Abstract
This paper investigates the identification and estimation of the quantile treatment effect in a difference in differences (DID) setting when treatment is provided only to qualified individuals at a certain point in time and the qualification is time-varying. The time-varying qualification may affect an outcome variable even when the actual effect of treatment is zero. We show how to account for this “movers effect” bias and propose the quantile treatment effect on “in-stayers” that are qualified both before and after the treatment. The estimate is identified under three main assumptions: (i) panel data availability, (ii) a distributional common trend assumption conditional on covariates, and (iii) a copula stability assumption. We then apply our method to estimate the effects of an increase in the benefits of the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program (SNAP) on recipients’ food expenditure shares. The results show significant heterogeneity and highlight the importance of accounting for time-varying qualification.
1 Introduction
The difference-in-differences (DID) approach is one of the most widely used methods in applied economics to evaluate the effects of policy interventions. Many DID applications can be found in Athey and Imbens (2006), Blundell and Dias (2009), and Lechner (2011). In a DID approach, treatment is given to individuals that satisfy some qualification criteria at a certain point in time. To estimate the average treatment effect on the treated (ATT), the DID method subtracts a before-and-after difference in an outcome variable for the group of unqualified individuals from the same difference for the group of qualified individuals. This identification strategy, however, holds only when the qualification is time-invariant. If the qualification status is time-varying, meaning, for instance, that an unqualified individual beforehand becomes qualified when treatment is provided, the DID method may lead to a bias in the estimation of the ATT.
Lee and Kim (2014) are the first to identify this issue and show that in the presence of time-varying qualification, the composition of the treatment and control groups is modified as follows. There are four groups of individuals depending on the qualification status before and after the treatment: (1) in-stayers who satisfy the qualification criteria over the whole period, (2) out-movers who do not satisfy the qualification criteria only at the time of treatment, (3) in-movers who satisfy the qualification criteria only at the time treatment occurs, and (4) out-stayers who never satisfy the qualification criteria. The existence of time-varying qualification, out-movers and in-movers, can introduce a “movers effect” bias on the ATT because they face different incentives to self-select themselves into the qualified group and have unique characteristics. Lee and Kim (2014) account for this moving effect and propose a method to identify the average treatment effect on in-stayers using a linear model while assuming the same time-effects and same group-effects. This study expands on the work of Lee and Kim (2014) to examine the case of distributional effects of treatment when the qualification is time-varying. In particular, we propose the identification and estimation of the quantile treatment effect on the treated (in-movers and in-stayers) in a DID framework when qualification to treatment changes over time.
The quantile DID setting with the time-varying qualification can potentially fit in many empirical situations. For example, a sick pay reform (treatment) in Germany, analyzed by Puhani and Sonderhof (2010), was applied, after the reform was implemented in 1997 and 1998, only to qualified workers, i.e. those not covered by collective bargaining contracts. However, some workers could change their employers and thus their qualification statuses at the same time as the policy change. If so, outcomes of workers who move from jobs covered by collective bargaining contracts to those that are not, could have changed even if the treatment were not applied because the working environment in their new jobs are typically less generous in terms of sick leave policies.[1] In short, the policy effect estimated using their qualification status after the policy reform at treatment is contaminated by such a compositional change.
Another example is a minimum wage reform, analyzed by Cengiz et al. (2019) on the effect of a minimum wage reform in the United States on earnings among workers in low-paying sectors. Using a distributional DID approach, Cengiz et al. (2019) showed a significant increase in average earnings at the bottom of the wage distribution. However, workers who lost a high-paying job would typically accept only a job paying above the average wage rate as a next job. Therefore, these in-movers must be accounted for to avoid biased treatment effect estimates. Our distributional framework accounts for this “movers effect” and provides quantile treatment effect on treated (in-stayers and in-movers).
In Section 4, we use our method to analyze the distributional impact of an increase in the benefits of the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program (SNAP, formerly known as the food stamp program) implemented by the U.S. federal government on households food expenditures, where qualification criteria may change over time. The treatment (i.e. an increase in SNAP benefits) is provided in October 2008 and April 2009 only to individuals that participate in the program. Because (i) there are individuals that change their participation status before-and-after the treatment and (ii) the distributional analysis is important from the policy perspective, our framework is suitable for the analysis.
Contributions
Our main contribution is methodological and derives identification and estimation results for the QTT in a DID framework when qualification varies over time. To achieve this, we combine an identification strategy introduced by Callaway and Li (2019) with the approach accounting for time-varying qualification to a program by Lee and Kim (2014). Key assumptions for the identification are (i) a distributional version of the common trend assumption conditional on covariates, (ii) panel data with at least three periods, and (iii) the constant dependence over time between the distribution of a change in untreated potential outcomes and the level of untreated potential outcomes for the group of interest. Our work is also related to that of Fan and Yu (2012), who provide partial identification results for the QTT in a DID setting, using the conditional Common Trend Assumption and Frechet–Hoeffding bounds for the copula.
Another contribution is empirical and provides results on the distributional impact of an increase in SNAP benefits on households’ food expenditure share, considering their heterogeneity and potential changes in their qualification status. Valizadeh and Smith (2020) also explore this distributional impact using a non-additive fixed-effect quantile estimator from Powell (2020) and obtain similar empirical results as ours.
Outline
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes a DID framework in the presence of time-varying qualifications and shows the potential for bias. Section 3 provides identification results for the parameters of interest. Section 4 uses our distributional framework to study the effects of policy changes on SNAP. Finally, Section 5 concludes.
2 Difference in Differences with Time-Varying Qualification
This section uses a quantile DID framework to show the potential for bias from the “movers effect”.
2.1 Setup
Consider a DID panel model with three time periods given by t = 1, 2, 3 in which treatment is applied in t = 3 to a group of qualified individuals. In the standard framework, the qualification indicator Q is assumed to be time-constant. However, in practice, Q is often a time-varying variable such as income, wealth, age, number of children, or residential location. Therefore, the time-varying qualification status is denoted with time subscript t, Q t . In the presence of time-varying qualification, individuals are divided into four groups: in-stayers (Q 2 = 1, Q 3 = 1), in-movers (Q 2 = 0, Q 3 = 1), out-movers (Q 2 = 1, Q 3 = 0), and out-stayers (Q 2 = 0, Q 3 = 0).
Q 3 = 0: not qualified at t = 3 | Q 3 = 1: qualified at t = 3 |
---|---|
Q 2 = 0, Q 3 = 0: out-stayers | Q 2 = 0, Q 3 = 1: in-movers |
Q 2 = 1, Q 3 = 0: out-movers | Q 2 = 1, Q 3 = 1: in-stayers |
Let Y it be the outcome of interest for individual i at time t and let X it be covariates including time-constant ones C i and time-varying ones W it . The treatment indicator is given by D it = Q it × 1[t = 3]. X it is realized first, then D it at the start of period t, and Y it at the end of period t. Both X it and D it can directly affect Y it :

For each period t and individual i, the potential outcomes for the treated and untreated are given by
This implies that
The time-varying qualification can introduce a bias in estimating the treatment effect on the treated in a conventional DID setting. The estimate is identified under the common trends assumption, stating that the difference in untreated potential outcomes is independent of the treatment status:
To see how the presence of movers can introduce bias in the quantile DID estimator, we consider the following panel linear model without covariates as in Lee and Kim (2014) and Lee and Sawada (2020):
where V it is a time-varying error term. Under the assumption that the error term V is independent of the treatment variable D. Under this model, and the assumption that β q ≠ 0, the presence of movers (in-movers and out-movers) implies:
Therefore, the assumption
3 Identification and Inference
This section presents the parameters of interest and their identification. Our framework is based on Callaway and Li (2019), but allows for the presence of time-varying qualification. The estimation and inference the parameters of interest are provided in Appendix A.
3.1 Parameters of Interest
For two random variables U and V, let F U (u) denote the distribution function of U, Supp(U) the support of U, and F U|V (u) the conditional distribution of U given V. The τ-quantile of U with τ ∈ (0, 1) is defined as:
In the presence of time-varying qualification, in-stayers and in-movers are the only treatment recipients. Therefore, our parameters of interest are the quantile treatment effect for the in-stayers (QTIS) and the quantile treatment effect for the in-movers (QTIM) given by:
3.2 Identification
This subsection provides identification results for the QTIS. Results for the QTIM are similar and thus relegated to the Online Appendix C.
Before stating the identification assumptions, let us introduce additional notations. For any random variable U, let
Assumption 1
(Distributional Difference in Differences)
For all x ∈ Supp(X), for all δ,
Assumption 2
(Copula Stability Assumption)
Assumption 3
(Continuity)
Assumption 4
(Overlap)
p 11 > 0 and p 00(x) > 0 for all x ∈ Supp(X).
Assumption 1 is an extension of the conditional common trend assumption. It postulates that conditional on covariates X (in this subsection, covariates are assumed to be time-invariant), the distribution of the change in untreated potential outcomes for the in-stayers (treatment group) is identical to that for the control group. Assumption 2 introduces a stability restriction on the copula function of their marginal distributions
Motivation for using Assumption 1 under time-varying qualification is the following. It allows a case where unobservable covariates can be distributed differently over time within each group, in-stayers, in-movers, out-movers, and out-stayers, while a leading quantile method by Athey and Imbens (2006) assumes that the distribution of unobservable covariates is different across groups but does not change over time. Because, in our setting on time-varying qualification, in-movers and out-stayers are those that have changed their qualification status over time for some observable and/or unobservable reasons, their distributions on unobservable covariates are likely to change over time. In addition, our Assumption 1 is conditional on covariates rather than unconditional. This allows, for example, the impact of increasing food subsidies on expenditure share depending on a household’s characteristics, which will be discussed more in Section 4.
Motivation for using Assumption 2 is the same as Callaway and Li (2019): recovering the dependence between untreated potential outcome for treated units in initial period and the change in untreated potential outcome for treated units by using that in the previous period for obtaining point identification. However, utilizing Assumption 2 for in-stayers seems to be reasonable in our setting. If we rather assumed the CSA for all groups altogether, then including units that have changed their qualification status over time (i.e. in-movers and out-moves) would be likely to violate the assumption.
Assumption 3 ensures the continuous distribution of potential outcome variables and their differences. The first part of Assumption 4 states that there is a positive probability that a household is in-stayer. The second part postulates that there is a positive probability for a household with covariates x for any value of x, to be part of the out-stayers group.
Given these assumptions, we now state the main identification results of the paper. The proof can be found in the Online Appendix B1.
Theorem 1
Under Assumptions 1–4,
where
and
Theorem 1 identifies the counterfactual distribution of untreated outcomes for in-stayers. The intuition behind this result is simple. Assumption 1 allows us to identify the distribution of
The following example provides a situation where Assumptions 1 and 2 hold. Its proof is relegated to the Online Appendix B1.
Example 1
Consider the following model for untreated potential outcomes
Such that (i) (U
3, U
2|X, Q
2 = 0, Q
3 = 0) and (U
3, U
2|X, Q
2 = 1, Q
3 = 1) have the same distribution, and (ii) (U
3, U
2, X, η|Q
2 = 1, Q
3 = 1) and
The model imposes assumptions only on how untreated potential outcomes are generated as in Example 2 of Callaway and Li (2019), thus allowing individuals to select into treatment due to anticipated treated potential outcomes in an unrestricted way. The untreated potential outcomes also depend on the qualification status as in the model (M 0) in Lee and Kim (2014). In this model, we show that Assumptions 1 and 2 hold.
It is possible in some cases that the Copula Stability Assumption (CSA) holds only conditional on covariates. This conditional assumption states that the copula between the difference in untreated potential outcomes and the initial level of untreated potential outcomes for the treatment group (in-stayers) remains the same over time after conditioning on covariates. We show in the next proposition that even under the conditional CSA, the quantile treatment effect for in-stayers is still identified.
Assumption 2.1
(Conditional Copula Stability Assumption)
Proposition 1
Assume that for all x ∈ Supp(X), the random variables
and
and the unconditional treatment effect is given by
Using the conditional CSA is advantageous because it allows the path of untreated potential outcomes to change with covariates. An example is when the return to some covariates, such as the return to family size, changes over time. However, with this assumption, nonparametric estimation of the parameters of interest would require estimating several conditional distribution functions, which can be computationally challenging. Therefore, our application in the next section uses Assumption 2 rather than Assumption 2.1. As explained in Section D5 of the Online Appendix D, the CSA is likely to hold without conditioning on covariates in our application.
4 Application: Distributional Effects of an Increase in SNAP Benefits
SNAP is the largest federal government nutrition-assistance program for low-income households in the U.S. Because of its large scale (c.f. 34.5 million participants and $58.5 billion in federal expenditure in 2019), many papers have studied the effect of providing SNAP benefits on food expenditure by using a linear DID framework and a timing of policy changes (Bruich 2014; Beatty and Tuttle 2015; Kim 2016; Nord and Prell 2011; Valizadeh and Smith 2020). However, the effect may vary across the distribution of food spending, and thus it is important to undertake a study using a distributional framework (Southworth 1945; USDA-FNS 2016).[3]
It is also important to pay attention to changes in qualification over time. A normal household is eligible for receiving SNAP benefits if it clears means-tests.[4] Because the economic and demographic criteria for being eligible in SNAP change over time, the qualified population also changes over time. Actually, there were a non-negligible number of SNAP participants changing their enrollment status in our data. Table 1 shows the number of households with different participation statuses. Approximately 5% of SNAP participants are either in-movers or out-movers. This time-varying qualification gives us a potential bias in the estimates of the effect of extra SNAP benefits, if it is analyzed by a simple before-and-after comparison of the averages.
Change in the qualification in our sample.
Household status | # household | % |
---|---|---|
In-movers | 62 | 2.51 |
In-stayers | 170 | 6.89 |
Infra-marginal | 106 | 4.26 |
Extra-marginal | 64 | 2.63 |
Out-movers | 59 | 2.39 |
Out-stayers | 2178 | 88.21 |
-
The table shows the frequency of a change in qualification status in our sample. There are four groups im terms of the qualification changes: in-movers, in-stayer, out-movers, and out-stayers. In-stayers is further divided into infra-marginal and extra-marginal based on the relationship between food expenditure at home and SNAP allotments.
Under the motivations, we apply the QTT estimation framework constructed above to study the effect of an increase in SNAP benefits in October 2008 and April 2009 on the share of food expenditure consumed at home. The qualification to SNAP is time-varying depending on eligibility criteria and households’ characteristics and therefore defined by a time-varying dummy variable Q it for household i in time t. Treatment is an increase in SNAP benefits provided only to individuals that participate in the program and is thus defined by D it = 1{after policy change t }× Q it , where 1{after policy change t } is equal to one if a period is after a policy change.
We use the Consumer Expenditure Quarterly Interview Survey (CEX) administrated by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, where each household is interviewed once a quarter for five consecutive quarters. Our main outcome variable Y it is the share of food expenditure share consumed at home because it is a category of consumption that SNAP benefit can be used for.
Our counterfactual distribution, as shown in Equation (3), uses the propensity score re-weighting method. The propensity score is estimated parametrically using logit and covariates X include total expenditure, family size, family age, a working status dummy, household composition, urban dummy, education level, marital status, race, gender, year, and month. Total expenditure is included in X, because it allows us to investigate how food expenditure share changes due to an increase in SNAP benefits while controlling for the effect of additional benefits on a change in total expenditure, following Beatty and Tuttle (2015). Because covariate X needs to be time-invariant, we use the value in the initial period (two periods before the treatment), t = 1, except for total expenditure being the value in period t = 3. As a robustness check, we also estimate the propensity score using not only these covariates but also their interaction and squared terms. The 95% confidence intervals are computed using the bootstrap with 300 iterations.
4.1 Results
Figures 1 and 2 and Table 2 show our main results of this application. Figure 1 shows the QTIS using the food-at-home expenditure share as an outcome variable, and Figure 2 shows the QTIS using the food-at-home expenditure level. The average treatment effect on the treated (the horizontal dotted lines in the figures) is positive and statistically significant. For example, Figure 1 shows that the share of food expenditure at home increases by 2.27 percentage points on average after the increase in SNAP benefits. More importantly, it shows heterogeneous treatment effects over the distribution of household’s expenditure share of food at home, while their difference is statistically insignificant due to large standard errors. A SNAP household at the 20th percentile of the distribution has a coefficient of 0.71, with a standard error of 1.02. In contrast, at the other end of the distribution, a SNAP household at the 70th percentile has a coefficient of 4.89, with a standard error of 1.76, thus being statistically significant.
![Figure 1:
QTT on the share of food expenditure at home: ATT 2.27 [s.e. 0.98].
The figure provides estimates of the QTIS with covariates on the effect of an increase in SNAP benefits on food expenditure share at home. The solid line denotes the estimate for each quantile measured on the horizontal axis. The black dotted line is a 95% confidence interval calculated by the bootstrap with 300 iterations. The red dashed horizontal line is the average treatment effect.](/document/doi/10.1515/jem-2021-0032/asset/graphic/j_jem-2021-0032_fig_001.jpg)
QTT on the share of food expenditure at home: ATT 2.27 [s.e. 0.98].
The figure provides estimates of the QTIS with covariates on the effect of an increase in SNAP benefits on food expenditure share at home. The solid line denotes the estimate for each quantile measured on the horizontal axis. The black dotted line is a 95% confidence interval calculated by the bootstrap with 300 iterations. The red dashed horizontal line is the average treatment effect.
![Figure 2:
QTT on food expenditure at home: ATT 83.32 [25.86].
The figure provides estimates of the QTIS with covariates on the effect of an increase in SNAP benefits on food expenditure level at home. The solid line denotes the estimate for each quantile measured on the horizontal axis. The black dotted line is a 95% confidence interval calculated by the bootstrap with 300 iterations. The red dashed horizontal line is the average treatment effect.](/document/doi/10.1515/jem-2021-0032/asset/graphic/j_jem-2021-0032_fig_002.jpg)
QTT on food expenditure at home: ATT 83.32 [25.86].
The figure provides estimates of the QTIS with covariates on the effect of an increase in SNAP benefits on food expenditure level at home. The solid line denotes the estimate for each quantile measured on the horizontal axis. The black dotted line is a 95% confidence interval calculated by the bootstrap with 300 iterations. The red dashed horizontal line is the average treatment effect.
Quantile treatment effects.
Expenditure: | With covariantes | Without covariates | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Quantile | Share food at home | Level food at home | Share food at home | Level food at home | ||||
Estimate | s.e. | Estimate | s.e | Estimate | s.e. | Estimate | s.e | |
10 | 0.53 | (1.71) | 16.80 | (38.97) | 0.28 | (1.46) | 3.10 | (34.81) |
20 | 0.71 | (1.22) | 60.28 | (27.99) | 0.47 | (0.98) | 57.46 | (25.53) |
30 | 0.84 | (1.14) | 73.12 | (28.00) | 0.96 | (1.03) | 53.79 | (28.51) |
40 | 1.71 | (1.42) | 76.85 | (29.60) | 1.93 | (1.41) | 44.48 | (30.55) |
50 | 3.85 | (1.37) | 79.23 | (32.63) | 3.14 | (1.26) | 58.04 | (29.68) |
60 | 4.08 | (1.49) | 105.83 | (42.26) | 4.09 | (1.43) | 86.67 | (39.56) |
70 | 4.89 | (1.57) | 93.53 | (54.60) | 4.82 | (1.66) | 36.91 | (58.09) |
80 | 6.07 | (2.50) | 173.35 | (62.28) | 6.52 | (2.62) | 65.47 | (72.59) |
90 | 0.29 | (4.11) | 76.01 | (102.22) | 1.46 | (3.67) | 12.68 | (109.14) |
ATT | 2.27 | (0.98) | 83.32 | (25.86) | 2.32 | (0.97) | 55.46 | (24.17) |
-
The table shows the QTIS and their standard errors from the 10th to 90th percentiles. The first two columns show the results when using the share of food expenditure consumed at home as the outcome variable and controlling for covariates. Columns 3 and 4 show the results when using food expenditure at home as the outcome and controlling for covariates. Columns 5 and 6 show those when using the share of food expenditure at home as the outcome variable without covariates. The final two columns show those when using food expenditure at home as the outcome variable without covariates. The standard errors in parentheses are calculated by the bootstrap with 300 iterations.
The magnitude of the estimates is also not negligible. As shown in Table D2 of the Online Appendix D, the average share of food expenditure at home is 21.59% among the SNAP households (combining infra-marginal and extra-marginal households). Using the average share, the estimated effect suggests that a SNAP household at the 70th percentile of the distribution increases its food expenditure share at home by 22.65%, while those at the 20th percentile increases its food expenditure share only by 3.29%.
Similar heterogeneous results are observed when we use the unconditional version of Assumption 1, as reported in Figures 3 and 4 and the final four columns of Table 2. For example, while a SNAP participant at the 20th percentile increases their food expenditure share at home by 0.47 percentage points (statistically insignificant), those at the 70th percentile raise their shares by 4.82 percentage points (statistically significant). The observed pattern that an increment in the food expenditure share is increasing in a percentile of the distribution is not solely due to our identification assumptions. It is also confirmed using another distributional DID method by Athey and Imbens (2006), which is reported in the Online Appendix E.
![Figure 3:
QTT on the share of food expenditure at home (no covariates): ATT 2.32 [s.e. 0.97].
The figure provides estimates of the QTIS without covariates on the effect of an increase in SNAP benefits on food expenditure share at home. The solid line denotes the estimate for each quantile measured on the horizontal axis. The black dotted line is a 95% confidence interval calculated by the bootstrap with 300 iterations. The red dashed horizontal line is the average treatment effect.](/document/doi/10.1515/jem-2021-0032/asset/graphic/j_jem-2021-0032_fig_003.jpg)
QTT on the share of food expenditure at home (no covariates): ATT 2.32 [s.e. 0.97].
The figure provides estimates of the QTIS without covariates on the effect of an increase in SNAP benefits on food expenditure share at home. The solid line denotes the estimate for each quantile measured on the horizontal axis. The black dotted line is a 95% confidence interval calculated by the bootstrap with 300 iterations. The red dashed horizontal line is the average treatment effect.
![Figure 4:
QTT on food expenditure at home (no covariates): ATT 55.46 [24.17].
The figure provides estimates of the QTIS without covariates on the effect of an increase in SNAP benefits on food expenditure level at home. The solid line denotes the estimate for each quantile measured on the horizontal axis. The black dotted line is a 95% confidence interval calculated by the bootstrap with 300 iterations. The red dashed horizontal line is the average treatment effect.](/document/doi/10.1515/jem-2021-0032/asset/graphic/j_jem-2021-0032_fig_004.jpg)
QTT on food expenditure at home (no covariates): ATT 55.46 [24.17].
The figure provides estimates of the QTIS without covariates on the effect of an increase in SNAP benefits on food expenditure level at home. The solid line denotes the estimate for each quantile measured on the horizontal axis. The black dotted line is a 95% confidence interval calculated by the bootstrap with 300 iterations. The red dashed horizontal line is the average treatment effect.
The ATT and QTT become smaller when ignoring the changes in qualification status than they would be when considering these changes. For example, the result with all types of households (in-stayers, in-movers, out-stayers, and out-movers) shows that a SNAP participant at the 70th percentile of the distribution has a coefficient of 4.54, and the average treatment effect is 2.02 (not reported). This is probably because new participants, in-movers, should be relatively wealthier and have lower food expenditure shares, thus resulting in a smaller treatment effect.
Finally, we provide supportive evidence for our identification assumptions: (1) the Distributional Difference in Differences (DDID) Assumption, (2) the CSA, (3) the Continuity Assumption, and (4) the Overlap Assumption.[5] The Online Appendix D5 provides supportive evidence for each of them, suggesting that they are likely to hold.
5 Conclusion
This paper proposes a new methodology to study the distributional effects of a policy change in a DID framework when qualification to treatment varies over time. In such case, the treatment group consist of in-stayers and in-movers and not accounting for movers effect can introduce bias in standard quantile DID estimators. We provide identification and estimation results on the conditional and unconditional quantile treatment effects in a difference in differences setting with time-varying qualification. To achieve this, three identification assumptions are introduced: (i) panel data availability, (ii) a distributional common trend assumption conditional on covariates, and (iii) a copula stability assumption. Our methodology takes the “movers effect” bias into account and allows us to assess the validity of our identification assumptions using a placebo test and the Kendall’s Tau test.
We use the proposed method to revisit the distributional effect of an increase in SNAP benefits on food expenditure share. We find that while participants at the 20th percentile of the distribution of the food expenditure share experienced an insignificant 0.71 percentage-point increase in food expenditure share, those at the 70th percentile had their food expenditure share increased by 4.89 percentage points with a statistical significance.
Acknowledgement
We are grateful to Keisuke Hirano, Ted Jaenicke, Kala Krishna, Daolu Cai and seminar participants in HiAS lunch seminar at Hitotsubashi University and Econometric Society African Meeting 2019 for helpful comments.
References
Athey, S., and G. W. Imbens. 2006. “Identication and Inference in Nonlinear Dierence-in-Dierences Models.” Econometrica 74 (2): 431–97 .10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00668.xSearch in Google Scholar
Beatty, T. K., and C. J. Tuttle. 2015. “Expenditure Response to Increases in In-Kind Transfers: Evidence from the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 97 (2): 390–404. https://doi.org/10.1093/ajae/aau097.Search in Google Scholar
Blundell, R., and M. C. Dias. 2009. “Alternative Approaches to Evaluation in Empirical Microeconomics.” Journal of Human Resources 44 (3): 565–640. https://doi.org/10.1353/jhr.2009.0009.Search in Google Scholar
Bruich, G. A. 2014. The Effect of SNAP Benefits on Expenditures: New Evidence from Scanner Data and the November 2013 Benefit Cuts. Harvard University.Search in Google Scholar
Callaway, B., and T. Li. 2019. “Quantile Treatment Effects in Difference in Differences Models with Panel Data.” Quantitative Economics 10 (4): 1579–618. https://doi.org/10.3982/qe935.Search in Google Scholar
Cengiz, D., A. Dube, A. Lindner, and B. Zipperer. 2019. “The Effect of Minimum Wages on Low-Wage Jobs.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 134 (3): 1405–54. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjz014.Search in Google Scholar
Fan, Y., and Z. Yu. 2012. “Partial Identification of Distributional and Quantile Treatment Effects in Difference-in-Differences Models.” Economics Letters 115 (3): 511–5. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2012.01.001.Search in Google Scholar
Kim, J. 2016. “Do SNAP Participants Expand Non-food Spending when they Receive More SNAP Benefits?—Evidence from the 2009 SNAP Benefits Increase.” Food Policy 65: 9–20. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2016.10.002.Search in Google Scholar
Lechner, M. 2011. “The Estimation of Causal Effects by Difference-in-Difference Methods.” Foundations and Trends in Econometrics 4 (3): 165–224. https://doi.org/10.1561/0800000014.Search in Google Scholar
Lee, M. J., and Y. S. Kim. 2014. “Difference in Differences for Stayers with a Time-Varying Qualification: Health Expenditure Elasticity of the Elderly.” Health Economics 23 (9): 1134–45. https://doi.org/10.1002/hec.3049.Search in Google Scholar PubMed
Lee, M. J., and Y. Sawada. 2020. “Review on Difference in Differences.” Korean Economic Review 36: 135–73.Search in Google Scholar
Nord, M., and M. A. Prell. 2011. Food Security Improved Following the 2009 ARRA Increase in SNAP Benefits. Washington, DC: US Department of Agriculture.Search in Google Scholar
Powell, D. 2020. “Quantile Regression with Nonadditive Fixed Effects.” In RAND Working Paper.10.1007/s00181-022-02216-6Search in Google Scholar
Puhani, P. A., and K. Sonderhof. 2010. “The Effects of a Sick Pay Reform on Absence and on Health-Related Outcomes.” Journal of Health Economics 29 (2): 285–302. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2010.01.003.Search in Google Scholar PubMed
Southworth, H. M. 1945. “The Economics of Public Measures to Subsidize Food Consumption.” Journal of Farm Economics 27 (1): 38–66. https://doi.org/10.2307/1232262.Search in Google Scholar
USDA-FNS 2016. Characteristics of Supplemental Nutrition Assistant Program Households: Fiscal Year 2015. Also available at https://fns-prod.azureedge.net/sites/default/files/ops/Characteristics2015.pdf (accessed September 6, 2018).Search in Google Scholar
Valizadeh, P., and T. A. Smith. 2020. “How Did the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act Affect the Material Well-Being of SNAP Participants? A Distributional Approach.” Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy 42 (3): 455–76. https://doi.org/10.1093/aepp/ppy039.Search in Google Scholar
Supplementary Material
The online version of this article offers supplementary material (https://doi.org/10.1515/jem-2021-0032).
© 2022 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Research Articles
- Empirical Framework for Two-Player Repeated Games with Random States
- The Robustness of Conditional Logit for Binary Response Panel Data Models with Serial Correlation
- Density Forecast of Financial Returns Using Decomposition and Maximum Entropy
- On the Implementation of Approximate Randomization Tests in Linear Models with a Small Number of Clusters
- Quantile Difference in Differences with Time-Varying Qualification in Panel Data
- A Random Forest-based Approach to Combining and Ranking Seasonality Tests
- Teaching Corner
- On the Use of the Helmert Transformation, and its Applications in Panel Data Econometrics
- Practitioner's Corner
- Linear Rescaling to Accurately Interpret Logarithms
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Research Articles
- Empirical Framework for Two-Player Repeated Games with Random States
- The Robustness of Conditional Logit for Binary Response Panel Data Models with Serial Correlation
- Density Forecast of Financial Returns Using Decomposition and Maximum Entropy
- On the Implementation of Approximate Randomization Tests in Linear Models with a Small Number of Clusters
- Quantile Difference in Differences with Time-Varying Qualification in Panel Data
- A Random Forest-based Approach to Combining and Ranking Seasonality Tests
- Teaching Corner
- On the Use of the Helmert Transformation, and its Applications in Panel Data Econometrics
- Practitioner's Corner
- Linear Rescaling to Accurately Interpret Logarithms