Startseite Likelihood-Ratio-Based Confidence Intervals for Multiple Threshold Parameters
Artikel
Lizenziert
Nicht lizenziert Erfordert eine Authentifizierung

Likelihood-Ratio-Based Confidence Intervals for Multiple Threshold Parameters

  • Luiggi Donayre ORCID logo EMAIL logo
Veröffentlicht/Copyright: 8. August 2024
Veröffentlichen auch Sie bei De Gruyter Brill

Abstract

This paper proposes the inversion of likelihood ratio tests for the construction of confidence intervals for multiple threshold parameters. Using Monte Carlo simulations, conservative likelihood-ratio-based confidence intervals are shown to exhibit empirical coverage rates at least as high as nominal levels for all threshold parameters, while still being informative in the sense of only including relatively few observations in each confidence interval. These findings are robust to the magnitude of the threshold effect, the sample size and the presence of serial correlation. Applications to existing models with multiple thresholds for U.S. real GDP growth and for the wage Phillips curve demonstrate how the proposed approach is empirically relevant to make inferences about the uncertainty of threshold estimates.

JEL Classification: C15; C22

Corresponding author: Luiggi Donayre, Department of Economics, University of Minnesota – Duluth, 1318 Kirby Dr., Duluth, MN 55812, USA, E-mail: 

Helpful comments from Yunjong Eo, James Morley, Xinyu Zhang and participants at the 2022 Midwest Economics Research Group Annual Conference, the 2022 International Conference on Computational Statistics, and the 2022 Latin American Meetings of the Econometric Society, as well as as the use of code provided by Dong Li and Shiqing Ling, are gratefully acknowledged. All errors are my own.


Appendix: Discussion of assumptions

In ensuring the asymptotical equivalence between the limiting distribution of the likelihood ratio statistic for the construction of confidence intervals in multiple threshold and multiple break point settings, the assumptions in Eo and Morley (2015) are followed closely and adapted to the threshold regression environment of equation (1). Let the true values of the parameters be denoted with a superscript 0 and, for any i = 1, 2, …, m + 1, define the moment functionals M ( γ ) = E x t 1 x t 1 1 i , t γ i , d , D ( γ ) = E x t 1 x t 1 | q t d = γ and V ( γ ) = E x t 1 x t 1 e t 2 | q t d = γ . Then, the assumptions are given as follows:

Assumption 1.

For i = 1, 2, …, m + 1, t i /T ≥ τ as T for some τ > 0, where t i = t = 1 T 1 i , t γ , d .

Assumption 2.

y t , q t , e t t = 1 T is strictly stationary, ergodic and ρ-mixing, with ρ-mixing coefficients satisfying ρ m  = O(ρ m ) with |ρ| < 1, so that j = 1 ρ j 1 / 2 < .

Assumption 3.

E e t | F t 1 = 0 and E e t 2 < , where F t 1 is the Borel sigma-field σ (y t , yt−1, yt−2, …).

Assumption 4.

For F = σ field , y t 2 , y t 1 , , e t 3 , e t 2 , y t e t , F form a strongly mixing sequence so that E | x t 1 | 4 < and E | x t 1 e t | 4 < .

Assumption 5.

For all γ ∈ Γ i ,  E | x t 1 | 4 e t 4 | q t d = γ M ; E | x t 1 | 4 | q t d = γ M for some M < ,  where  Γ i = q t 1 i , t γ , d t = 1 T for i = 1, …, m;  and f ( γ ) f ( γ i 0 ) < for f (q t ) the density function of q t .

Assumption 6.

The functions f (γ), D (γ) and V (γ) are continuous at γ = γ i 0 for i = 1, 2, …, m.

Assumption 7.

The magnitudes of the threshold effects satisfy Δ β i = β i + 1 0 β i 0 = υ T δ i , where δ i  ≠ 0 and υ T is a sequence of positive numbers that satisfy υ T → 0 and T1/2 υ T /(logT)2.

Assumption 8.

The conditional mean satisfies υ T D γ i 0 υ T > 0 , υ T V γ i 0 υ T > 0 ,  and f ( γ i 0 ) > 0 , and M γ i 0 > M ( γ ) > 0 for all γ ∈ Γ i and i = 1, …, m.

To verify that equations (7) and (8) satisfy these assumptions, note that Assumption 1 restricts the threshold γ i so that each regime contains a minimum number of observations, where t i is the number of sample of observations in the ith regime. This ensures the threshold parameters to be asymptotically different and it is enforced during the estimation process as discussed in the main text, setting τ = 0.1. Assumption 2 is important given the dynamics of time series and is trivially satisfied for independent observations. Threshold processes of the types in equations (7) and (8) exhibit a strong form of geometric ergodicity, which implies Assumption 2 (Chan 1989). Assumption 3 imposes that the error term is zero-meaned with finite variance, so that the model in equation (1) correctly specifies the conditional mean, and ordinary least squares (OLS) estimation is appropriate. The error terms associated with equations (7) and (8) follow a normal distribution with mean zero and variance σ2, which satisfy this assumption.

Assumptions 4 and 5 determine the structure of the x t e t and e t processes and imply conditional and unconditional bounded fourth moments. Since the relevant characteristic polynomials of equations (7) and (8) have roots that lie outside the unit circle and the errors distribute normally and are i.i.d. (that is, they have a bounded and continuous probability density function), Assumptions 4 and 5 are satisfied (Chan 1993; Gonzalo and Pitarakis 2002; Hansen 2000). Assumption 6 requires the threshold variable to have a continuous distribution, effectively requiring the conditional variance E e t 2 | q t d = γ to be continuous at γ i 0 for i = 1, …, m, which excludes the possibility of regime-dependent heteroskedasticity. Since the error terms follow the same distributions across regimes, Assumption 6 is satisfied.

Assumption 7 implies that the magnitude of the threshold effect Δ β i → 0 as T, which guarantees that the limiting distribution is free of nuisance parameters and, therefore, allow for the construction of confidence intervals. Of course, the threshold effect for any give sample size T is of fixed magnitude. However, the asymptotic distribution of the likelihood ratio statistic for a shrinking threshold effect provides an upper bound on the distribution under a fixed threshold effect under normal errors (Hansen 2000). Therefore, any confidence intervals will overcover for any given experiment.

Finally, Assumption 8 is a full-rank condition which excludes multicollinearity and is necessary to ensure non-degenerate asymptotic distributions. Since γ ∈ Γ i , and all threshold parameters are required to lie in the bounded set Γ = γ ̲ , γ ̄ , Assumption 8 is then satisfied.

References

Abreu, D. S., and A. S. Lopes. 2021. “How to Disappear Completely: Nonlinearity and Endogeneity in the New Keynesian Wage Phillips Curve.” Applied Economics Letters 28 (9): 774–8. https://doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2020.1781763.Suche in Google Scholar

Ahmad, Y., and L. Donayre. 2016. “Outliers and Persistence in Threshold Autoregressive Processes.” Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics 20 (1): 37–56. https://doi.org/10.1515/snde-2014-0058.Suche in Google Scholar

Aleem, A., and A. Lahiani. 2014. “A Threshold Vector Autoregression Model of Exchange Rate Pass-Through in Mexico.” Research in International Business and Finance 30: 24–33. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ribaf.2013.05.001.Suche in Google Scholar

Bec, F., M. Ben-Salem, and M. Carrasco. 2004. “Tests for Unit Root Versus Threshold Specification with an Application to the Purchase Power Parity Relationship.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 22: 382–95. https://doi.org/10.1198/073500104000000389.Suche in Google Scholar

Chan, K. S. 1989. “A Note on the Ergodicity of a Markov Chain.” Advances in Applied Probability 21: 702–4. https://doi.org/10.1017/s0001867800018887.Suche in Google Scholar

Chan, K. S. 1993. “Consistency and Limiting Distribution of the Least Squares Estimator of a Threshold Autoregressive Model.” Annals of Statistics 21: 520–33. https://doi.org/10.1214/aos/1176349040.Suche in Google Scholar

Donayre, L. 2022. “On the Behavior of Okun’s Law Across Business Cycles.” Economic Modelling 112: 105858. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2022.105858.Suche in Google Scholar

Donayre, L., Y. Eo, and J. Morley. 2018. “Improving Likelihood-Ratio-Based Confidence Intervals for Threshold Parameters in Finite Samples.” Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics 22 (1): 1–11. https://doi.org/10.1515/snde-2016-0084.Suche in Google Scholar

Donayre, L., and I. Panovska. 2016. “Nonlinearities in the U.S. Wage Phillips Curve.” Journal of Macroeconomics 48: 19–43. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2016.01.004.Suche in Google Scholar

Enders, W., B. Falk, and P. Siklos. 2007. “A Threshold Model of U.S. Real GDP and the Problem of Constructing Confidence Intervals in TAR Models.” Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics 11 (3): 4. https://doi.org/10.2202/1558-3708.1322.Suche in Google Scholar

Eo, Y., and J. C. Morley. 2015. “Likelihood-Ratio-Based Confidence Sets for the Timing of Structural Breaks.” Quantitative Economics 6 (2): 463–7. https://doi.org/10.3982/qe186.Suche in Google Scholar

Galí, J. 2011. “The Return of the Wage Phillips Curve.” Journal of the European Economic Association 9 (3): 436–61. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1542-4774.2011.01023.x.Suche in Google Scholar

Gonzalo, J., and J.-Y. Pitarakis. 2002. “Estimation and Model Selection Based Inference in Single and Multiple Threshold Models.” Journal of Econometrics 110: 319–52. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0304-4076(02)00098-2.Suche in Google Scholar

Hansen, B. E. 1997. “Inference in TAR Models.” Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics 2 (1): 1–14. https://doi.org/10.2202/1558-3708.1024.Suche in Google Scholar

Hansen, B. E. 1999. “Testing for Linearity.” Journal of Economic Surveys 13 (5): 551–76. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-6419.00098.Suche in Google Scholar

Hansen, B. E. 2000. “Sample Splitting and Threshold Estimation.” Econometrica 68: 575–603. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00124.Suche in Google Scholar

Li, D., and S. Ling. 2012. “On the Least Squares Estimation of Multiple-Regime Threshold Autoregressive Models.” Journal of Econometrics 167: 240–53. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2011.11.006.Suche in Google Scholar

Potter, S. 1995. “A Nonlinear Approach to U.S. GNP.” Journal of Applied Econometrics 10: 109–25. https://doi.org/10.1002/jae.3950100203.Suche in Google Scholar


Supplementary Material

This article contains supplementary material (https://doi.org/10.1515/snde-2023-0029).


Received: 2023-04-05
Accepted: 2024-07-12
Published Online: 2024-08-08

© 2024 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Heruntergeladen am 22.9.2025 von https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/snde-2023-0029/html
Button zum nach oben scrollen