Home A new route to the rapid growth of the service sector: rise of the standard of living
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

A new route to the rapid growth of the service sector: rise of the standard of living

  • Harutaka Takahashi EMAIL logo and Kansho Piotr Otsubo
Published/Copyright: April 24, 2019

Abstract

In the present study, we set up a continuous-time two-sector optimal growth model with services and manufacturing goods and then examine structural change: the rapid growth of the service sector. Earlier studies of structural changes can be separated into two categories: preference-driven and technology-driven. Here we introduce a new and distinct category of structural change: consumption externality identified as rise of the living standard. A key assumption is that (1) a representative consumer has a non-homothetic Stone–Geary type utility function with respect to manufacturing goods and that (2) its subsistence level will be regarded as the standard of living and will be affected by the average consumption of manufacturing goods, which also affects the consumption level of services. We also assume that the manufacturing sector is more capital-intensive than the service sector, which takes an important role in our proofs. Results show that a steady state equilibrium exists that is globally stable as well as saddle-point stable. Then, given certain production parameters in a steady state, there exists optimal steady state where the value-added and employment shares by service sector will dominate those of the manufacturing sector under the condition that external effects of the service sector dominates capital-intensity effect of the manufacturing sector. In other words, through the transition process, the service sector will dominate the manufacturing sector in the steady state.

JEL Classification: O41; O11; E21; E22

Acknowledgement

We thank an anonymous referee for helpful comments and suggestions. Especially, Kunieda and Nishimura (2016) has inspired us to write the paper. The previous version was presented at the conference “Real and financial interdependences: new approaches with dynamic equilibrium models” held at the Paris School of Economics in July 2017. We thank the conference participants, especially X. Raurich and A. Venditti for their comments and suggestions. We also thank Ngo Van Long for detailed review of the paper.

Appendix A

Rewriting (19) and (20) with the natural logarithm, one can obtain

(24)ln(pScS)=ln(pS)+lncS=ln(ps)+lnk(1β)ln[(1+M)kMkS]

and

(25)lny=ln(kkS)+(1α)(1+M)(1α)ln[(1+M)MkS].

Subtracting (25) from (24) will yield

(26)lnpscSlny=lnps+[lnkSln(kkS)]+[(1α)(1+M)]+{[(1β)(1α)]ln[(1+M)kMkS]}.

Now we will show that each term of the right hand side of (26) will turn to be positive.

  1. lnpS>0

    Due to Assumption 6, it readily follows that lnpS>0.

  2. [lnkSln(kkS)]>0

    All we need to show is that kS>kkS. Substituting (16) into the equation and after some manipulation yields

    kS(kkS)=2kSk=2(BAk)k=2B(2A+1)k.

    Therefore, the condition (*) implies that 2B(2A+1)k>0 and kS(kkS)>0.

  3. –(1 – α)ln(1 + M) > 0

    Due to Assumption 5, it follows that −1 < M < 0. Thus 0 < 1 + M < 1 holds and it implies that ln(1 + M) < 0. This is what we wanted.

  4. [(1β)(1α)]ln[(1+M)kMkS]>0

    (M+1)kMkS=β(1α)α(1β)kMB+MAk=β(1α)α(1β)kMBβ(1α)α(1β)k=MB,

    whereMA=β(1α)α(1β).

Thus we need to show that 0 < −MB < 1 where

MB=[αβα(1β)](DpS)1α(αβ)=D1αα(1β)(pS)1α.

Note that

D1αα(1β)(pS)1α<1[D1αα(1β)(pS)1α]α=D[α(1β)]α(pS)<1pS<[α(1β)]αD=(αβ)α(1α1β)1α.

Assumption 6 will establish the last inequality and ln[(1+M)kMkS]<0.

Since Assumption 5 implies that −[(1 − β) − (1 − α)] < 0, we establish the result that we wanted. Finally, combining all the results 1. through 4. will complete the Proof.    ■

Appendix B

Due to Assumption 5, let us define β = αɛ where ɛ > 0. Then, we have

(27)(αβ)α(1α1β)1α=(ααε)α(1α1α+ε)1α.

Rewriting Eq. (27) with natural logarithm yields,

I(ε)α[lnαln(αε)]+(1α)[ln(1α)ln(1α+ε)].

Differentiate I(ɛ) with respect to ɛ yields

dIdε=ααε1α1α+ε=αβ1α1β=αββ(1β)>0.

Since I(0)=0(αβ)α(1α1β)1α=1, then dIdε>0 implies that ε>0I(0)>0. Therefor, it readily follows that (αβ)α(1α1β)1α>1. We complete the Proof.    ■

References

Acemoglu, D., and V. Guerrieri. 2008. “Capital Deepening and Nonbalanced Economic Growth.” Journal of Political Economy 116: 467–498.10.1086/589523Search in Google Scholar

Alonso-Carrera, J., and X. Raurich. 2015. “Demand-Based Structural Change and Balanced Economic Growth.” Journal of Macroeconomics 46: 356–374.10.1016/j.jmacro.2015.10.005Search in Google Scholar

Alonso-Carrera, J., J. Caballe, and X. Raurich. 2008. “Can Consumption Spillovers Be a Source of Equilibrium Indeterminacy?” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32 (29): 2883–2902.10.1016/j.jedc.2007.12.001Search in Google Scholar

Alvarez-Cuadrado, F., N. V. Long, and M. Poschke. 2017. “Capital-Labor Substitution, Structural Change, and Growth.” Theoretical Economics 12 (3): 1229–1266.10.3982/TE2106Search in Google Scholar

Ariu, A., F. Mayneris, and M. Parenti. 2018. “One Way to the Top: How Services Boost the Demand for Goods.” NBB Discussion Papers 340, National Bank of Belgium.Search in Google Scholar

Baierl, G., K. Nishimura, and M. Yano. 1998. “The Role of Capital Depreciation in Multi-Sectoral Models.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 33: 467–479.10.1016/S0167-2681(97)00070-XSearch in Google Scholar

Baumol, W. J. 1967. “Macroeconomics of Nonbalanced Growth: The Anatomy of Urban Crisis.” American Economic Review 57 (3): 415–426.Search in Google Scholar

Boppart, T. 2013. “Structural Change and the Kaldor Facts in a Growth Model with Relative Price Effects and Non-Gorman Preferences.” Working Paper. http://hdl.handle.net/10419/79777.Search in Google Scholar

Chen, B. L., Y.-S. Hsu, and K. Mino. 2015. “Welfare Implications and Equilibrium Indeterminancy in a Two-Sector Growth Model with Consumption Externalities.” Macroeconomic Dynamics 19 (3): 535–577.10.1017/S1365100514000613Search in Google Scholar

Dennis, B., and T. Iscan. 2009. “Engle versus Baumol: Accounting for Structural Change Using Two Centuries of U.S. Data.” Explorations in Economic History 46: 186–202.10.1016/j.eeh.2008.11.003Search in Google Scholar

Echevarria, C. 1997. “Changes in Sectoral Composition Associated with Economic Growth.” International Economic Review 38: 431–452.10.2307/2527382Search in Google Scholar

Foellmi, R., and J. Zweimuller. 2008. “Structural Change, Engel’s Consumption Cycles and Kaldor’s Facts of Economic Growth.” Journal of Monetary Economics 55: 1317–1328.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2008.09.001Search in Google Scholar

Herrendorf, B., R. Rogerson, and A. Valentinyi. 2014. “Chapter 6 – Growth and Structural Transformation.” In: Handbook of Economic Growth, Vol. 2, edited by P. Aghion and S. Durlauf, 855–941. Amsterdam: North-Holland.10.1016/B978-0-444-53540-5.00006-9Search in Google Scholar

Hori, T., M. Ikefuji, and K. Mino. 2015. “Conformism and Structural Change.” International Economic Review 56 (3): 939–961.10.1111/iere.12127Search in Google Scholar

Kongsamut, P., S. Rebelo, and D. Xie. 2001. “Beyond Balanced Growth.” Review of Economic Studies 68: 869–882.10.3386/w6159Search in Google Scholar

Kunieda, T., and K. Nishimura. 2016. “Consumption Externalities and Indeterminacy in a Continuous-Time Two-Sector Growth Model.” International Journal of Dynamical Systems and Differential Equations 6 (4): 358–369.10.1504/IJDSDE.2016.081821Search in Google Scholar

Laitner, J. 2000. “Structural Change and Economic Growth.” Review of Economic Studies 67: 545–561.10.1111/1467-937X.00143Search in Google Scholar

Ngai, R., and C. Pissarides. 2007. “Structural Change in a Multisector Model of Growth.” American Economic Review 97 (1): 429–443.10.1257/aer.97.1.429Search in Google Scholar

Nishimura, K., and M. Yano. 1995. “Non-Linearity and Business Cycles in a Two-Sector Equilibrium Model: An Example with Cobb-Douglas Production Functions.” In Nonlinear and Convex Analysis in Economic Theory (Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical System 149), edited by Toru Maruyama Wataru Takahashi. Berlin, New York: Springer-Verlag.10.1007/978-3-642-48719-4_18Search in Google Scholar

Takahashi, H. 2016. “Chapter 14 – Nonbalanced Growth in a Neoclassical Two-Sector Optimal Growth Model.” In Sunspot and Non-linear Dynamics, edited by K. Nishimura, A. Venditti and N. Yannelis, 339–359. Springer Nature.10.1007/978-3-319-44076-7_14Search in Google Scholar

Uzawa, H. 1964. “Optimal Growth in a Two-Sector Model of Capital Accumulation.” Review of Economic Studies 31: 1–24.10.1017/CBO9780511664496.019Search in Google Scholar

Valentinyi, A., and B. Herrendorf. 2008. “Measuring Factor Income Shares at the Sectoral Level.” Review of Economic Dynamics 11: 820–835.10.1016/j.red.2008.02.003Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2019-04-24

©2019 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 28.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/snde-2019-0018/html
Scroll to top button