Startseite Tests for Price Endogeneity in Differentiated Product Models
Artikel
Lizenziert
Nicht lizenziert Erfordert eine Authentifizierung

Tests for Price Endogeneity in Differentiated Product Models

  • Kyoo il Kim EMAIL logo und Amil Petrin
Veröffentlicht/Copyright: 12. März 2014
Veröffentlichen auch Sie bei De Gruyter Brill

Abstract

We develop simple tests for endogenous prices arising from omitted demand factors in discrete choice models. Our approach only requires one to locate testing proxies that have some correlation with the omitted factors when prices are endogenous. We use the difference between prices and their predicted values given observed demand and supply factors. If prices are exogenous, these proxies should not explain demand given prices and other explanatory variables. We reject exogeneity if these proxies enter significantly in utility as additional explanatory variables. The tests are easy to implement as we show with several Monte Carlos and discuss for three recent demand applications.

JEL Classification: C3; L0

Corresponding author: Kyoo il Kim, Department of Economics, University of Minnesota, 4-101 Hanson Hall, 1925 4th Street South, Minneapolis, MN 55455, USA, Tel.: +612-625-6793, Fax: +612-624-0209, E-mail: ; and School of Economics, Sungkyunkwan University, Seoul, Republic of Korea

Appendix A Asymptotic Distributions of Test Statistics

A.1 Proof of Lemma 5.1

Proof. The unconstrained ML estimator solves the first order condition logLN(ξ^m,θ˜^U)θ˜=0. Define Γ^(θ˜,π)=logLN(ξ˜m(π),θ˜)θ˜θ˜,Γ0(θ˜,π)=limME[logLN(ξ˜m(π),θ˜)θ˜θ˜],Γ^(θ˜)=Γ^(θ˜,π^), and Γ0=Γ0(θ˜0,π0). The asymptotic distribution of M(θ˜^Uθ˜0) is obtained from the asymptotic expansion of

(13)M(θ˜^Uθ˜0)=Γ^1(θ˜){MlogLN(ξ˜m,θ˜0)θ˜+M×(logLN(ξ^m,θ˜0)θ˜logLN(ξ˜m,θ˜0)θ˜)}+op(1), (13)

which is obtained from the element-by-element mean value expansions of the first order condition logLN(ξ^m,θ˜^U)θ˜=0 around θ˜0 where θ˜ lies between θ˜^U and θ˜0. Therefore the asymptotic variance of M(θ˜^Uθ˜0) contains two variance terms that are from (i) the ML estimation and (ii) the estimation of the controls.

Note that under Assumptions 5.1, 5.2 (i)(a), (v), and (vi), by the uniform law of large numbers and the continuity, we obtain

(14)Γ^(θ˜)pΓ0 (14)

because

(15)Γ^(θ˜)Γ0Γ^(θ˜)Γ0(θ˜,π^)+Γ0(θ˜,π^)Γ0supθ˜Θ˜0,πΠ0Γ^(θ˜,π)Γ0(θ˜,π)+Γ0(θ˜,π^)Γ0=op(1) (15)

where the first term in (15) converges to zero by the uniform LLN under Assumption 5.2 (vi) and the second term in (15) converges to zero because of the continuity of Γ0 [which is implied by Assumption 5.2 (v) and (vi) due to the dominated convergence theorem] and because (θ˜,π^)p(θ˜0,π0).

To derive the variance term due to the second term inside {‧} bracket in (13), we approximate the second term in (13) using a first order mean value expansion,

(16)M(logLN(ξ^m,θ˜0)θ˜logLN(ξ˜m,θ˜0)θ˜)=1Nm=1Mi=1Nmj=0JYimjj=1J2logPimj(v(ξ˜m(π^*)),θ˜0)θ˜vj(ξ˜m)j=1Jvj(ξ˜m(π^*))ξ˜mjξ˜mj(π^*)πjM(π^jπj0)+op(1) (16)

where π^* lies between π^ and π0.

Define ΛjN,M(θ˜,ξ˜m)=1Nm=1Mi=1Nmj=0JYimjj=1J2logPimj(v(ξ˜m),θ˜)θ˜vj(ξ˜m)vj(ξ˜m)ξ˜mjξ˜mjπj. Then we can rewrite (16) as

M(logLN(ξ^m,θ˜0)θ˜logLN(ξ˜m,θ˜0)θ˜)=j=1JΛjN,M(θ˜0,ξ˜m(π^*))ϖj+op(1)dN(0,j,kΛ0jCov(ϖj,ϖk)Λ0k)=N(0,V1)

where Λ0j=limME[ΛjN,M(θ˜0,ξ˜m)] and the asymptotic normality result holds by the continuous mapping theorem and by the Lindeberg-Feller CLT under Assumption 5.1. In the above we can show ΛjN,M(θ˜0,ξ˜m(π^*))pΛ0j by following similar steps to (14) under Assumptions 5.1 and 5.2.

Then by MlogLN(ξ˜m,θ˜0)θ˜dN(0,Γ0limMMN) [due to the Lindeberg-Feller CLT under Assumption 5.2 (vii)], (14), the Slutsky theorem, and the continuous mapping theorem, from (13) we obtain

(17)M(θ˜^Uθ˜0)dN(0,Γ01(Γ0limMMN+V1)Γ01). (17)

A.2 Asymptotic Distribution of the LM Test

Proof. We show that the feasible LM test statistic has the same asymptotic distribution with the corresponding Wald test statistic.

Element-by-element mean value expansions of logLN(ξ^m,θ˜^R)θ˜ around θ˜0 yield

(18)MlogLN(ξ^m,θ˜^R)θ˜=MlogLN(ξ^m,θ˜0)θ˜+logLN(ξ^m,θ˜)θ˜θ˜M(θ˜^Rθ˜0)+op(1) (18)

where θ˜ lies between θ˜^R and θ˜0. Note that H(θ˜^Rθ˜0)=0 by construction of H. Write Γ^(θ˜)=logLN(ξ^m,θ˜)θ˜θ˜. Then by multiplying HΓ^(θ˜)1 to both sides of (18), it follows that

MHΓ^(θ˜)1logLN(ξ^m,θ˜^R)θ˜=MHΓ^(θ˜)1logLN(ξ^m,θ˜0)θ˜+op(1)=MHΓ01logLN(ξ^m,θ˜0)θ˜+op(1)=MHΓ01(logLN(ξ˜m,θ˜0)θ˜+(logLN(ξ^m,θ˜0)θ˜logLN(ξ˜m,θ˜0)θ˜))+op(1)

by the similar argument with (14) and the Slutsky theorem. Therefore, under the null hypotheses (7), MHΓ^(θ˜)1logLN(ξ^m,θ˜^R)θ˜ follows the same asymptotic distribution with MH(θ˜^Uθ˜0) and we obtain from (17)

(19)MHΓ̂(θ˜̂R)1logLN(ξ̂m,θ˜̂R)θ˜d0,HΓ01Γ0limMMN+V1Γ01H (19)

by the Lindeberg-Feller CLT and the continuous mapping theorem and because Γ^(θ˜^R)pΓ0,Γ^(θ˜)pΓ0. Then by (19), Γ^(θ˜^R)pΓ0,V^1(θ˜^R)pV1, and the continuous mapping theorem it follows that

LM˜M,N=NlogLN(ξ^m,θ˜^R)θ˜'Γ^(θ˜^R)1HV˜M,N1(θ˜^R)HΓ^(θ˜^R)1logLN(ξ^m,θ˜^R)θ˜={MHΓ^(θ˜^R)1logLN(ξ^m,θ˜^R)θ˜}×{HΓ^(θ˜^R)1(Γ^(θ˜^R)MN+V^1(θ˜^R))Γ^(θ˜^R)1H'}1×{MHΓ^(θ˜^R)1logLN(ξ^m,θ˜^R)θ˜}dχ2(dim((λ,γ˜,γ˜p))).

Therefore, LM˜M,N follows the same asymptotic distribution as that of the Wald test statistic T˜M,N under the null hypothesis of the price exogeneity.■

A.3 Consistency of the LM Test

Define h¯M,N(v(ξ˜m),θ˜)=1Nm=1Mi=1Nmhim(v(ξ˜m),θ˜) and E¯[him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜)]=1Nm=1Mi=1NmE[him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜)]. Assume the following to show the consistency of the LM test.

Assumption A.1(i)θ˜^Rpθ˜RAunder the alternative hypothesis against (7); (ii)–(viii) each corresponding Assumption of Assumption 5.2 (ii) to (viii) holds replacingθ˜0withθ˜RAandΘ˜0withΘ˜AwhereΘ˜Adenotes a neighborhood ofθ˜RA.

Theorem A.1Suppose Assumptions 5.1 and A.1 hold. Then the LM testLM˜M,Nis consistent underlimM||E¯[him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA)]||0.

Proof. Under the alternative hypothesis against (7), using a mean value expansion, we obtain

(20)Mh¯M,N(v(ξ^m),θ˜^R)=1Nm=1Mi=1Nm(him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA)E[him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA)])×MN (20)
(21)+M(h¯M,N(v(ξ^m),θ˜RA)h¯M,N(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA)) (21)
(22)+h¯M,N(v(ξ^m),θ˜A)θ'M(θ˜^Rθ˜RA)+ME¯[him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA)], (22)

where θ˜A lies between θ˜^R and θ˜RA. Now we analyze each term one by one below.

For (21) applying the mean value expansion around π0, we obtain

(23)M(h¯M,N(v(ξ^m),θ˜RA)h¯M,N(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA))=h¯M,N(v(ξ˜m(π)),θ˜RA)πM(π^π0) (23)

where π* lies between π^ and π0. Let ΓπA=limME[h¯M,N(v(ξ˜m(π)),θ˜RA)π]. We then have

M(h¯M,N(v(ξ^m),θ˜RA)h¯M,N(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA))=ΓπAϖ+op(1)

by Assumption 5.1 and because under E[supπΠ0him(v(ξ˜m(π)),θ˜RA)π2]< for all m [which holds under Assumption A.1 (viii)], we have h¯M,N(v(ξ˜m(π)),θ˜RA)πpΓπA by the uniform Law of Large numbers and because E[h¯M,N(v(ξ˜m(π)),θ˜RA)π] is continuous at π=π0 [which is implied by Assumption A.1 (viii) due to the dominated convergence theorem].

Next to analyze the first term in (22) let the inverse of the asymptotic variance matrix of the unconstrained estimator θ˜^U be B=Γ0(Γ0limMMN+V1)1Γ0 and define a matrix =IB1/2H(HB1H)1HB1/2. Then the asymptotic distribution of the constrained estimator θ˜^R is given by M(θ˜^Rθ˜RA)dN(0,B1/2B1/2)Z2A (see Newey and McFadden 1994, 2217–2220). Then we obtain

h¯M,N(v(ξ^m),θ˜A)θ˜M(θ˜^Rθ˜RA)=ΓθAZ2A+op(1)

where M(θ˜^Rθ˜RA)dZ2A and ΓθA=limME[h¯M,N(v(ξ^m),θ˜A)θ˜] because under Assumption A.1 (vi)–(v), we have h¯M,N(v(ξ^m),θ˜A)θ˜pΓθA by the uniform Law of Large numbers, because E[h¯M,N(v(ξ˜m(π)),θ˜R)θ˜] is continuous at θ˜R=θ˜RA and π=π0 [which is implied by Assumption A.1 (vi)–(v) due to the dominated convergence theorem], and because θ˜Apθ˜RA and π^pπ0.

Next we consider the term in (20). Note that under E[him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA)4]< for all m [which holds under Assumption A.1 (vii)], by the Lindeberg-Feller CLT, we have

m=1Mi=1Nm(him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA)E[him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA)])/NdZ1AN(0,VhA)

where VhA=limM1Nm=1Mi=1NmE[{him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA)E[him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA)]}{him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA)E[him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA)]}]. Combining these results, we obtain

Mh¯M,N(v(ξ^m),θ˜^R)=Z1AMN+ΓπAϖ+ΓθAZ2A+ME¯[him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA)]+op(1)=Op(1)+ME¯[him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA)].

Therefore, we obtain ||Mh¯M,N(v(ξ^m),θ˜^R)|| if limM||E¯[him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA)]||0 under the alternative against (7). This implies LM˜M,N under the alternative if limM||E¯[him(v(ξ˜m),θ˜RA)]||0. Therefore the LM test for price endogeneity is consistent.■

References

Altonji, J., and R. Matzkin. 2005. “Cross Section and Panel Data Estimators for Nonseparable Models with Endogenous Regressors.” Econometrica 73: 1053–1102.10.1111/j.1468-0262.2005.00609.xSuche in Google Scholar

Andrews, D. 1997. “A Conditional Kolmogorov Test.” Econometrica 65: 1097–1128.10.2307/2171880Suche in Google Scholar

Berry, S. 1994. “Estimating Discrete Choice Models of Product Differentiation.” RAND Journal of Economics 25: 242–262.10.2307/2555829Suche in Google Scholar

Berry, S., and P. Haile. 2010. “Identification in Differentiated Products Markets Using Market Level Data.” Working Paper.10.3386/w15641Suche in Google Scholar

Berry, S., J. Levinsohn, and A. Pakes. 1995. “Automobile Prices in Market Equilibrium.” Econometrica 63: 841–889.10.2307/2171802Suche in Google Scholar

Berry, S., A. Gandhi, and P. Haile. 2011. “Connected Substitutes and Invertibility of Demand.” Working Paper.10.3386/w17193Suche in Google Scholar

Bierens, H. 1990. “A Consistent Conditional Moment Test of Functional Form.” Econometrica 58: 1443–1458.10.2307/2938323Suche in Google Scholar

Chen, X., and Y. Fan. 1999. “Consistent Hypothesis Testing in Semiparametric and Nonparametric Models for Econometric Time Series.” Journal of Econometrics 91: 373–401.10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00081-5Suche in Google Scholar

Chintagunta, P., J. Dube, and K. Goh. 2005. “Beyond the Endogeneity Bias: The Effect of Unmeasured Brand Characteristics on Household-level Brand Choice Models.” Management Science 51 (5): 832–849.10.1287/mnsc.1040.0323Suche in Google Scholar

Crawford, G. 2000. “The Impact of the 1992 Cable Act on Household Demand and Welfare.” RAND Journal of Economics 31: 422–449.10.2307/2600995Suche in Google Scholar

Dubé, J. P., J. Fox, and C. L. Su. 2012. “Improving the Numerical Performance of Static and Dynamic Aggregate Discrete Choice Random Coefficients Demand Estimation.” Econometrica 80 (5): 2231–2267.10.3982/ECTA8585Suche in Google Scholar

Fan, Y., and Q. Li. 1996. “Consistent Model Specification Tests: Omitted Variables, Parametric and Semiparametric Functional Forms.” Econometrica 64: 865–890.10.2307/2171848Suche in Google Scholar

Gandhi, A., K. Kim, and A. Petrin. 2011. “Identification and Estimation in Discrete Choice Demand Models when Endogenous Variables Interact with the Error.” Working Paper.10.3386/w16894Suche in Google Scholar

Goolsbee, A., and A. Petrin. 2004. “The Consumer Gains from Direct Broadcast Satellites and the Competition with Cable TV.” Econometrica 72 (2): 351–382.10.1111/j.1468-0262.2004.00494.xSuche in Google Scholar

Hardle, W., and E. Mammen. 1993. “Comparing Nonparametric versus Parametric Regression Fits.” Annals of Statistics 21: 1926–1947.10.1214/aos/1176349403Suche in Google Scholar

Hausman, J. 1978. “Specification Tests in Econometrics.” Econometrica 46: 1251–1272.10.2307/1913827Suche in Google Scholar

Hausman, J. 1997. “Valuation of New Goods under Perfect and Imperfect Competition.” In The Economics of New Goods, edited by R. Gordon and T. Bresnahan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Suche in Google Scholar

Heckman, J. 1978. “Dummy Endogenous Variables in a Simultaneous Equation System.” Econometrica 46: 931–959.10.2307/1909757Suche in Google Scholar

Heckman, J., and R. Robb. 1985. “Alternative Methods for Evaluating the Impacts of Interventions: An Overview.” Journal of Econometrics 30: 239–267.10.1016/0304-4076(85)90139-3Suche in Google Scholar

Horowitz, J., and V. Spokoiny. 2001. “An Adaptive, Rate Optimal Test of a Parametric Mean Regression Model against a Nonparametric Alternative.” Econometrica 69: 599–631.10.1111/1468-0262.00207Suche in Google Scholar

Imbens, G., and W. Newey. 2003. “Identification and Estimation of Triangular Simultaneous Equations Models Without Additivity.” Working Paper.10.3386/t0285Suche in Google Scholar

Karaca-Mandic, P., and K. Train. 2002. “Standard Error Correction in Two-Step Estimation with Nested Samples.” Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley.10.1111/1368-423X.t01-1-00115Suche in Google Scholar

Kim, K., and A. Petrin. 2010. “Control Function Corrections for Unobserved Factors in Differentiated Product Models.” Working Paper.Suche in Google Scholar

Kitamura, Y., G. Tripathi, and H. Ahn. 2004. “Empirical Likelihood-based Inference in Conditional Moment Restriction Models.” Econometrica 72: 1667–1714.10.1111/j.1468-0262.2004.00550.xSuche in Google Scholar

Knittel, C. R., and K. Metaxoglou. 2008. “Estimation of Random Coefficient Demand Models: Challenges, Difficulties and Warnings.” Working Paper, MIT.10.3386/w14080Suche in Google Scholar

Li, Q., C. Hsiao, and J. Zinn. 2003. “Consistent Specification Tests for Semiparametric/Nonparametric Models Based on Series Estimation Methods.” Journal of Econometrics 112: 295–325.10.1016/S0304-4076(02)00198-7Suche in Google Scholar

Matzkin, R. 2003. “Nonparametric Estimation of Nonadditive Random Functions.” Econometrica 71: 1339–1375.10.1111/1468-0262.00452Suche in Google Scholar

Nevo, A. 2001. “Measuring Market Power in the Ready-to-Eat Cereal Industry.” Econometrica 69: 307–342.10.1111/1468-0262.00194Suche in Google Scholar

Newey, W. K. 1985. “Maximum Likelihood Specification Testing and Conditional Moment Tests.” Econometrica 53 (5): 1047–1070.10.2307/1911011Suche in Google Scholar

Newey, W. 1997. “Convergence Rates and Asymptotic Normality of Series Estimators.” Journal of Econometrics 79: 147–168.10.1016/S0304-4076(97)00011-0Suche in Google Scholar

Newey, W., and D. McFadden 1994. “Large Sample Estimation and Hypothesis Testing.” The Handbook of Econometrics, Volume 4, Chapter 36: 2111–2245, edited by R.F. Engle and D.L. McFadden, Elsevier.10.1016/S1573-4412(05)80005-4Suche in Google Scholar

Pakes, A. 1994. “Dynamic Structural Models, Problems and Prospects: Mixed Continuous Discrete Controls and Market Interaction.” In Advances in Econometrics, edited by C. Sims, 171–259. Sixth World Congress, Volume II, New York: Cambridge.10.1017/CCOL0521444608.005Suche in Google Scholar

Petrin, A. 2002. “Quantifying the Benefits of New Products: The Case of the Minivan.” Journal of Political Economy 110: 705–729.10.1086/340779Suche in Google Scholar

Petrin, A., and K. Train. 2010 “A Control Function Approach to Endogeneity in Consumer Choice Models.” Journal of Marketing Research 47: 370–379.10.1509/jmkr.47.1.3Suche in Google Scholar

Rivers, D., and Q. Vuong. 1988. “Limited Information Estimators and Exogeneity Tests for Simultaneous Probit Models.” Journal of Econometrics 39: 347–366.10.1016/0304-4076(88)90063-2Suche in Google Scholar

Smith, R., and R. Blundell. 1986. “An Exogeneity Test for a Simultaneous Equation Tobit Model with an Application to Labor Supply.” Econometrica 54: 679–686.10.2307/1911314Suche in Google Scholar

Song, K. 2010. “Testing Semiparametric Conditional Moment Restrictions Using Conditional Martingale Transforms.” Journal of Econometrics 154: 74–84.10.1016/j.jeconom.2009.07.002Suche in Google Scholar

Stinchcombe, M., and H. White. 1998. “Consistent Specification Testing When the Nuisance Parameters Present Only Under the Alternative.” Econometric Theory 14: 295–325.10.1017/S0266466698143013Suche in Google Scholar

Trajtenberg, M. 1989. “The Welfare Analysis of Product Innovations, with an Application to Computed Tomography Scanners.” Journal of Political Economy 97: 444–479.10.1086/261611Suche in Google Scholar

Villas-Boas, J., and R. Winer. 1999. “Endogeneity in Brand Choice Models.” Management Science 45: 1324–1338.10.1287/mnsc.45.10.1324Suche in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2014-3-12
Published in Print: 2015-1-1

©2015 by De Gruyter

Heruntergeladen am 16.9.2025 von https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/jem-2012-0002/html
Button zum nach oben scrollen