer Exp. (W)−0.012−0.003−0.002
(0.026)(0.027)(0.027)
Transfer Exp. (H)0.049**0.043*0.044**
(0.022)(0.022)(0.022)
Marriage duration0.006***0.006***0.006***0.006***0.007***
(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)(0.001)
Net wealth−0.001***
(0.000)
High school (W)0.063*0.069**0.064*0.068**0.073**
(0.034)(0.034)(0.034)(0.034)(0.034)
Associate (W)0.086**0.098**0.090**0.097**0.104**
(0.042)(0.042)(0.042)(0.042)(0.042)
Bach. or higher (W)0.094**0.111**0.096**0.107**0.121**
(0.047)(0.047)(0.047)(0.048)(0.048)
High school (H)−0.017−0.018−0.019−0.020−0.015
(0.032)(0.032)(0.032)(0.032)(0.032)
Associate (H)0.0740.0740.0710.0720.079
(0.051)(0.051)(0.051)(0.051)(0.051)
Bach. or higher (H)−0.017−0.013−0.020−0.020−0.007
(0.035)(0.035)(0.035)(0.035)(0.035)
Religiosity0.017**0.017**0.018**0.017**0.016**
(0.008)(0.008)(0.008)(0.008)(0.008)
Constant0.441***0.457***0.442***0.437***0.420***
(0.063)(0.061)(0.063)(0.063)(0.064)
N1,8311,8311,8311,8311,831
  1. Notes: Significance levels: *** is <0.01, ** is <0.05 and * is <0.10. Huber/White robust standard errors are in parentheses. H stands for husband and W denotes wife. Abbreviations Rec., Exp. and Bach. stand for “received,” “expected” and “bachelor,” respectively.

Table 8:

Poisson regressions: robustness analyses.

VariableModel 1Model 2Model 3Model 4Model 5
Transfer Rec. (W)−0.048**−0.041*−0.035
(0.021)(0.021)(0.022)
Transfer Rec. (H)0.037**0.033*0.032*
(0.018)(0.018)(0.018)
Transfer Exp. (W)−0.001−0.015−0.004
(0.026)(0.026)(0.027)
Transfer Exp. (H)0.042*0.0150.018
(0.022)(0.022)(0.023)
Inter vivos Rec. (W)−0.060**−0.055**
(0.028)(0.028)
Inter vivos Rec. (H)0.069***0.055**
(0.025)(0.026)
Inter vivos Exp. (W)−0.048
(0.059)
Inter vivos Exp. (H)0.080*
(0.045)
Marriage duration0.008***0.022***0.022***0.006***0.007***
(0.001)(0.003)(0.004)(0.001)(0.001)
Net wealth−0.000−0.000−0.001***−0.001***
(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)
Wealth index−0.012***
(0.002)
Age (W)−0.023***−0.026***
(0.004)(0.004)
Age (H)0.004
(0.004)
High school (W)0.075**0.0470.0360.084**0.091**
(0.034)(0.034)(0.034)(0.036)(0.036)
Associate (W)0.107**0.082*0.0650.109**0.119***
(0.042)(0.042)(0.043)(0.045)(0.045)
Bach. or higher (W)0.125***0.105**0.090*0.136***0.142***
(0.047)(0.048)(0.049)(0.051)(0.051)
High school (H)−0.013−0.019−0.000−0.037−0.041
(0.031)(0.032)(0.032)(0.032)(0.032)
Associate (H)0.087*0.0770.0740.0810.068
(0.051)(0.052)(0.054)(0.052)(0.052)
Bach. or higher (H)0.000−0.0090.009−0.040−0.044
(0.035)(0.035)(0.036)(0.036)(0.036)
Religiosity0.015*0.021***0.023***0.023***0.021**
(0.008)(0.008)(0.008)(0.009)(0.009)
Constant0.407***1.309***1.267***0.453***0.442***
(0.064)(0.133)(0.159)(0.065)(0.066)
N1,8311,8311,7251,6761,657
  1. Notes: Significance levels: *** is <0.01, ** is <0.05 and * is <0.10. Huber/White robust standard errors are in parentheses. H stands for husband and W denotes wife. Abbreviations Rec., Exp. and Bach. stand for “received,” “expected” and “bachelor,” respectively.

References

Al-Qudusi, S. 1998. “The Demand for Children in Arab Countries: Evidence from Panel and Count Data Model.” Journal of Population Economics 11: 435–52.10.1007/s001480050078Suche in Google Scholar

Apps, P. F., and R. Rees. 1988. “Taxation and the Household.” Journal of Public Economics 35: 355–69.10.1016/0047-2727(88)90037-0Suche in Google Scholar

Azmat, G., and L. González. 2010. “Targeting Fertility and Female Participation through the Income Tax.” Labour Economics 17: 487–502.10.1016/j.labeco.2009.09.006Suche in Google Scholar

Bar, M., M. Hazan, O. Leukhina, D. Weiss, and H. Zoabi. 2017. “Is the Market Pronatalist? Inequality, Differential Fertility, and Growth Revisited.” Working paper, Tel Aviv University.Suche in Google Scholar

Basu, K. 2006. “Gender and Say: A Model of Household Behaviour with Endogenously Determined Balance of Power.” Economic Journal 116: 558–80.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2006.01092.xSuche in Google Scholar

Becker, G. S. 1960. “An Economic Analysis of Fertility,” in Demographic and Economic Change in Developed Countries, edited by Universities National Bureau, 209– 31. New York: Columbia University Press.Suche in Google Scholar

Becker, G. S., and H. G. Lewis. 1973. “On the Interaction between the Quantity and Quality of Children.” Journal of Political Economy 81: S279–S288.10.1086/260166Suche in Google Scholar

Becker, G. S., and N. Tomes. 1976. “Child Endowments and the Quantity and Quality of Children.” Journal of Political Economy 84: S143–S162.10.1086/260536Suche in Google Scholar

Bellido, H., M. Marcén, and J. A. Molina. 2016. “The Effect of Culture on Fertility Behavior of US Teen Mothers.” Feminist Economics 22: 101–26.10.1080/13545701.2015.1120881Suche in Google Scholar

Bergstrom, T. C. 1997. “A Survey of Theories of the Family.” In Handbook of Population and Family Economics, vol. 1A, edited by M. R. Rosenzweig and O. Stark, 21–79. Amsterdam: Elsevier B. V.10.1016/S1574-003X(97)80019-0Suche in Google Scholar

Bernheim, B. D., A. Shleifer, and L. H. Summers. 1985. “The Strategic Bequest Motive.” Journal of Political Economy 93: 1045–76.10.1086/261351Suche in Google Scholar

Black, D. A., N. Kolesnikova, S. G. Sanders, and L. J. Taylor. 2013. “Are Children ‘Normal’?” Review of Economics and Statistics 95: 21–33.10.1162/REST_a_00257Suche in Google Scholar

Brown, M., C. J. Flinn, and J. Mullins. 2015. “Family Law Effects on Divorce, Fertility and Child Investment.” Working paper, New York University.Suche in Google Scholar

Browning, M., and P.-A. Chiappori. 1998. “Efficient Intra-Household Allocations: A General Characterization and Empirical Tests.” Econometrica 66: 1241–78.10.2307/2999616Suche in Google Scholar

Browning, M., P.-A. Chiappori, and V. Lechene. 2006. “Collective and Unitary Models: A Clarification.” Review of the Economics of the Household 4: 5–14.10.1007/s11150-005-6694-2Suche in Google Scholar

Browning, M., P.-A. Chiappori, and Y. Weiss. 2014. Economics of the Family. New York: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9781139015882Suche in Google Scholar

Bruckner, M., and H. Schwandt. 2015. “Income and Population Growth.” Economic Journal 125: 1653–76.10.1111/ecoj.12152Suche in Google Scholar

Canning, D., D. French, and M. Moore. 2016. “The Economics of Fertility Timing: An Euler Equation Approach.” Working paper, No. 3, University of Belfast, .10.2139/ssrn.2474641Suche in Google Scholar

Chiappori, P.-A. 1988. “Rational Household Labor Supply.” Econometrica 56: 63–90.10.2307/1911842Suche in Google Scholar

Chiappori, P.-A. 1992. “Collective Labor Supply and Welfare.” Journal of Political Economy 100: 437–67.10.1086/261825Suche in Google Scholar

Cigno, A. 2012. “Marriage as a Commitment Device.” Review of Economics of the Household 10: 193–213.10.1007/s11150-012-9141-1Suche in Google Scholar

Cigno, A. 2014. “Is Marriage as Good as a Contract?” CESifo Economic Studies 60: 599–612.10.1093/cesifo/ift010Suche in Google Scholar

Connelly, R., and J. Kimmel. 2015. “If You're Happy and You Know It: How Do Mothers and Fathers in the US Really Feel about Caring for Their Children?” Feminist Economics 21: 1–34.10.1080/13545701.2014.970210Suche in Google Scholar

Córdoba, J. C., and M. Ripoll. 2016. “Intergenerational Transfers and the Fertility-Income Relationship.” Economic Journal 126: 949–77.10.1111/ecoj.12197Suche in Google Scholar

Duflo, E. 2003. “Grandmothers and Granddaughters: Old Age Pension and Intra-Household Allocation in South Africa.” World Bank Economic Review 17: 1–25.10.1093/wber/lhg013Suche in Google Scholar

Ermisch, J. F. 1989. “Purchased Childcare, Optimal Family Size and Mother’s Employment: Theory and Econometric Analysis.” Journal of Population Economics 2: 79–102.10.1007/BF00522403Suche in Google Scholar

Ermisch, J. F. 2003. An Economic Analysis of the Family. Princeton: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9781400880102Suche in Google Scholar

Fisher, H. 2012. “Fertility in a Collective Household Model.” Working paper, University of Sydney.Suche in Google Scholar

Galor, O. 2011. Unified Growth Theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9781400838868Suche in Google Scholar

Galor, O., and D. N. Weil. 2000. “Population, Technology, and Growth: From Malthusian Stagnation to the Demographic Transition and Beyond.” American Economic Review 90: 806–28.10.1257/aer.90.4.806Suche in Google Scholar

Gauthier, A. H., and J. Hatzius. 1997. “Family Benefits and Fertility: An Econometric Analysis.” Population Studies 51: 295–306.10.1080/0032472031000150066Suche in Google Scholar

Gugl, E. 2009. “Income Splitting, Specialization, and Intra-Family Distribution.” Canadian Journal of Economics 42: 1050–71.10.1111/j.1540-5982.2009.01538.xSuche in Google Scholar

Hazan, M., and H. Zoabi. 2006. “Does Longevity Cause Growth? A Theoretical Critique.” Journal of Economic Growth 11: 363–76.10.1007/s10887-006-9008-5Suche in Google Scholar

Hazan, M., and H. Zoabi. 2015. “Do Highly Educated Women Choose Smaller Families?” Economic Journal 125: 1191–226.10.1111/ecoj.12148Suche in Google Scholar

Heckman, J. J., and R. J. Willis. 1976. “Estimation of a Stochastic Model of Reproduction: An Econometric Approach.” In Household Production and Consumption, edited by N. E. Terleckyj, 99–146. New York: Columbia University Press.Suche in Google Scholar

Holloway, S. D., and A. Nagase. 2014. “Child Rearing in Japan.” In Parenting across Cultures: Childrearing, Motherhood and Fatherhood in Non-Western Cultures, vol. 7, edited by H. Selin, 59–76. Dordrecht: Springer.10.1007/978-94-007-7503-9_6Suche in Google Scholar

Horioka, C. Y., E. Gahramanov, A. Hayat, and X. Tang. 2018. “Why Do Children Take Care of Their Elderly Parents? are the Japanese Any Different?” International Economic Review 59: 113–36.10.1111/iere.12264Suche in Google Scholar

Hotz, V. J., J. A. Klerman, and R. J. Willis. 1997. “The Economics of Fertility in Developed Countries.” In Handbook of Population and Family Economics, vol. 1A, edited by M. R. Rosenzweig and O. Stark, 275–347. Amsterdam: Elsevier B. V.10.1016/S1574-003X(97)80024-4Suche in Google Scholar

Jones, L. E., and M. Tertilt. 2008. “An Economic History of Fertility in the United States: 1826-1960.” In Frontiers of Family Economics, vol. 1, edited by P. Rupert, 165–230. Bingley: Emerald Group Publishing.10.1016/S1574-0129(08)00005-7Suche in Google Scholar

Kim, J. 2005. “Sex Selection and Fertility in a Dynamic Model of Conception and Abortion.” Journal of Population Economics 18: 41–67.10.1007/s00148-004-0195-0Suche in Google Scholar

Kim, Y-I. A. 2014. “Lifetime Impact of Cash Transfer on Fertility.” Canadian Studies in Population 41: 97–110.10.25336/P64S52Suche in Google Scholar

Kitao, S. 2015. “Fiscal Cost of Demographic Transition in Japan.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 54: 37–58.10.1016/j.jedc.2015.02.015Suche in Google Scholar

Konrad, K. A., H. Künemund, K. E. Lommerud, and J. R. Robledo. 2002. “Geography of the Family.” American Economic Review 92: 981–98.10.1257/00028280260344551Suche in Google Scholar

Konrad, K. A., and K. E. Lommerud. 1995. “Family Policy with Non-Cooperative Families.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics 97: 581–601.10.2307/3440544Suche in Google Scholar

Kremer, M., and D. L. Chen. 2002. “Income Distribution Dynamics with Endogenous Fertility.” Journal of Economic Growth 7: 227–58.10.1023/A:1020154031908Suche in Google Scholar

Kureishi, W., and M. Wakabayashi. 2011. “Son Preference in Japan.” Journal of Population Economics 24: 873–93.10.1007/s00148-009-0282-3Suche in Google Scholar

Lépine, A., and E. Strobl. 2013. “The Effect of Women’s Bargaining Power on Child Nutrition in Rural Senegal.” World Development 45: 17–30.10.1016/j.worlddev.2012.12.018Suche in Google Scholar

McGarry, K. 1999. “Inter Vivos Transfers and Intended Bequests.” Journal of Public Economics 73: 321–51.10.1016/S0047-2727(99)00017-1Suche in Google Scholar

Meier, V., and H. Rainer. 2015. “Pigou Meets Ramsey: Gender-Based Taxation with Non-Cooperative Couples.” European Economic Review 77: 28–46.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2015.03.010Suche in Google Scholar

Meier, V., and H. Rainer. 2017. “Daddy Months.” Journal of Population Economics 30: 875–92.10.1007/s00148-016-0631-ySuche in Google Scholar

Milligan, K. 2005. “Subsidizing the Stork: New Evidence on Tax Incentives and Fertility.” Review of Economics and Statistics 87: 539–55.10.1162/0034653054638382Suche in Google Scholar

Mira, P. 2007. “Uncertain Infant Mortality, Learning, and Life-Cycle Fertility.” International Economic Review 48: 809–46.10.1111/j.1468-2354.2007.00446.xSuche in Google Scholar

Moffitt, R. 1984. “Optimal Life-Cycle Profiles of Fertility and Labor Supply.” Research in Population Economics 5: 29–50.Suche in Google Scholar

Mörk, E., A. Sjögren, and H. Svaleryd. 2013. “Childcare Costs and the Demand for Children - Evidence from a Nationwide Reform.” Journal of Population Economics 26: 33–65.10.1007/s00148-011-0399-zSuche in Google Scholar

Newman, J. L. 1988. “A Stochastic Dynamic Model of Fertility.” Research in Population Economics 6: 41–68.Suche in Google Scholar

Ogawa, N. 2003. “Japan’s Changing Fertility Mechanisms and Its Policy Responses.” Journal of Population Research 20: 89–106.10.1007/BF03031797Suche in Google Scholar

Oliveira, J. 2016. “The Value of Children: Inter-Generational Support, Fertility and Human Capital.” Journal of Development Economics 120: 1–16.10.1016/j.jdeveco.2015.12.002Suche in Google Scholar

Samuelson, P. A. 1956. “Social Indifference Curves.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 70: 1–22.10.2307/1884510Suche in Google Scholar

Sánchez-Romero, M., N. Ogawa, and R. Matsukura. 2013. “To Give or Not to Give a Bequest: Bequest Estimate and Wealth Impact Based on a CGE Model with Realistic Demography in Japan.” Working paper, Max Planck Institute for Demographic Research.10.4054/MPIDR-WP-2013-012Suche in Google Scholar

Schultz, T. P. 1990. “Testing the Neoclassical Model of Family Labor Supply and Fertility.” Journal of Human Resources 25: 599–634.10.2307/145669Suche in Google Scholar

Schultz, T. P. 1997. “Demand for Children in Low Income Countries.” In Handbook of Population and Family Economics, vol. 1A, edited by M. R. Rosenzweig and O. Stark, 349–430. Amsterdam: Elsevier B. V.10.1016/S1574-003X(97)80025-6Suche in Google Scholar

Sleebos, J. E. 2003. “Low Fertility Rates in OECD Countries: Facts and Policy Responses.” OECD Labour Market and Social Policy Occasional Papers 15: 1–62.Suche in Google Scholar

Strulik, H., and S. Vollmer. 2015. “The Fertility Transition around the World.” Journal of Population Economics 28: 31–44.10.1007/s00148-013-0496-2Suche in Google Scholar

Thomas, D. 1990. “Intra-Household Resource Allocation: An Inferential Approach.” Journal of Human Resources 25: 635–64.10.2307/145670Suche in Google Scholar

Varian, H. R. 1984. “Social Indifference Curves and Aggregate Demand.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 99: 403–14.10.2307/1885957Suche in Google Scholar

Wang, Q., and X. Sun. 2016. “The Role of Socio-Political and Economic Factors in Fertility Decline: A Cross-Country Analysis.” World Development 87: 360–70.10.1016/j.worlddev.2016.07.004Suche in Google Scholar

Weil, D. N. 2016. Economic Growth. London and New York: Routledge.10.4324/9781315510453Suche in Google Scholar

Wilhelm, M. O. 1996. “Bequest Behavior and the Effect of Heirs’ Earnings: Testing the Altruistic Model of Bequests.” American Economics Review 86: 874–92.Suche in Google Scholar

Willis, R. J. 1973. “A New Approach to the Economic Theory of Fertility Behavior.” Journal of Political Economy 81: S14–S64.10.1086/260152Suche in Google Scholar

Wolpin, K. I. 1984. “An Estimable Dynamic Stochastic Model of Fertility and Child Mortality.” Journal of Political Economy 92: 852–74.10.1086/261262Suche in Google Scholar

Yamamoto, Y. 2015. “Social Class and Japanese Mothers’ Support of Young Children’s Education: A Qualitative Study.” Journal of Early Childhood Research 13: 165–80.10.1177/1476718X13482303Suche in Google Scholar

Yamamura, E. 2013. “Effects of Sex Preference and Social Pressure on Fertility in Changing Japanese Families.” Journal of Socio-Economics 46: 97–104.10.1016/j.socec.2013.08.002Suche in Google Scholar

Zhang, J., J. Quan, and P. Van Meerbergen. 1994. “The Effect of Tax-Transfer Policies on Fertility in Canada, 1921-88.” Journal of Human Resources 29: 181–201.10.2307/146061Suche in Google Scholar


Supplementary Material

The online version of this article offers supplementary material (DOI:https://doi.org/10.1515/bejeap-2018-0118).



Note

This research uses micro-data from the Preference Parameters Study of Osaka University’s twenty-first Century COE Program “Behavioral Macrodynamics Based on Surveys and Experiments” and its Global COE project “Human Behavior and Socioeconomic Dynamics.”


Published Online: 2018-10-12

© 2019 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Heruntergeladen am 2.10.2025 von https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejeap-2018-0118/html
Button zum nach oben scrollen