Startseite Incentives for Conditional Aid Effectiveness
Artikel
Lizenziert
Nicht lizenziert Erfordert eine Authentifizierung

Incentives for Conditional Aid Effectiveness

  • Francisco Candel-Sánchez EMAIL logo
Veröffentlicht/Copyright: 6. September 2014

Abstract

Can sanctions against foreign aid donors enhance the credibility of conditional aid policies? If such policies suffer from time inconsistency, the answer is positive. This paper proposes a mechanism to overcome the lack of credibility of conditional aid donations to developing countries. A scheme of policy-dependent transfers to the donor country is shown to achieve an optimal commitment outcome by improving the credibility of conditional aid programs. The scheme is devised to cover situations in which the cost of structural reforms is information privately owned by the recipient government.


Corresponding author: Francisco Candel-Sánchez, Dept. de Fundamentos del Análisis Económico, Universidad de Murcia, 30100 Murcia, Spain, e-mail:

Acknowledgments

This paper has benefited from the comments and suggestions of Ravi Kanbur, Ashley Piggins and Stéphane Straub. I also thank two anonymous reviewers and the editors of this journal for very helpful comments. Financial support from the Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness through MEC/FEDER grant ECO2010-21624 is gratefully acknowledged.

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1: First of all, we prove that, faced with yopt, the recipient’s best response is zopt. This conclusion follows whenever the inequality (k–1)yopt>θ holds. Assumptions 1 and 2 imply that θ<k1k(C¯12γk)=(k1)yopt. On the other hand, yopt is the value for y that minimizes L(y, zopt). Next we show that the pair (yopt, zopt) is the unique SPE of the game. To see this, consider any alternative strategy y0yopt If (k–1)y0>θ then y0 cannot belong to an equilibrium. The reason is that faced with y0 the recipient would set z=1, but the value that minimizes L(y, zopt) is yopty0. If (k–1)y0=θ any z0 would be a best response. Consider z0<1. The pair (θk1,z0) cannot be an equilibrium, since aid level yopt would induce reforms zopt and the strategy pair (yopt, zopt) gives a higher payoff to the donor. For z0=1, the donor would be better off by selecting yopt, so (y0, 1) is neither an equilibrium. Finally, if (k–1)y0<θ the recipient sets up z=0. Let us call y0 the value for y0 that minimizes the donor’s loss given that z=0. Observe first that any pair (y0, 0) with y0y0 can never be an equilibrium since by definition y0 yields a better payoff than y0. We have that (y0,0) is neither an equilibrium. The reason is that the donor’s loss associated with the pair (y0,0) is given by L0=C¯14γ while the loss under (yopt, zopt) is given by Lopt=1k(C¯14γk), and Lopt<L0 since γ12C¯k1k is implied by Assumption 2. Therefore, (y0,0) is not a SPE of the game. This completes the proof.

Proof of Proposition 2:

Let p(y)=prob(θky). The donor’s problem is:

min{y}p(y)L(y,1)+[1p(y)]L(0,0).

Let yC be the solution of the above problem. We write the first order condition as:

p(yC)[L(yC,1)L(0,0)]+p(yC)L(yC,1)=0.

From this condition we obtain:

L(yC,1)=p(yC)p(yC)[L(yC,1)L(0,0)]

The loss function is such that L(yC, 1)<L(0, 0). Then, from the above FOC we deduce that L′(yC, 1)>0. On the other hand, since yopt minimizes function L(y, 1) we have L′(yopt, 1)=0. The inequality L′(yC, 1)>L′(yopt, 1)=0 holds, and then yC>yopt.

Proof of Proposition 3: Faced with z* in Eq. (5) the donor disburses

y=y(z)=(2γθk1)1/2C¯θk1.

The minimal loss associated with any given z is:

l(z)=L(z,y(z))=A(z)[C¯14γA(z)].

It is easy to see that l′(z)<0. As z*<zopt=1, we have that l(z*)>l(zopt). On the other hand, consumption level in the equilibrium pair (y*, z*) is given by

C=C¯(θ2γ(k1))1/2.

We find that C<Coptk1k2<2θγ. The latter inequality is true by Assumption 1. This finishes the proof.

Proof of Proposition 4: We solve the game by backwards induction. In the last stage of the game, the donor selects y to minimize L(y,z)+t(z,λ,θ˜)y. The first order condition of this problem yields the following reaction function:

(7)y(z,λ,θ˜)=A(z)[C¯1+t(z,λ,θ˜)2γA(z)]. (7)

There are several statements in the main text that are now proven here. Observe first that y(z) in Eq. (4) is above y(z,λ,θ˜) for all z and for all λ. This proves the claim that, for given reforms level z, the donor disburses more aid in the absence of a sanction scheme. We are also interested in the dependence on the reports λ and θ˜of the reaction function above.

For this purpose we compute y(z,λ,θ˜)λ=A(z)(1z)[(k1)yoptθ˜]<0, and y(z,λ,θ˜)θ˜=A(z)(1z)(1λ)<0. This proves that, ceteris paribus, the donor’s equilibrium disbursement is lower the higher are λ and/or θ˜. Moreover, aid disbursements are more (less) sensitive to changes in θ˜ the lower (higher) is λ, and vice versa, since 2y(z,λ,θ˜)λθ=A(z)(1z)>0. This feature of the mechanism turns out to be critical to induce truthtelling on the recipient. As we will see below, the donor reports λ high enough so as to avoid the recipient’s misrepresentation of θ˜.

In the second stage of the game, the recipient selects z to maximize Gθ(y(z,λ,θ˜),z). We compute Gθ(.)z=λ[(k1)yoptθ˜]+θ˜θ. Let z^ be the value for z that maximizes Gθ(.). If Gθ(.)z>0, then z^=1, and if Gθ(.)z<0 then z^=0.

An equilibrium of the subgame starting in Stage 2 is given by z^=1 and y(1,λ,θ˜) if λ[(k1)yoptθ˜]+θ˜θ>0. The equilibrium actions are z^=0 and y(0,λ,θ˜) when λ[(k1)yoptθ˜]+θ˜θ<0, and z^[0,1] and y(z,λ,θ˜) when

λ[(k1)yoptθ˜]+θ˜θ=0. To compute the SPE of the game, we assume that both the donor and the recipient are aware of the outcomes derived from all possible equilibria of the subgame starting in Stage 2, and take them into account when announcing simultaneously λ and θ˜ in the first stage of the game.

Let us now analyze the (Nash) equilibrium actions in the announcement stage of the game. Let (λ,θ˜) be a pair of NE actions. Then,

λargmin{λ}L(y(z^,λ,θ˜),z^)+t(z^,λ,θ˜)y(z^,λ,θ˜)

and θ˜argmax{θ˜}Gθ(y(z^,λ,θ˜),z^). Notice that if z^=1, then y(1,λ,θ˜)=yoptfor all λ and θ˜. Next, we show that the highest possible payoff for the donor is obtained when z^=zopt=1 and y(1,λ,θ˜)=yopt. For this purpose, observe first that L(yopt, zopt) is a minimum. It remains to show that t(z,λ,θ˜)>0 for all λ, θ˜,z≠zopt and that t(zopt,λ,θ˜)=0 for all λ, θ˜. The latter is immediate. To prove the former we rewrite the inequality t(z,λ,θ˜)>0 as

2γA(z)(1z){λ[(k1)yoptθ˜]+θ˜12γk1kA(z)}>0.

Provided that 1k<A(z)1 for z<1, Assumptions 1 and 2 imply that (k1)yoptθ˜>0 and Assumption 1 implies θ˜>12γk1kA(z). Hence, t(z,λ,θ˜)>0 holds for all λ, θ˜ and z1. If the penalty rate is positive (except for z=1) and L(yopt, zopt) is the minimum social loss, the donor announces a value for λ with the goal of inducing z=1. Reporting λ* such that λ[(k1)yoptθ˜]+θ˜θ>0 for all θ˜ (including θ˜) dominates any other report. The donor’s announcement must be high enough (so as to induce z^=1 for any possible θ˜) since otherwise, for certain θ˜ it could be the case that λ[(k1)yoptθ˜]+θ˜θ<0 and hence z^=0. Any equilibrium report from the donor must be such that the recipient can never be interested in performing z=0. In the absence of information about θ, the latter possibility is avoided by setting λλ(θ˜)=θHθ˜(k1)yoptθ˜. Function λ(θ˜) is a reaction function to any conjecture about θ˜. Now, given that λ[λ(θ˜),1], the recipient can never get advantage from misrepresenting θ. It turns out that reporting truthfully (i.e. using the strategy s(θ)=θ for all θ) is optimal for the recipient. Then, for the pair (λ,θ˜) to be part of a SPE of the game induced by the mechanism, it is sufficient that λλ(θ˜)and θ˜=s(θ)=θ for all θ.

Finally, since (k1)yopt>θ for all θ, in equilibrium we have Gθ(.)z=λ[(k1)yoptθ]>0. Therefore, the optimal reforms level is zopt=1. Provided that the recipient performs zopt=1 in Stage 2, the donor disburses y(1, λ*, θ)=yopt in Stage 3. This completes the proof.

References

Alesina, A. and D. Dollar (2000) “Who Gives Aid to Whom and Why?” Journal of Economic Growth, 5:33–63.10.1023/A:1009874203400Suche in Google Scholar

Arndt, C., S. Jones and F. Tarp (2010) “Aid, Growth and Development: Have We Come Full Circle?” Journal of Globalization and Development, 1(2):Art. 5.10.2202/1948-1837.1121Suche in Google Scholar

Azam, J.-P. and J.-J. Laffont (2003) “Contracting for Aid,” Journal of Development Economics, 70:25–58.10.1016/S0304-3878(02)00085-8Suche in Google Scholar

Berthélemy, J. C. (2006) “Bilateral Donors’ Interest vs. Recipients’ Development Motives in Aid Allocation: Do All Donors Behave the Same?” Review of Development Economics, 10(2):179–194.10.1111/j.1467-9361.2006.00311.xSuche in Google Scholar

Berthélemy, J. C. and A. Tichit (2004) “Bilateral Donors’ Aid Allocation Decisions –A Three-Dimensional Panel Analysis,” International Review of Economics and Finance, 13:253–274.10.1016/j.iref.2003.11.004Suche in Google Scholar

Boone, P. (1996) “Politics and The Effectiveness of Foreign Aid,” European Economic Review, 40:289–329.10.1016/0014-2921(95)00127-1Suche in Google Scholar

Bräutigam, D. (2000) Aid Dependence and Governance (Vol. 1). Expert Group on Development Issues.Suche in Google Scholar

Buchanan, J. M. (1975) “The Samaritan’s Dilemma.” In: (E. S. Phelps, ed.) Altruism, Morality and Economic Theory. New York: Russel Sage Foundation, pp. 71–85.Suche in Google Scholar

Burall, S., S. Maxwell and A. R. Menocal (2006) Reforming the International Aid Architecture: Options and Ways Forward. Overseas development institute (ODI).Suche in Google Scholar

Burnside, C. and D. Dollar (2000) “Aid, Policies and Growth,” American Economic Review, 90:847–868.10.1257/aer.90.4.847Suche in Google Scholar

Burnside, C. and D. Dollar. (2004) “Aid, Policies and Growth: Reply,” American Economic Review, 94:781–784.10.1257/0002828041464524Suche in Google Scholar

Carter, P. (2013) “Does Foreign Aid Displace Domestic Taxation?” Journal of Globalization and Development, 4(1):1–47.10.1515/jgd-2013-0023Suche in Google Scholar

Clemens, M., S. Radelet and R. Bhavnani (2004) Counting Chickens When They Hatch: The Short Term Effect of Aid on Growth. Center for Global Development working paper, (44).10.2139/ssrn.567241Suche in Google Scholar

Coate, S. (1995) “Altruism, the Samaritan’s Dilemma and Government Transfer Policy,” The American Economic Review, 85(1):46–57.Suche in Google Scholar

Collier, P. (1997) “The Failure of Conditionality.” In: (C. Gwin and J. M. Nelson, eds.) Perspectives on Aid and Development. Policy Essay, Vol. 22. ODC: Washington DC.Suche in Google Scholar

Conway, P. (2006) “Empirical Implications of Endogenous IMF Conditionality.” In: (Kosack, Stephen, Gustav Ranis and James Vreeland eds.) Globalization and the Nation State, Chapter 4, NY: Routledge.Suche in Google Scholar

Cordella, T. and G. Dell’Ariccia (2002) Limits of Conditionality In Poverty Reduction Programs. IMF staff papers 49.Suche in Google Scholar

Cowhey, P. F. (1993) “Domestic Institutions and The Credibility of International Commitments: Japan and the United States,” International Organization, 47(2):299–326.10.1017/S0020818300027958Suche in Google Scholar

Crawford, G. (1997) “Foreign Aid and Political Conditionality: Issues of Effectiveness and Consistency,” Democratization, 4(3):69–108.10.1080/13510349708403526Suche in Google Scholar

Devarajan, S., D. Dollar and T. Holmgren (2001). “Aid and Reform in Africa.” The World Bank.Suche in Google Scholar

Dollar, D. and J. Svensson (2000) “What Explains The Success or Failure of Structural Adjustment Programs,” Economic Journal, 110:894–917.10.1111/1468-0297.00569Suche in Google Scholar

Easterly, W. (2003) “Can Foreign Aid Buy Growth?” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(3):23–48.10.1257/089533003769204344Suche in Google Scholar

Easterly, W., R. Levine and D. Roodman (2004) “Aid, Policies and Growth: Comment,” American Economic Review, 94:774–780.10.1257/0002828041464560Suche in Google Scholar

Fearon, J. D. (1994) “Domestic Political Audiences and The Escalation of International Disputes,” American Political Science Review, 88(3):577–592.10.2307/2944796Suche in Google Scholar

Fearon, J. D. (1998). “Enforcement, and International Cooperation,” International Organization, 52(2):269–305.10.1162/002081898753162820Suche in Google Scholar

Federico, G. (2004) “Aid and Policies Under Weak Donor Conditionality,” Journal of African Economies, 13:395–416.10.1093/jae/ejh028Suche in Google Scholar

Gaubatz, K. T. (1996) “Democratic States and Commitment in International Relations,” International Organization, 50:109–140.10.1017/S0020818300001685Suche in Google Scholar

Grossman, S. J. and O. D. Hart (1982) “Corporate Financial Structure and Managerial Incentives.” In: (J. McCall, ed.) The Economics of Information and Uncertainty. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press, pp. 107–140.Suche in Google Scholar

Hagen, R. J. (2006) “Samaritan Agents? On the Strategic Delegation of Aid Policy,” Journal of Development Economics, 79:249–263.10.1016/j.jdeveco.2004.11.009Suche in Google Scholar

Hansen, H. and F. Tarp (2001) “Aid and Growth regressions,” Journal of Development Economics, 64(2):547–570.10.1016/S0304-3878(00)00150-4Suche in Google Scholar

Kanbur, R. (2000) “Aid, Conditionality and Debt in Africa.” In: (F. Tarp, ed.) Foreign Aid and Development: Lessons Learnt and Directions for the Future. London and New York: Routledge.10.4324/9780203461761.ch18Suche in Google Scholar

Kapur, D. and R. Webb (2000) Governance-Related Conditionalities of the International Financial Institutions. G-24 Discussion Paper Series, 6.Suche in Google Scholar

Killick, T. (1995) IMF Programmes in Developing Countries. Design and Impact. Routledge.Suche in Google Scholar

Killick. T. (2004) “Politics, Evidence and the New Aid Agenda,” Development Policy Review, 22(1):5–29.10.1111/j.1467-8659.2004.00235.xSuche in Google Scholar

Killick, T., R. Gunatilaka and A. Marr (1998) Aid and the Political Economy of Policy Change. London and New York: Routledge.10.4324/9780203446539Suche in Google Scholar

Knack, S. (2001) “Aid Dependence and The Quality of Governance: Cross-Country Empirical Tests,” Southern Economic Journal, 68(2):310–329.Suche in Google Scholar

Knack, S. (2004) “Does Foreign Aid Promote Democracy?” International Studies Quarterly, 48(1):251–266.10.1111/j.0020-8833.2004.00299.xSuche in Google Scholar

Knack, S. and A. Rahman (2007) “Donor Fragmentation and Bureaucratic Quality in Aid Recipients,” Journal of Development Economics, 83(1):176–197.10.1016/j.jdeveco.2006.02.002Suche in Google Scholar

Leeds, B. A. (1999) “Domestic Political Institutions, Credible Commitments, and International Cooperation,” American Journal of Political Science, 43(4):979–1002.10.2307/2991814Suche in Google Scholar

Leeds, B. A., and D. R. Davis (1999) “Beneath The Surface: Regime Type and International Interaction, 1953-78,” Journal of Peace Research, 36(1):5–21.10.1177/0022343399036001001Suche in Google Scholar

Lindbeck, A. and J. Weibull (1988) “Altruism and Time Consistency: The Economics of Fait Accompli,” Journal of Political Economy, 96(6):1165–1182.10.1086/261582Suche in Google Scholar

Mayer, W. and A. Mourmouras (2002) Vested Interests in A Positive Theory of IFI Conditionality. IMF working paper 02/73.10.2139/ssrn.879581Suche in Google Scholar

Mayer, W. and P. Raimondos-Møller (2003) “The Politics of Foreign Aid: A Median Voter Explanation,” Review of Development Economics, 7:165–178.10.1111/1467-9361.00183Suche in Google Scholar

McGillivray, F. and A. Smith (2000) “Trust and Cooperation Through Agent-Specific Punishments,” International Organization, 54(4):809–824.10.1162/002081800551370Suche in Google Scholar

Moore, J. and R. Repullo (1988) “Subgame Perfect Implementation,” Econometrica, 56:1191–1220.10.2307/1911364Suche in Google Scholar

Mosley, P. (1996) “The Failure of Aid and Adjustment Policies in Sub-Saharan Africa: Counter-Examples and Policy Proposals,” Journal of African Economies, 5:406–443.10.1093/oxfordjournals.jae.a020913Suche in Google Scholar

Mosley, P., J. Harrigan and J. Toye (1995) Aid and Power: The World Bank and Policy-Based Lending. (P. Mosley, J. Harrigan and J. Toye, eds.) Volume 1: analysis and policy proposals (No. Ed 2). London and New York: Routledge.Suche in Google Scholar

Murphy, R. G. and N. G. Tresp (2006) Government Policy and The Effectiveness of Foreign Aid. Boston College Working Papers in Economics 647.Suche in Google Scholar

Murrell, P. (2002) “The Interaction of Donors, Contractors, and Recipients in Implementing Aid for Institutional Reform,” The Institutional Economics of Foreign Aid, 69–111.Suche in Google Scholar

Oyejide, A., B. Ndulu and J. W. Gunning (1997) Regional Integration and Trade Liberalisation: Evidence from Country Case Studies, Introduction and Overview. Regional Integration and Trade Liberalisation in Sub-Saharan Africa. Vol. 2: Country Case Studies.Suche in Google Scholar

Pedersen, K. R. (1996) “Aid, Investment and Incentives,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 98(3):423–438.10.2307/3440735Suche in Google Scholar

Pedersen, K. R. (2001) “The Samaritan’s Dilemma and The Effectiveness of Foreign aid,” International Tax and Public Finance, 8:693–703.10.1023/A:1012839126094Suche in Google Scholar

Ramcharan, R. (2003) Reputation, Debt and Policy Conditionality. IMF Working Paper 03/192.10.5089/9781451859782.001Suche in Google Scholar

Rodrik, D. (1995) Why is there multilateral lending? Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics. World Bank, Washington DC, pp. 167–193.Suche in Google Scholar

Rogoff, K. (1985) “The Optimal Degree of Commitment to An Intermediate Monetary Target,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100:1169–1190.10.2307/1885679Suche in Google Scholar

Selbervik, H. (1999) Aid and Conditionality: The Role of The Bilateral Donor: A Case Study of Norwegian–Tanzanian Aid Relationship. Report submitted to the Norwegian Ministry of Foreign Affairs by Chr. Michelsen Institute (link at: http://www.oecd.org/countries/tanzania/35178610.pdf).Suche in Google Scholar

Simmons, B. A. (2000) “International Law and State Behavior: Commitment and Compliance in International Monetary Affairs,” The American Political Science Review, 94(4):819–835.10.2307/2586210Suche in Google Scholar

Siverson, R. M. and J. Emmons (1991) “Birds of a Feather Democratic Political Systems and Alliance Choices in the Twentieth Century,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 35(2):285–306.10.1177/0022002791035002007Suche in Google Scholar

Svensson, J. (2000a) “When is Foreign Aid Policy Credible? Aid Dependence and Conditionality,” Journal of Development Economics, 61:61–84.10.1016/S0304-3878(99)00061-9Suche in Google Scholar

Svensson, J. (2000b) “Foreign Aid and Rent-Seeking,” Journal of International Economics 51(2):437–461.10.1016/S0022-1996(99)00014-8Suche in Google Scholar

Svensson, J. (2003) “Why Conditional Aid Doesn’t Work and What Can Be Done About It,” Journal of Development Economics, 70:381–402.10.1016/S0304-3878(02)00102-5Suche in Google Scholar

Varian, H. (1994) “A Solution to The Problem of Externalities When Agents are Well-Informed,” American Economic Review, 85:1278–1293.Suche in Google Scholar

Villanger, E. (2006) “Company Interests and Foreign Aid Policy: Playing Donors Off Against One Another,” European Economic Review, 50(3):533–545.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2005.01.005Suche in Google Scholar

Walsh, C. (1995) “Optimal Contracts for Central Bankers,” American Economic Review, 85, 150–167.Suche in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2014-9-6
Published in Print: 2014-6-1

©2014 by De Gruyter

Heruntergeladen am 28.9.2025 von https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/jgd-2012-0018/html
Button zum nach oben scrollen