Home Estimating the Effects of Political Instability in Nascent Democracies
Article Open Access

Estimating the Effects of Political Instability in Nascent Democracies

  • Thomas J. Emery , Mitja Kovac and Rok Spruk ORCID logo EMAIL logo
Published/Copyright: September 5, 2023

Abstract

In this paper, we revisit and examine the effect of political instability on institutional quality. To this end, we exploit the crackdown of government cabinet in 2008 that led to almost two decades of pervasive political instability using the unique case of Slovenia and estimate the average treatment effect of political instability and the missing counterfactual scenario for the period 1996–2020. Based on large-scale Bayesian analysis with Metropolis–Hastings algorithm, we extract the residual component of institutional quality from the variation in predetermined unobserved characteristics. Across more than 1.5 million sequenced random samples, we construct novel time-varying estimates of institutional quality at the local and regional level. Our difference-in-differences and synthetic control estimates emphasize a rampant deterioration of institutional quality in response to political instability with evidence of weakened rule of law, less effective public sector, decreased political accountability, and more widespread prevalence of power abuses. The estimated negative effects of political instability are robust to a variety of placebo checks across more than 12 billion placebo averages for institutional quality outcome variable using random sampling method of treatment permutation.

JEL Classification: C33; D73; H70; O43

1 Introduction

Political instability and its consequences for economic and social outcomes has been a subject of rigorous scholarly debate. The conventional wisdom suggests that political instability undermines economic outcomes (Ades and Chua 1997; Aisen and Veiga 2013; Alesina et al. 1996; Barro 1991; Jong-A-Pin 2009). By disrupting the production, increasing the uncertainty, it distorts the incentives to invest, save, and acquire various forms of capital. Hence, episodes of political instability exacerbate slow economic growth (Asteriou and Price 2001), lower the rate of investment, undermine the incentives to engage in productive economic activities (Carmignani 2003), lead to a more volatile macroeconomic environment (Campos et al. 2012), increase the rewards from rent-seeking behavior (Caporale and Leirer 2010), suppress talent acquisition (Benhabib and Spiegel 1994), and may even displace human capital (Docquier et al. 2007).

Political instability has been linked with lower independence of central banks (Cukierman and Webb 1995, Cukierman et al. 1992), heavier reliance on seigniorage (Cukierman 1992), reduced aggregate investment (Özler and Rodrik 1992), heightened fiscal deficits (Roubini 1991), higher external debt (Alesina and Tabellini 1989), more widespread inequality (Alesina and Perotti 1996), and more volatile exchange rate regime (Collins 1996). In the long-term perspective, political and institutional instability is costly (Berggren et al. 2012), while even modest increase in instability may reduce per capita income up to 25 % (Hartmann and Spruk 2021).

Not everyone agrees that political instability is harmful to economic and social development. The general thrust of the argument is that vibrant economic growth and social changes necessitate vital structural changes that break the status quo of existing political coalitions and promulgate the adjustment in the balance of power among the interest groups that influence economic and political elites (North 1981; Olson 1963). Without the loss of generality, distinguishing between positive and negative type of instability need not be left to scholarly neglect. The negative type of instability is characterized by the insecurity of property rights, undermined existing institutions by political or economic elites, and their co-opted networks. Thus, the negative type of instability leads to the institutional weakening, generates insecure property rights and high transaction costs (Olson 1982).

On the contrary, the positive type of instability promulgates improvements in the existing institutions through greater adaptive efficiency to counteract unexpected economic and external shocks, break away from status quo, and adjust to altered reality. For instance, in Understanding the Process of Economic Change, North (2005) defines adaptive efficiency as the ability of societies “to flexibly adjust in the face of shocks and evolve institutions that effectively deal with altered reality.” Hence, the positive type of instability promulgates the necessary structural changes that readjust the balance of political power, break the existing rent-seeking coalitions and induce growth-enhancing institutional and policy reforms.

If the notion that institutions may be one of the root causes of long-run development may be taken for granted (Acemoglu et al. 2001, 2002), the obvious question to ask is whether political instability erodes or improves institutional quality. Existing evidence suggests that political instability tends to deteriorate and weaken labor market institutions, creating incentives for the government to introduce more distortionary regulation (Lucifora and Moriconi 2015), and impedes financial development (Roe and Siegel 2011). Gates et al. (2006) show that political regimes lacking self-enforcing equilibria characterized by a small electorate and highly constrained executive may be prone to prolonged political instability. The net effect of prolonged instability includes more volatile inflation rates (Aisen and Veiga 2006, 2008), crowded-out private investment (Svensson 1998), increased output share of government spending (Deveraux and Wen 1998), increased incentives for informality (Alberola and Urrutia 2020), and reduced security of property rights and costly contract enforcement (Keefer and Knack 2002) with substantial output, consumption, and welfare losses (Azzimonti 2011).

In this paper, we examine the effects of political instability on institutional quality at the local and regional level by exploiting the reform-blockade voice in the government cabinet as a quasi-random political shock using the case of Slovenia for the period 1996–2020. Our approach to capture subnational institutional quality relies on the extraction of the residual component of institutional quality (Magnusson and Tarverdi 2020) from geo-coded data using the repeated year-by-year variation in predetermined exogenous geographic characteristics. Such approach allows capturing the residual component and determining whether regions’ and provinces’ institutional quality is above or below the threshold implied by their geographic and climatic characteristics. In doing so, we build a large dataset that tracks the evolution of residual component of institutional quality for 468 regions worldwide where a relatively high degree of political stability is present. For the treatment and control sample, we estimate the posterior densities of institutional quality through the application of Monte Carlo Markov Chain (MCMC) sampling methods and build posterior density distributions based on Metropolis–Hastings algorithm with flat, noninformative priors. We perform a large number of iterations to estimate the posterior densities of institutional quality with around 1.5 million random sequences of samples. Subsequently, we match the treatment sample of Slovenian regions and municipalities with the control sample of regions where political stability scores is in the 80th percentile of the global distribution (Kaufmann et al. 2011).

Using a variety of difference-in-differences and synthetic control specifications, we find significant evidence of deteriorating institutional quality in response to political instability. In particular, after the blockade of structural reforms that led to early elections and opened doors to prolonged instability, our evidence highlights deteriorated voice and accountability, lower effectiveness of government administration, reduced quality of regulation, weakened rule of law, and substantially more widespread prevalence of corruption. A battery of estimated synthetic control specifications highlights that the negative institutional quality effect of political instability appears to be permanent with ample evidence of institutional breakdown. Compared to the regional level, local-level evidence indicates some improvement in government effectiveness, which appears to be entirely downgraded by increases in corruption, weakening of the rule of law, and debilitated voice and accountability. Hence, our analysis offers no evidence in support of the positive type of political instability and suggests that political instability, by increasing the cost of cooperation, does not foster the necessary adjustment and improvement of institutional quality and appears to be persistent.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the background. Section 3 presents the data and samples. Section 4 discusses the identification strategy. Section 5 presents the results. Section 6 concludes.

2 Background

After the political independence from former Yugoslavia in 1991, Slovenia established liberal democratic institutions that enshrined a respect for human rights supported by the rule of law and multi-party democracy. The period after the rapid transition to market economy between 1991 and 2007 had been characterized by strong economic growth and solid macroeconomic stability. In 2004, Slovenia has been admitted to European Union and NATO as a full member. Prior to 2007, Slovenia fully achieved Maastricht criteria with respect to monetary and fiscal stability and was admitted to European Monetary Union. In 2010, the country also joined the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) as a full member together with Chile, Israel, and Estonia. In 2021, Slovenia’s GDP per capita is comparable with that of Spain and Italy, and its inequality-adjusted human development index is high, ranked 9th worldwide together with Netherlands, Sweden, and Australia.

Political development after 1991 has been characterized by a period of relative stability between 1991 and 2008 when the balance of power shifted between center-left coalition of Liberal Democratic Party and Social Democracy (1991–2004) and the center-right coalition of Democratic Party and Christian Democratic party New Slovenia (2004–2008). In 2008, the center-left Social Democrats won the election with a relative majority of votes, heeding a fragile coalition with substantial tensions between the coalition partners. Amid the economic and financial crisis, the government cabinet proposed economic reforms for the structural adjustment of public finance and austerity policies to counteract the economic losses from the crisis. The reforms were rejected by the opposition leaders and brought to the referendum, where the reform package failed. With the assistance of the veto-player in the government cabinet, Democratic Party of Pensioners, the parliament did not support the confidence vote in favor of the government mandate and headed for early elections. In 2011, faced with the loss of several ministers and falling public support, the government cabinet ultimately collapsed. The new mandate to form the government coalition was assigned to the center-right Democratic Party, which led another fragile coalition between February 2012 and March 2013, marred by numerous corruption scandals.

The obvious response to the pervasive political instability beginning in 2008 led to a series of minority governments dominated by veto-playing political parties and coupled with widespread government interference in the economy, deteriorating control of corruption and even imprisonment of former prime minister. Former prime minister was convicted on bribery charges related 2006 arms deal and spent 6 months in prison. From September 2014 until March 2018, the government coalition comprised of the centrist party (SMC), Social Democrats, and a few minor parties. In 2018, the center-right Democratic Party won the elections but was unable to form a government coalition, leading to a minority government formed in August 2018, which collapsed and resigned in January 2020 because of the weaknesses and disagreements in pushing through the structural and institutional reforms to boost economic growth. In March 2020, formerly imprisoned head of Slovenian Democratic Party became the prime minister for the third time and headed a coalition with a policy agenda emphasizing populist right-wing rhetoric and substantial euroscepticism. In 2020, Varieties of Democracy report ranked Slovenia’s level of electoral and liberal democracy 42nd worldwide together with countries such as Malta, Argentina, Tunisia, Peru, and Cape Verde.

To estimate a rough aggregate effect of political instability, we first compare Slovenia’s economic growth trajectory with the rest of the world and apply the synthetic control estimator (Abadie and Gardeazabal 2003, Abadie et al. 2015). To this end, we build a sample dataset of 154 International Monetary Fund’s member states for the period 1992–2022, use the full path of GDP per capita in preinstability period as the set of predictors, and compare the economic growth trajectory of Slovenia to several variants of the donor pool in the pre-2008 period. The evidence suggests several important insights. Figure 1 reports the aggregate effect of political instability on per capita GDP. First, political instability appears to be a permanent shock derailing the growth trajectory downward, offering somewhat more support for theoretical notion of the negative, insecurity-generating type of instability. Second, by the end-of-sample instability period, the observed real GDP per capita is around 5690 international dollars lower than the implied counterfactual without political instability. Assessing Slovenia’s economic growth trajectory against a donor pool of 33 OECD countries[1] yields the end-of-sample GDP per capita gap indicating around 3109 international dollars lower per capita GDP in comparison with its synthetic control group. Using worldwide donor pool, Slovenia’s per capita GDP trajectory prior to the political instability is best reproduced as a weighted average of convex combination of the implied attributes of Taiwan (23 %), Latvia (19 %), South Korea (12 %), Malta (11 %), Poland (11 %), Guyana (11 %), Luxembourg (6 %), Puerto Rico (3 %), and Norway (3 %). That said, the synthetic control group unveils a hybrid and diverse influence mixture of East Asia (35 %), Central Europe and Baltics (31 %), Latin America (14 %), Southern Europe (11 %), and Western Europe (9 %), which is able to synthetize and reproduce Slovenia’s preinstability growth trajectory with almost nonexistent imbalance. Restricting the donor pool to OECD countries yields a dominant influence of Central European and Baltic states in the donor pool followed by somewhat lower shares of South Korea, Norway, Luxembourg, as well as Australia and New Zealand in the control group. By contrast, using a donor pool of non-OECD countries yields a balanced composition of synthetic version of Slovenia consisting of Taiwan (47 %), Trinidad and Tobago (10 %), Oman (10 %), Cyprus (10 %), and few others with minor weight shares. The non-OECD synthetic version of Slovenia exhibits 3464 international dollars higher per capita GDP than the actual Slovenia in the end-of-sample year. Hence, political instability entails a substantial negative effect on the trajectory of economic growth. Figure 2 reports the composition of synthetic control groups in greater detail.

Figure 1: 
Economic growth impact of political instability in Slovenia, 1992–2022.
Figure 1:

Economic growth impact of political instability in Slovenia, 1992–2022.

Figure 2: 
Composition of synthetic control groups.
Figure 2:

Composition of synthetic control groups.

The composition of synthetic control groups unveils several noteworthy similarities that warrant some discussion with respect to relevance, appropriateness, and applicability to canvass the internal validity of our estimates. Across four iterations of the analysis, a large role of East Asia and several European countries is perceptible in the composition of control groups. Several similarities and qualitative narratives can be drawn. In the full-sample specification, almost all control countries can be characterized as small, open and largely export-driven economies at the cultural and historical confluence of Latin-speaking countries such as Malta and Puerto Rico, fast-growing East Asian economies such as Taiwan and South Korea, Central European states such as Poland and Latvia, as well as several Western European states such as Norway and Luxembourg, which reflects Slovenia’s exposure to diverse influences that can be inferred from the comparison of preinstability growth trajectories. Thereby, these influences reflect both historical antecedents of Habsburg rule, geographic location in Mediterranean part of Europe as well as relatively high degree of trade openness and large manufacturing share of GDP, which can be found in East Asian donor states. In the non-OECD donor pool, the number of control countries with nonzero weight increases to 11 and is largely dominated by Taiwan, which represents 47 % of the control group. The remainder of the control group consists of small and open economies either in the Mediterranean part of Europe (i.e., Cyprus and Malta) or elsewhere, having a comparatively high level of per capita GDP. This implies that the convex combination of the implicit attributes of Slovenia’s preinstability growth trajectory is best reproduced by small and open economies in East Asia in Europe. The presence of European countries with high level of per capita income such as Ireland, Norway, and Luxembourg also poses Slovenian economy as relatively distinct and more developed than those in former Yugoslavia and Central-Eastern part of Europe where such influences can only seldom be found.

Given the apparent macroeconomic losses emanating from political instability, the obvious question to ask revolves around the effect of instability on institutional quality while adopting a disaggregated approach where the effect can be assessed at the subnational level rather than an the aggregate level per se. Such analysis may provide further insights into the variation of institutional quality in both space and time in response to a sudden shock posited by the political instability.

In this respect, our analysis adds three dimensions to the existing body of literature. First, we examine the effect of political instability by disaggregating the institutional quality to the regional and local level, which provides important insights into the heterogeneity of the effect in space. Second, we use Bayesian approach to measure institutional quality as a latent trait approximated by Monte Carlo Markov Chain (MCMC) sampling algorithm where the quality is captured through large-scale sequence of random samples based on the extraction of institutional quality component from predetermined exogenous geographic characteristics that usually fall within the scope of unobserved effects. While such approach has found ample support in political science literature, its application in empirical domain of institutional economics has not been widespread. And third, we incorporate latent scores into the standard impact evaluation techniques of difference-in-differences and synthetic control estimators and use them as the outcomes of interest where the causal effect of policies or interventions such as political instability can be learned and estimated under the plausible assumptions.

3 Data and Samples

3.1 Outcome Variables

Our approach to measure the institutional quality of Slovenian municipalities and regions is per se constrained by the lack of observable and measurable characteristics of subnational institutional quality that may provide plausible insights in the variation of institutional quality across space and time. In a seminal contribution, Magnusson and Tarverdi (2020) highlight the problems arising from aggregate baseline indicators of institutional quality that reflect some information about quality as the underlying latent variable. Although aggregate indicators have been used extensively in cross-country empirical analysis of institutional quality and its economic effects, the aggregation method implicitly assumes that the errors linked with the baseline indicators are independently distributed, which is both questionable and subject to rigorous scholarly debate. They also propose the extension of the method with nonzero cluster dependence among the error terms.

Our approach to measure subnational institutional quality combines Magnusson and Tarverdi (2020) cluster dependence approach with the extraction of the residual component of institutional quality from the observable aggregate baseline indicators. The approach we propose hinges on the extraction of the latent variable component of institutional quality from the aggregate baseline level through the linear projection onto the local level using the set of predetermined and plausibly exogenous characteristics that are usually considered “fixed” effect and cannot be manipulated at the same time to minimize the measurement error. The proposed disaggregation scheme uses the ex-ante variation in predetermined geographic characteristics to extract the residual component of institutional quality from a higher level of aggregation. That said, disaggregating institutional quality scores can be readily projected to both regional and municipal (i.e., local) level of aggregation provided that sufficient variation in the predetermined characteristics is perceivable in the data. By disaggregating the institutional quality scores to the level, it should be emphasized that the level of institutional quality at the local and regional level per se cannot be recovered, which poses an intrinsic limitation of our approach. Nevertheless, the recovery of the residual component at the local level from a linear projection of predetermined characteristics is able to uncover the residual component, which indicates whether the existing set of institutions is either better or worse than the implied level plausibly expected in the potential control units with plausibly similar geographic characteristics. Since the predetermined physical geographic covariates can be easily compared across and municipalities, regions, and countries, the disaggregating allows for a straightforward comparison of residuals both across singular (i.e., within country) and multiple (i.e., across countries) sources of space and time for each dimension of institutional quality.

In a similar vein, our set of institutional quality variables is from Kaufmann et al. (2011) and comprises well-recognized and established baseline indicators of institutional quality, namely, (i) voice and accountability,[2] (ii) rule of law,[3] (iii) regulator quality,[4] (iv) government effectiveness,[5] and (v) control of corruption.[6] Our set of predetermined characteristics exploited as a source of variation in institutional quality consists of region-level and municipal-level geographic covariates and, specifically, include latitude and longitude coordinates (in degrees), precipitation amount (in mm), duration of sunshine (in hours per year), mean annual temperature (in °C), landlocked binary indicator, and Köppen–Geiger climatic zone. These characteristics are collected from large-scale Beck et al. (2018) climate classification at 1 km resolution of topographically corrected climatic maps for the period 1980–2016. Using 1 km resolution of global map, we assemble hand-coded climatic characteristics for 2097 regions, provinces, or states from 121 countries for the period 1996–2020 and match it together with the Kaufmann et al. (2011) governance dataset that yields the potential donor pool with roughly 50,328 year-region/state/province-matched observations.

Since the institutional quality can be only partially observed at the subnational level given the measurement error and ex-ante constraints, our goal is to extract the residual component of baseline governance indicator from the aggregate level from the variation in predetermined subnational geographic covariates that are orthogonal to the institutional quality variable of interest. Residualizing the series of institutional quality to the subnational level allows us to examine whether projected institutional quality at the lower level of aggregation is higher or lower compared to the expected level implied by the multi-country and cross-regional comparison. If the underlying institutional quality residual recovered from the variation in geographic characteristics is positive, our interpretation is that the institutional quality at the subnational level is better than expected in geographically similar environment elsewhere. If the respective residual component is negative, then our interpretation is that the quality of institutions is worse than one can expect elsewhere with geographically similar characteristics. By contrast, zero residual may indicate the level of institutional quality as predicted by geographic endowments.

Suppose we observe a continuum of treated regions or municipalities indexed by i = 1,2, … N and a continuum of control units denoted by j = 1,2, … J. Since some of the geographic characteristics are time-invariant, we extract the institutional quality residual for kth baseline governance indicator through the canonical regression of the following form for each t = 1,2, … T:

q j ϵ J = η 0 + X j , i ϵ N × α + ε j , i ϵ N

where q denotes the institutional quality as a latent variable, η0 is the level of institutional quality, X is the vector of geographic characteristics, α is the set of quality response coefficients, and ε is the canonical error term. From the canonical regression of institution on the predetermined physical geographic characteristics, the residual component for the full repeated cross section of treated regions and municipalities is recovered as the difference between the observed baseline indicators and its predicted counterpart implied from the variation in exogenous geographic characteristics:

e i ϵ N = q j ϵ J , N o b s e r v e d q i ϵ N j ϵ J p r e d i c t e d

where q j ϵ J , N o b s e r v e d is the observed level of institutional quality from the baseline indicator, and q i ϵ N j ϵ J p r e d i c t e d is the predicted level of institutional quality for ith municipality that belongs to jth region and for the jth region only. The general thrust of the residual component is that it can be used to determine spatial disparities and spreads of institutional quality over time based on the difference between the observed and predicted level of institutional quality. By the same analogy, the overall level of institutional quality can be recovered as the sum of the observed component at jth level and the exogenous residual component at ith level such that QiN = qjJ + eiNjJ.

One of the limitations of the repeated cross-sectional estimation of the residual component arises from the time-invariance of some geographic characteristics such as latitude and longitude or binary indicators of coastal access and landlocked status. Without the loss of generality, repeating the cross-sectional canonical regression may only shift the intercept η0 upward or downward in each t = 1,2, … T, while the variation in QiN may be the same as in qjJ. Consequently, any attempt to isolate the effect of institutional quality from the observables and unobservables would be impossible per se since institutional differences would be treated as a set of fixed effects in panel-level analysis. It should be noted that the selection of the predetermined covariates used to construct the residualized level of institutional quality is driven by data availability. Although a much richer set of the covariates would reflect a more nuanced ex-post variation in institutional quality and further reduce noise-to-signal ratio, both cost and time of data collection are overly cumbersome. Nevertheless, we submit the battery of the predetermined covariates to further scrutiny and construct the residual series separately through a variety of combinations of X variables to tackle the robustness of the residualized series to the possible misspecification. We find that the correlation between the outcome variables using various sets of X variables is very high, with the sample correlation coefficient between +0.8 and 0.9 (i.e. p-value = 0.000). This implies that quantitatively and qualitatively similar results can be expected when different sets of predetermined covariates are used to build residualized institutional quality series.

To partially overcome these intrinsic limitations, we use Monte Carlo Markov Chain (MCMC) sampling algorithm for the probability distribution of the recovered residual component of institutional quality. Through the construction of Markov chain with the desired distribution as the equilibrium distribution, sample of target distribution can be obtained by recording the states from the chain (Jarner and Roberts 2007). We aim at obtaining a sequence of random samples from a probability distribution where random sampling is difficult and thus adopt the well-known Metropolis et al. (1953) and Hastings (1970) algorithm to approximate the true distribution of institutional quality at the subnational level. Randomly sequenced samples can be drawn from any probability distribution that has a known probability density for which a function must be known and proportional rather than exactly equal to its density and values. Metropolis–Hastings algorithm’s ability lies in generating a sequence of random sample in such way that as more samples are produced, the distribution of values more closely approximates the target distribution through an iterative procedure that produces a Markov chain. At each iteration, the algorithm selects a candidate for the next sample value from the current sample value. Provided that probability threshold is specified ex-ante, the candidate value of institutional quality is either accepted or rejected.

Let f(Q = e iϵN ) be a function proportional to the target probability distribution denoted by P(Q = e iϵN ). Our goal is to obtain a posterior parameter of institutional quality at the subnational level to be evaluated, π i ) = p i i−1,X,Q) where a single parameter is sampled from one-dimensional distribution π(Θ). To generate samples from π(Θ), the algorithm specifies a recognizable proposed probability density denoted as qg+1 g ) with the density ratio requirement π ( Θ g + 1 ) π ( Θ g ) . In this respect, the algorithm is similar to the Gibbs sampler, but it draws a candidate value first that will be accepted or rejected based on the acceptance probability. For the sake of brevity, we adopt a two-stage sampling procedure:

  • Step #1: Draw Θg+1 from the proposal density qg+1 g ).

  • Step #2: Accept Θg+1 with probability γg+1 g ) where: γ ( Θ g + 1 | Θ g ) = min ( π ( Θ g + 1 ) q ( Θ g + 1 | Θ g ) / π ( Θ g ) q ( Θ g | Θ g + 1 ) , 1 ) .

where the requirement to generate a sequence of random samples is that the values of the posterior parameter are drawn from the proposal distribution of the uniform random variable to evaluate the acceptance and rejection criteria. In the two designated steps, the algorithm decomposes the unrecognizable conditional distribution into recognizable distribution through the sequenced generation of candidate points and unrecognizable part from which the acceptance criteria is set. Such iterative procedure corrects the equilibrium distribution by allowing the functional form of the model to be nonanalytic. One notable advantage of the algorithm is that sampling can be conducted on specific tail of the distribution to analyze parameter restrictions imposed by the prior values. Since imposing prior values requires a complete information set and may be driven by subjective beliefs, our approach is to abstain from the imposition of priors. Instead, to enable the generation of random samples through the Markov chain, our approach is to impose a noninformative objective prior distribution on parameter space (Jeffreys 1946) with the density function proportional to the square root of the determinant from Fisher information matrix p ( Θ ) det I ( Θ ) . The key advantage of the objective noninformative prior is posed by the relatively nonthin tails of the distribution compared to its target counterpart, which ensures a straightforward and fast convergence of the algorithm.

By imposing objective noninformative prior to approximate the target distribution of institutional quality, we adopt an adaptive random-walk version of the Metropolis–Hastings algorithm where a candidate value of institutional quality for each region and municipality is drawn from a simple random-walk model Θ i ϵ N , t g + 1 = Θ i ϵ N , t g + ε i ϵ N , t where εiϵN,t = i.i.d ∼ (0,σ2) is the random component taken to be a symmetric density function with thick tails of t-distribution. Our choice of the density function is generic. As such, it ignores the structural features of the target density. Due to the symmetry in the proposal density functions, qg+1 g ) = q g g+1), the algorithm to estimate the subnational institutional quality converges to the following:

  • Step #1: Draw Θg+1 from the proposal density qg+1 g ).

  • Step #2: Accept Θg+1 with probability γg+1 g ) where: γg+1 g ) = min[πg+1)/π g )t,1].

And conveys two chief advantages in estimating the latent institutional quality. First, the simplified algorithm has the ability to control the variance of the error term, which substantially reduces the measurement error. And second, the algorithm must be tuned by adjusting the variance of the error term to obtain an acceptable level of accepted draws. Given the size of our sample, we set the number of iterations to obtain a sequence of random samples at 12,500 for each outcome-year combination and set the acceptance rate at 25 %, which is in the conventional range between 20 and 40 %. At 12,500 iterations per outcome and year, the number of discarded observations through the burn-in amounts to 2500. Hence, for 24 years and 5 outcomes under consideration, the overall number of iterations performed in our analysis is around 1,500,000 million random sequences of samples. This allows us to construct the mean and median estimate of the posterior parameter for each region and municipality for each t = 1,2, … T. By inverting the test statistics, we also compute the upper and lower confidence bounds of the posterior parameter for each treated and nontreated region and for a full cross section of municipalities. One of the caveats arises from the stability and composition of the latent component over time. Estimating a repeated sequence of randomly generated samples through MCMC algorithms such as Metropolis–Hastings usually invokes a notable confluence of cyclical and deterministic components that may be inherent in the estimated series with noninformative priors. While the deterministic component captures long-term trend of the series, the cyclical component may capture short-run oscillations of the posterior parameter values from its long-run equilibrium. Suppose that the posterior parameters can be decomposed into the deterministic and cyclical component:

Θ i , j , t = τ i , j , t + c i , j , t

where τ captures he deterministic component and c represents the cyclical component of the parameter. Notice that the deterministic component captures the signal of the institutional quality parameter, whereas the latter captures the noise behind the latent quality trait. If the latent trait denotes short-term and temporary deviations from the long-run trend, Θ has a tendency to exhibit a stationary mean-reverting pattern since, in such circumstances, it is determined by c instead of τ. Hence, if c component prevails over time, the simulated latent quality trait will converge to the random-walk behavior. Conversely, if the latent quality trait exhibits little deviation from the cyclical component, the underlying posterior parameter Θ is dominated by τ. Our goal is to recover a smooth long-run trend component of the posterior parameter for ith municipality and jth regions, which is done by solving Hodrick and Prescott (1997) optimization problem:

min t 1 T ( Θ i , j , t τ i , j , t ) 2 + ϕ ( ( τ i , j , t + 1 τ i , j , t ) ( τ i , j , t τ i , j , t 1 ) ) 2

where (Θi,j,t − τi,j,t) denotes the residual component of the latent quality trait in continuous time and satisfies the stability condition such that c t i . i . d N ( 0,1 ) . The parameter ϕ captures the speed of dynamic quality trait adjustment over time to parse out the cyclical component from its long-run counterpart. Ravn and Uhlig (2002) state that ϕ should vary by the fourth power of frequency observation ratio. For annual observations, this implies that ϕ = 6.25 (=1600/44), which we adopt to smooth the series of latent institutional quality trait for each dimension.

3.2 Sample

To isolate the treatment effect of political instability, it is necessary to build a control sample of regions where the prevalence of political instability is imperceptible. This implies that regions from countries that have endured prolonged political instability such as Italy or Argentina that has persisted over time do not provide a plausible variation in the trajectory of institutional quality to estimate the effects of instability. To address these concerns, we leverage the variation in the estimated latent institutional quality of Slovenian regions and municipalities against their peers from countries with a high degree of political stability. To this end, we examine the differences in the political stability and absence of violence using Kaufmann et al. (2011) indicator of stability, which has been used extensively in the literature. In the next step, we build a distribution of political stability through the kernel density function and eliminate the region-level observations below the 80th percentile threshold of political instability score. Excluding these observations ensures that stable unit treatment value assumption (SUTVA) is reasonably met, while those observations where the influence of political instability is apparent are discarded from the sample. Figure 3 depicts the global distribution of political instability score in our treatment and control samples through a joint density function.

Under this particular criteria, the effective size of the donor pool to 246 regions from 16 countries[7] for the period 1996–2020 yields a donor pool 5904 matched observations. The treatment sample consists of the 12 regions,[8] 201 municipalities, and 11 urban municipalities for the same period. This yields a region-level treatment sample with 288 observations and a municipal-level treatment sample with 5088 observations. Hence, the combined size of treatment and control samples comprises 11,280 observations.

Figure 3: 
Global distribution of political stability.
Figure 3:

Global distribution of political stability.

Figure 4 exhibits the trajectories of regional institutional quality estimated from the latent quality model using Metropolis–Hastings MCMC algorithm with the objective prior function. Each figure exhibits the mean score of institutional quality obtained from the repeated sequence of randomly generated samples together with the upper and lower bound of the 95 % confidence interval. The evidence readily uncovers the signs of deteriorating institutional quality after the onset of political instability in 2008. Declining institutional quality does not seem to be created equal across all respective dimensions. For instance, latent dynamic scores of quality suggest that voice and accountability, rule of law, and the ability to control corruption tend to deteriorate particularly fast. By contrast, the speed of decline in government effectiveness appears to be somewhat slower, while the trend of regulatory quality tends to improve around the year 2016 amidst persistent decline after 2008. The general thrust of these comparisons invariably advocates a pattern of accelerated deteriorating of subnational institutional quality in the midst of the rising political instability. In Figure 5, municipal-level latent scores are depicted for the same dimensions of institutional quality. In spite of the notable similarities of the trajectories of institutional quality, several differences are apparent. First, voice and accountability dimension tends to deteriorate relatively fast in the initial years of the shock, while it does not seem to decrease further. Second, rule of law and government effectiveness components tend to deteriorate much slower than at the regional level. Third, municipal regulatory quality tends to decrease substantially in the initial years of the shock, while it tends to recuperate strongly afterward and exceeds the preinstability level in the end-of-sample years. Fourth, the control of corruption tends to deteriorate even faster at the municipal level, which suggests that local communities may be even more prone to the rampant deterioration of the control of corruption. Compared to the regional level, municipalities have somewhat lesser drop in political accountability, rule of law, and government effectiveness. The estimated latent scores also advocate a somewhat better regulatory capacity of the municipalities amidst a temporary nature of instability shock. However, the deterioration in the ability to control corruption appears to be even stronger than at the regional level.

Figure 4: 
Trajectories of regional institutional quality in Slovenia, 1996–2020.
Figure 4:

Trajectories of regional institutional quality in Slovenia, 1996–2020.

Figure 5: 
Trajectories of municipal institutional quality in Slovenia, 1996–2020.
Figure 5:

Trajectories of municipal institutional quality in Slovenia, 1996–2020.

4 Identification Strategy

4.1 Difference-In-Differences

Our goal is to estimate the contribution of political instability to the institutional quality consistently. To this end, we estimate a simple but compact difference-in-differences specification in the presence of unobserved effects:

Q i , j , t = α ˆ 0 + α ˆ 1 ( P o s t C r a c k d o w n ) i , j , t + X i , t β ˆ + μ i J + δ t T + ϵ i , t

where Q is the institutional quality in municipality i = 1,2, … N and region j = 1,2, … J at time t = 1,2, … T, X is the vector of structural covariates that vary systematically with the outcome variable, μ is the set of municipality- or region-level fixed effects which are, by default, unobserved to the econometrician, δ is the set of time-varying institutional quality shock common to all municipalities and regions, and ϵ denotes stochastic disturbances. Our key parameter of interest is α ˆ 1 , which represents the average treatment effect of political instability captured by the binary treatment variable (Post-Crackdown) for the full set of regions and municipalities in the post-treatment period 2008–2020. In the baseline differences-in-differences model of institutional quality, standard errors are adjusted for serially correlated stochastic disturbances and heteroskedastic distribution of random error variance using simple region- or municipality-level non-nested single-way clustering scheme. The key assumption that underlines the validity of the difference-in-differences estimate of α ˆ 1 concerns parallel trends of institutional quality between the treated municipalities and regions and their untreated peers. Against this backdrop, De Chaismartin and D’Haultfoeuille (2020) show that in the presence of parallel trends assumption, a linear panel-level regressions of such type estimate weighted sums of the treatment effect in each unit and time period. The weights used to compute the treatment effect of interest may be negative, which can be problematic if the treatment effect exhibits either spatial or temporal heterogeneity. For instance, treatment coefficient in our DiD regression may be negative, while the treatment effect may be positive. To address these concerns, they propose a two-way fixed-effects estimator of the treatment effect for the observed units that switch treatment only at the time they switch, which does not necessitates homogeneity assumption on the treatment effect. Hence, we adopt a two-way fixed-effects estimator and for a given time-fixed treatment in our model, we thus tackle and allow for the heterogeneity of the treatment effect in time.

4.2 Synthetic Control Estimates

In the absence of parallel trend assumption, difference-in-differences estimator may not isolate the treatment effect of interest. When parallel trend assumption fails, the average treatment effect may be tainted by preexisting trends or shock and, thus, it does not provide any evidence of whether the effect of political instability on institutional quality is significant or not. The hypothetical absence of parallel trend assumption can be partially addressed by adopting the synthetic control estimator to isolate the treatment effect of interest (Abadie 2021; Abadie et al. 2015; Ben-Michael et al. 2021; Billmeier and Nannicini 2013; Cattaneo et al. 2021; Powell 2022; Xu 2017). Suppose we observed J + 1 regions in the time period t = 1,2, … T where the entire set of regions is exposed to the political instability while {2, … J + 1} being directly unaffected. We assume that political instability takes place at time T0 and lasts for the entire postintervention period, which implies that t < T0 < T where T0 + 1 indicates the first post-treatment period of instability. Our interest lies in estimating the effect of instability on institutional quality for the full set of treated regions. Let Y i , t N denote the outcome for ith region at time t in the hypothetical absence of political instability, and let Y i , t I denote the corresponding outcome for region i at time t that would be observed if ith unit were exposed to the shock posed by instability. By assuming that Y i , t N = Y i , t I for each jth region in the preintervention period t < T0 + 1, our aim is to estimate the impact of instability on institutional quality for each post-treatment period:

λ 1 , t > T 0 = Y 1 , t I Y 1 , t N
λ 1 = { λ 1 , T 0 , λ T }

where Y 1 , t N is by default unobserved to the econometrician and needs to be estimated. Without the loss of generality, our assumption is that Y 1 , t N follows a latent factor model, which allows the approximation of the counterfactual levels of institutional quality in the hypothetical absence of instability. Hence, for the combined pre- and postintervention period, we estimate the trajectory of institutional quality in the absence of instability through the following latent factor model:

Y i , t N = δ t + θ t Z i + η t μ i + ϵ i , t

where ϵ i , t N ( 0,1 ) transitory shocks under i.i.d. assumption, δ t is the set of common temporal shocks that absorb time-fixed effects into the counterfactual trajectory, Z i R r represents the observed covariates unaffected by the shock, η t R r is the set of common unobserved factors, and μ i R r represents the set of unknown factor loadings. The key advantage of the latent factor model is posed by the ability to capture heterogeneous responses of the outcome variable to multiple unobserved factors and embed the time trends into the model. By estimating Y i , t N , the control group can be reweighted so that a synthetic version of the instability-affected region is matched with the donor pool on Z i and some pre-T0 {Y}, which immediately implies that μ i will be matched automatically. Therefore, to approximate the missing counterfactual scenario, control group for the instability-affected region needs to be reweighted to ensure that the control group mimics the characteristics and attributes of the affected region inasmuch as possible. Let W = (w2, … wJ+1) be a vector of weights such that w j  ≥ 0∀j. For the full vector W, the outcome variable of the synthetic control group at time t is given by:

Y W , t = j = 2 J + 1 w j Y j , t = δ t + θ t ( j = 2 J + 1 w j Z j ) + η t ( j = 2 J + 1 w j μ j ) + ( j = 2 J + 1 w j ϵ j )

Where ∃W* is such that the synthetic control group can be reasonably well matched with the treated region in the full pre-T0 period wherein both j = 2 J + 1 w j * Y j , t = Y 1 , t and j = 2 J + 1 w j * Z j = Z 1 , t can be approximated. Provided that t = 1 T 0 λ t λ t is nonsingular, then for all t > T0, we have E [ Y 1 , t N j = 2 J + 1 w j * Y j , t ] 0 as T0 →  or if T0 is large relative to the scale of ϵi,t. The vector of weights W is built to minimize the distance in pre-T0 outcomes and auxiliary covariates between the full set of treated regions and its respective control group such that X 1 X 0 W V subject to w j  ≥ 0 and w2+ … +wJ+1 = 1. To minimize the discrepancy in the attributes and characteristics of the treated regions prior to the political instability, we use a positive semi-definite matrix as a linear combination of preintervention outcomes and covariates through the following cross validation:

W * = argmin W X 1 X 0 W V = ( X 1 X 0 W ) V ( X 1 X 0 W )

Which consists of two stages. In the training stage, the matrix V denotes the relative importance of covariates and pre-T0 outcomes in explaining the institutional quality outcomes. In the validation stage, predictive weights of covariates and pretreatment outcomes are selected to minimize the root mean square prediction error to build W vector indicating which regions from the donor pool have similar covariate and outcome values and fall within the convex hull of characteristics and attributes of the treated regions but had no political instability shock. Under these conditions, the missing counterfactual scenario can be estimated through an approximately unbiased estimator of λ1,t:

λ ˆ 1 , t = Y 1 , t j = 2 J + 1 w j * Y j , t = Y 1 , t Y w * , t

wherefrom it follows immediately that even though {μ} vector is unobservable to the econometrician, fitting the joint vector {Y,Z} provides the sufficient condition to match the observed realization of pre-T0 {Y} with its counterpart in the donor pool. Hence, the difference between the observed trajectory of institutional quality and its synthetic peer tends to disappear E [ Y 1 , t N j = 2 J + 1 w j * Y j , t ] 0 if Λ 1 = { Y 1,1 , Y 1 , T 0 , Z 1 } ϵ R 1 × ( T 0 + r ) falls within the convex hull of {Λ2, … ΛJ+1}, which implies that the linear combination of the attributes and characteristics from the vector of covariates V in the training stage and vector of weights W can only include nonzero positive weight rates and thus, Rank({Λ2, … ΛJ+1}) = T0 + r condition holds. To estimate a plausible counterfactual scenario without preexisting trends in the outcome variables, we assume that the treated regions and their counterparts in the donor pool without political instability follow the same latent factor model over time. If preintervention time window is sufficiently large, reasonably unbiased estimate of Y i , t N is possible. Given that our time window spans more than 10 years, it is neither insufficiently low nor excessively large and enables us to track and reproduce the region-level trajectory of institutional quality is a reasonable manner to avoid biasing the estimate of λ ˆ 1 , t .

Since our model involves several treated units with a single-treatment year, we follow Cavallo et al. (2013), Acemoglu et al. (2016), and Gobillon and Magnac (2016) and extend the model setup toward multiple treated units. Under such setup, the vector of treatment effects of political instability { λ ˆ 1 , T 0 + 1 , λ ˆ 1 , T 0 + k } is estimated for each region separately. Hence, a dynamic estimate of average treatment effect is computed by integrating over the treated units vector of λ ˆ 1 :

λ = { λ ˆ 1 , T 0 + 1 , λ ˆ 1 , T 0 + k } = N T 1 i = 1 N T { λ ˆ 1 , T 0 + 1 , λ ˆ 1 , T 0 + k }

where the heterogeneity of treatment effect is further examined through the inspection of λ ˆ 1 , which allows us to build the distribution of treatment effects for each underlying outcome variable and compare its evolution before and after the political instability shock. Following Firpo and Possebom (2018), we modify root mean square prediction error from preintervention period to test sharp null hypothesis of no treatment effect whatsoever and invert the test statistics to estimate the 95 % confidence bounds and examine the precision of the estimated treatment effects as well as their respective significance and robustness.

5 Results

5.1 Difference-In-Differences Estimates

Table 1 reports difference-in-differences (DiD) municipality-level estimates of the institutional quality effect of political instability. Panel A reports standard DiD estimates in the presence of municipality-fixed effect. Each specification confers the full set of both municipality-fixed effects and time-fixed effects to absorb both time-invariant heterogeneity and time-varying common institutional technology shocks into the model and eliminate them as the respective sources of confoundedness. The evidence points out a pervasive and substantial deterioration of institutional quality in response to the political instability. In particular, point estimates invariably suggest significant drop in institutional quality after the government crackdown in 2008. For instance, the estimates in column (1) suggest that the average treatment effect of political instability on voice and accountability dimension is around −0.13 and is statistically significant at 1 % (p-value = 0.000). This amounts to an average drop in municipal-level voice and accountability latent score by about one 10th of the standard deviation, which is appears to be large. That said, the advent of political instability in 2008 appears to have restrained the citizens’ access to participation in selecting the government and also deteriorated freedom of expression and association. The underlying post-treatment political instability variable accounts for around 20 % of the overall variation in voice and accountability dimension in the full sample, which appears to be large. Furthermore, point estimates in column (2) invariably indicate a substantial deterioration of the rule of law in response to the onset of political instability. Although the average treatment effect is about half as large as its voice and accountability counterpart in column (1), the point estimate is statistically significant and invariably suggests that rule of law score tends to decrease by 0.068 standard deviation in the post-treatment period while the underlying coefficient appears to be statistically significant at 1 %. By contrast, the estimated average treatment effect in column (3) indicates some improvement in government effectiveness in response to the political instability. The point estimate in column (3) shows that municipalities tend to have 0.058 standard deviation improvement in government effectiveness in the underlying post-treatment period. By contrast, the estimates in column (4) and column (5) uncover the evidence of rampant deterioration in regulatory quality as well as a substantial drop in the control of corruption. Both coefficients are statistically significant at 1 %, whereas the post-treatment effect of instability accounts for about 20 % of the overall variation in regulatory quality and control of corruption. In each specification, the null hypothesis of the absence of parallel trend assumption between the treated municipalities and its control group is rejected, which suggests that in the absence of instability, the differences in institutional quality between the treated municipalities and their control group is indeed constant over time.

Table 1:

Difference-in-differences estimated effect of political instability on institutional quality of Slovenian municipalities, 1996–2020.

Voice and accountability Rule of law Government effectiveness Regulatory quality Control of corruption
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Panel A: Standard difference-in-differences estimator with municipality-fixed effects

λ 1 −0.130*** (0.005) −0.068*** (0.005) 0.058*** (0.006) −0.081*** (0.006) −0.139*** (0.006)
Overall R2 0.20 0.19 0.14 0.20 0.20
# Observations 11,500 11,500 11,500 11,500 11,500
# Clusters 460 460 460 460 460
Parallel trend assumption t-statistics (p-value) 14.49 (0.000) 15.33 (0.000) 21.18 (0.000) 11.49 (0.000) 11.12 (0.000)

Panel B: de Chaisemartin and D’Haultfoeuille heterogeneous difference-in-differences estimates with two-way fixed effects and heterogeneous treatment

λ 1,Baseline −0.003 (0.004) 0.012*** (0.003) 0.038*** (0.002) −0.002 (0.003) −0.008*** (0.003)
λ 1,t+1 −0.024*** (0.007) 0.032*** (0.005) 0.071*** (0.004) −0.022*** (0.007) −0.033*** (0.006)
λ 1,t+2 −0.062*** (0.011) 0.051*** (0.007) 0.077*** (0.006) −0.059*** (0.010) −0.070*** (0.009)
λ 1,t+3 −0.120*** (0.014) 0.058*** (0.009) 0.066*** (0.008) −0.117*** (0.013) −0.111*** (0.011)
λ 1,t+4 −0.178*** (0.016) 0.056*** (0.009) 0.055*** (0.010) −0.175*** (0.015) −0.141*** (0.013)
λ 1,t+5 −0.215*** (0.017) 0.055*** (0.010) 0.056*** (0.011) −0.216*** (0.016) −0.143*** (0.015)
End-of-sample placebo DiD coefficient −0.0005 (0.003) −0.034 (0.002) 0.028 (0.002) −0.0006 (0.003) −0.008 (0.002)
# Observations 11,500 11,500 11,500 11,500 11,500
# Treated 460 460 460 460 460
# Switchers 212 212 212 212 212

Panel C: Nearest-neighboring matching estimates

λ 1 −0.517*** (0.007) −0.441*** (0.007) −0.322*** (0.007) −0.507*** (0.007) −0.539*** (0.012)
# Observations 11,500 11,500 11,500 11,500 11,500
# Match-ups 5 5 5 5 5
Distance matrix Mahalanobis Mahalanobis Mahalanobis Mahalanobis Mahalanobis
  1. Notes: The table reports difference-in-differences estimated effect of political instability on municipality-level institutional quality. The set of dependent variables comprises the latent institutional quality scores obtained through MCMC random sample sequencing method using Metropolis–Hasting algorithm. Panel A reports standard difference-in-differences estimates with municipality-fixed effects. Panel B reports de Chaisemartin and D’Haultfoeuille (2020) heterogeneous difference-in-differences estimates with two-way fixed effects and time-varying treatment heterogeneity. End-of-sample placebo coefficient is computed through the spatial permutation of the treatment to the full control group by capping placebo runs at 5000. Panel C reports Abadie and Imbens (2006) nearest-neighbor matching estimates of institutional quality effect of political instability using pairwise covariate-level distance matching between treated municipalities and their nontreated peers. Standard errors are adjusted for serially correlated stochastic disturbances and arbitrary heteroskedastic distribution of the error variance using non-nested multi-way clustering scheme and error component model for finite-sample adjustment of empirical distribution function. Asterisks denote statistically significant coefficients at 1 % (*), 5 % (**), and 10 % (***), respectively.

Panel B reports heterogeneous DiD estimates with two-way fixed effects proposed by De Chaisemartin and D’Haultfoeuille (2020). The key advantage of two-way fixed-effects estimator is that it specifically addresses temporal heterogeneity of the effect. The panel reports the baseline institutional quality effect of instability in the contemporaneous year of the shock as well as the effect in 5-year time span together with the end-of-sample placebo coefficient to further tackle both the uniqueness and significance of the effect. The evidence suggests a reasonably strong deterioration in the voice and accountability score in the post-treatment period. The estimated set of post-treatment coefficients indicates zero contemporaneous effect and a relatively high negative effect of instability in the 5-year period. At the same time, the end-of-sample placebo coefficient is not statistically significantly different from zero, which implies that the estimated negative effect of political instability on voice and accountability is relatively unique and specific to the treated municipalities only. The evidence also suggests some improvement of government effectiveness in response to the political instability as indicated in column (3) and also reported earlier in Panel B. Conversely, point estimates in column (4) further uncover the evidence of the deterioration of regulatory quality. While the contemporaneous effect is not distinguishable from zero, the effect becomes negative in the first post-treatment year (−0.022, p-value = 0.000) and rises up to −0.216 (p-value = 0.000) in the fifth post-treatment year. Consistent with the baseline fixed-effects difference-in-differences estimate in column (5), we further uncover the evidence of the widespread deterioration in the control of corruption.

The deterioration is both immediate and appears to persist. The treatment effect coefficient in the contemporaneous year of instability is both negative and statistically significant and tends to widen in magnitude considerably until the fifth year of the post-treatment period while retaining a high degree of statistical significance (i.e., p-value = 0.000). By explicitly accommodating temporal heterogeneity into the underlying DiD model specification, the evidence further unravels and demonstrates debilitating effects of political instability on institutional quality, which does not seem to be temporary. Panel C re-examines the difference-in-differences effect through nearest-neighbor matching technique (Abadie and Imbens 2006) where the treatment effect of instability is obtained by the covariate distance matching between the treated municipalities and the control sample. The estimated coefficients on average treatment effects are negative and significant at 1 %, which confirms the institutional quality deterioration in response to the instability and suggests no evidence to support the notion of growth-enhancing effects of political instability. The drop in institutional quality appears to the largest for voice and accountability and control of corruption dimensions.

5.2 Synthetic Control Estimates

The local-level evidence based on difference-in-differences estimates of the institutional quality model specification indicates substantial deterioration in response to the political instability. Two limitations are inherent in the DiD approach. First, small size of the municipalities chiefly implies that local-level response of the latent institutional quality to political instability may be dominated by the response at the regional level. Second, if the parallel trend assumption is sensitive to the length of the pretreatment period or varying composition of control sample, estimating the counterfactual scenario through the application of synthetic control estimator may provide a more plausible evidence on the effect scope and size. Synthetic control estimator provides evidence on the average treatment effect in each respective year of the postintervention period, which seems to be more informative about the nature of the political instability shock.

Table 2 reports the balance of preinstability institutional quality outcomes and auxiliary covariates between the selected treated regions and their respective synthetic control groups for the three selected regions. Balancing the outcomes in pre-T0 period and the auxiliary covariates indicates a reasonably good quality of the fit. Both the values of the outcomes and covariates in the preintervention period are closely aligned without major discrepancies. For instance, synthetically matched levels of outcome variables for the full set of treated regions are almost identical in the pretreatment period. The estimated root mean square prediction (RMSE) is low and appears to be within 2 % of the scale-adjusted error margin. At the same time, the matched control groups for the treated regions exhibit similar auxiliary characteristics, which imply that the synthetic control groups closely mimic both the dynamic and structural characteristics of the treated regions prior to the political instability shock. It should be noted that for some regions such as Littoral-Carso, the quality of the fit appears to be excellent (i.e., RMSE = 0.006) with evidence of few discrepancies compared to the synthetic control group in the pretreatment period.

Table 2:

Preinstability covariate balancing.

Central Slovenia Littoral-Carso Styria-Maribor
Voice and accountability Rule of law Control of corruption
RMSE 0.022 0.006 0.021
Treated Matched Treated Matched Treated Matched
Outcome variable in 1996 0.31 0.28 0.32 0.32 0.18 0.14
Outcome variable in 1998 0.07 0.05 0.37 0.37 −0.06 −0.06
Outcome variable in 2000 −0.13 −0.09 0.33 0.33 −0.22 −0.19
Outcome variable in 2002 −0.20 −0.19 0.26 0.26 −0.28 −0.27
Outcome variable in 2004 −0.19 −0.20 0.15 0.16 −0.25 −0.27
Outcome variable in 2006 −0.08 −0.08 0.13 0.13 −0.17 −0.18
Outcome variable in 2007 0.01 0.00 0.16 0.16 −0.13 −0.12
Latitude 46.05 47.10 45.54 36.30 46.55 42.98
Longitude 14.50 14.95 13.73 61.88 15.64 −5.61
Capital 1 0 0 0 0 0
Island 0 0.97 0 0.90 0 0.76
Landlocked 1 0.03 0 0.10 1 0.24
Land area (log) 7.85 9.29 6.95 8.08 7.68 9.43
Altitude 295 39.75 15 147.21 279 132.28
Temperature 10.40 11.75 14.4 15.68 9.5 12.24
Rainfall 1290 1231 1056 1615.78 986 946.41
Sunshine duration 1974 1613 2018.54 1791.25 2037 1837.03
Europe 1 0.82 1 0.47 1 0.91

Figure 6 reports the composition of synthetic control groups for the selected treated regions.[9] In spite of the numerous similarities, several differences are perceptible in the composition of control groups between the treated regions. For instance, the voice and accountability trajectory of Littoral-Carso in the preinstability period is best reproduced as a convex combination of the implied attributes of Midland Ireland (24 %), Madeira (13 %), Burgenland (18 %), Aomori (14 %), Porto (11 %), Gaborone (11 %), Regiao de Leiria (4 %), Azores (4 %), and Kagawa (<1 %). Taken altogether, 41 % of the control group consists of Portuguese intermunicipal regions, followed by Irish regions (24 %), Austrian federal states (18 %), Japanese prefectures (15 %), and Botswanan districts, particularly Gaborone City (11 %). In a similar vein, the rule of law trajectory of Central Slovenia prior to the political instability is best synthesized as convex combination of institutional development and the auxiliary characteristics of Madeira (66 %), Saitama (13 %), Southwest Ireland (11 %), Tottori (7 %), and Gotland (3 %), respectively. Furthermore, the control of corruption trajectory of Drava region before the instability period appears to be best reproduced as linear combination of the implied characteristics of South West Ireland (76 %), Medio Tejo (15 %), and Ghanzi (10 %). In terms of further example, the composition of synthetic control group for Upper Carniola’s trajectory of regulatory quality is similar and appears to be dominated by Irish regions, followed by one Botswana’s district (Ngamiland) and one Portuguese intermunicipal region (Ave/Braga) where the combined total weight share of Irish regions is around 80 %.

Figure 6: 
Composition of region-level synthetic control groups.
Figure 6:

Composition of region-level synthetic control groups.

Figure 7 reports synthetic control estimates of the institutional quality effect of political instability. More specifically, the figure reports the quality effect of instability for each of the five outcomes by displaying the mean effect for the full post-treatment period alongside 95 % confidence bounds. Thus, the vertical axis exhibits the institutional quality gap between the treated region and its synthetic peer. The estimates indicate plausible evidence of the pervasive institutional quality breakdown induced by the political instability. The estimated effect of instability on voice and accountability appears to be temporary. While the respective trajectory decreases markedly in the early postinstability period, it tends to rebound back to the preinstability level in the end-of-sample years. This indicates a sharp temporary effect of instability instead of its permanency. We also find evidence of the pervasive deterioration of the rule of law in response to the instability. After 2008, the rule of law trajectory appears to improve modestly followed by a rapid drop, which tends to amplify in the end-of-sample year. Pointwise, the average treatment effect of political instability on the treated amounts to −0.2 basis points in the end-of-sample year, respectively. The evidence based on synthetic control analysis also uncovers substantial deterioration of government effectiveness in the postinstability years. In spite of somewhat markedly lower gap behind the synthetic peers after 2015, the upper and lower bound of the confidence interval are firmly below zero, indicating an arguably strong and pervasive effect of instability on the ability of the government to effectively formulate and implement sound policies. The estimated gaps of regulatory quality are similarly negative in the entire post-treatment period, indicating a large regulatory quality cost associated with political instability. Furthermore, the synthetic control estimates indicate a pervasive and rigorous deterioration of the control of corruption. While the gap between the treated regions and their synthetic peers appears to be both indiscernible and imperceptible in the pretreatment period, the average treatment effect on the treated with respect to corruption control is both immediate, large, and pervasive. The control of corruption trajectory of the treated regions deviates substantially from its synthetic benchmark in a considerable manner. The deterioration of the trajectory continues unabated and appears to be large. In the end-of-sample year, the average treatment effect of instability on the institutional quality amounts to −0.35 basis points and seems to be large and ubiquitous.

Figure 7: 
Average treatment effect of political instability on institutional quality of Slovenian regions, 1996–2020.
Figure 7:

Average treatment effect of political instability on institutional quality of Slovenian regions, 1996–2020.

In Table 3, we compare the contrasts between the pretreatment and post-treatment effects of political instability for each outcome variable. More specifically, in the presence of weak effects of instability, the pretreatment effects and post-treatment effects should be roughly equal with the difference being statistically indistinguishable from zero. However, if the political instability triggers a discernible shift in the trajectories of institutional quality, the differences in the estimated post-treatment and pretreatment effects should be both apparent and statistically significant. Three different implications emanate from these comparisons. First, Chow test statistics on the equality of coefficients before and after the instability shock indicates ample evidence of the structural break in each outcome, indicating a marked shift in the trajectories of institutional quality. The resulting p-values are uniformly within 1 % significance threshold, which implies that the political instability has indeed triggered a differential trend in the post-treatment quality trajectory compared to the synthetic benchmark (Spruk and Kovac 2020). Second, a simple test of parallel trend assumption in the spirit of Muralidharan and Prakash (2017) is performed to examine whether the trends in the gap between the observed and synthesized trajectories of institutional quality are parallel in the pretreatment period. It should be noted that our test concerns parallel trends in the trajectories of institutional quality gaps compared to the trajectories in the donor pool. Nonparallel trajectories’ trends may indicate either large predictive discrepancy between the treated regions and their synthetic peers, which may invoke the presence of policy shocks distinctive from political instability. In each model specification, we reject the null hypothesis of no parallel trends between the treated regions and their synthetic peers at 1 % significance threshold, which implies that institutional quality gap at the regional level is plausibly captured by the trends in the synthetic control group. Lastly, another test we conduct is to see if in the anticipation of political instability, the treatment and control group change their institutional quality behavior. In the presence of discernible anticipation effect, the estimated effects of political instability would be questionable at best. The evidence largely confirms the absence of the anticipation effects in each institutional quality outcome in the treatment and control group prior to the instability shock. The resulting p-value is high in each outcome even when the significance threshold is set at artificially elevated levels, which implies that the null hypothesis of no effect in treatment anticipation cannot be rejected. Taken together, the tests readily suggest that synthetic control estimates plausibly capture the effect of political instability on institutional quality. No rejection of the null hypothesis also implies that the resulting post-treatment gap in the institutional quality is unlikely to be driven by the alternative political or structural shocks. If the null hypothesis were rejected, the hypothetical possibility of other shocks influencing the institutional quality trajectory would become more feasible to discuss.

Table 3:

Testing structural break, parallel trends, and treatment anticipation effects.

Voice and accountability Rule of law Government effectiveness Regulatory quality Control of corruption
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Panel A: Chow structural break test

F-Statistics (p-value) [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000]

Panel B: Parallel trend assumption test

t-Statistics (p-value) [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000]

Panel C: Granger treatment anticipation test

F-Statistics (p-value) [0.945] [0.675] [0.132] [0.867] [0.492]
  1. Notes: The table reports Chow (1960) structural break test in the institutional quality gap between treated regions and their control group for the post/pretreatment period to test for the presence of differential trend induced by the instability. Parallel trend assumption is tested through a simple linear regression of the respective outcome variable on treatment status, year variable, and the interaction term between the two. Granger test of treatment anticipation is tested through the equality of pretreatment instability variables compared to the post-treatment instability variables between the treated regions and their control groups. The table reports the p-values on the test statistics.

Figure 8 reports the overall composition of the synthetic control groups across the full set of treated regions for the full set of outcome variables. Instead of reporting the exhaustive composition for each region and outcome separately, the frequency distribution of donors with nonzero positive weight is reported, which enables a more straightforward comparison of the contrasts in the composition of synthetic control group across the outcome categories. The evidence suggests both notable similarities and marked contrasts in the composition of control group. For instance, in the estimated synthetic control specifications with voice and accountability latent outcome variable indicate Irish regions, Portuguese intermunicipal regions, and Japanese prefectures as the most dominant donors with nonzero weights for the full treated set. Similarly, in the rule of law specifications, the control groups are disproportionately dominated by Madeira and Azores, while with respect to government effectiveness, the control group is dominated by Azores followed by Japanese prefectures. In slight contrast, the control groups for regulatory quality specifications are characterized by the presence of Swedish counties such as Halland and Austrian federal states such as Salzburg and Burgenland. The presence of Australian states, particularly Tasmania, is also perceptible in the specifications estimating the effect of instability on the control of corruption. Taken together, this implies that preinstability latent institutional quality trajectories of Slovenian regions can be plausibly tracked and reproduced as a convex combination of attributes of regions from countries having markedly and substantially higher level of political stability after 2008, which are predominantly concentrated in the Western Europe, East Asia, North America, and Australasia.

Figure 8: 
Frequency distribution of synthetic control groups.
Figure 8:

Frequency distribution of synthetic control groups.

5.3 Placebo Analysis

The question behind our estimates that still remains unanswered is whether the estimated effects of political instability are driven by chance. To assess the significance of the estimated institutional quality gaps, we rely on the multiple-event placebo analysis proposed by Cavallo et al. (2013) based on Abadie et al. (2010) and further extended by Galiani and Quistorff (2017). In the likely absence of anticipated treatment and presence of structural break reported in Table 3, our approach is to perform a series of placebo analyses by applying the synthetic control estimator to the battery of regions in the donor pool that never underwent the treatment itself and thus never experience large-scale political instability opposed to Slovenia. If the placebo analysis creates institutional quality gaps with similar size to the ones obtained for Slovenian regions, then it is not likely that our analysis conveys evidence of the significant effect of political instability because, under such circumstances, the declining institutional quality conditions are absorbed by the general trend perceptible everywhere. By contrast, if the in-space placebo analysis uncovers evidence of unusually large institutional quality gaps of treated regions compared to the regions that did not undergo widespread political instability, then the notion of significant evidence of the negative effect of instability on institutional quality becomes more plausible. To quantitatively evaluate and assess the significance of the estimates, the synthetic control estimator is iteratively applied to every region in the donor pool, which effectively reassigns the treatment and shifts the treated regions into the donor. In the next step, the estimated effect for each outcome and each quasi-treated region is estimated through the placebo run, which yields a distribution of placebo effects.

Without the loss of generality, we follow Cavallo et al. (2013) and adopt a multi-treatment placebo framework. Let g ∈ {1, … ,G} be an index of treated regions and let J represent the number of regions that never undergo the treatment. For each treated unit, we estimate the effect of instability in the first post-treatment year denoted by λ ˆ g , 1 , T 0 + 1 . Across the full treatment set, the average effect is given by λ = G 1 ( g = 1 G λ ˆ g ) . For each treatment g, we generate the unrestricted set of placebo effects, λ g , t P l a c e b o = { λ ˆ j , t : j 1 } where each region enters the treatment at the same time as region g. By averaging λ g , t P l a c e b o over the instability treatment to obtain λ g , t P l a c e b o partially removes the noise from the estimates. This is constructed from all possible averages where a single placebo coefficient set is taken from each λ ˆ g , t P l a c e b o . Notice that there are N P l a c e b o = g = 1 J J g possible averages. To keep the placebo analysis parsimonious, we restrict the donor pool by match quality and discard placebos that do not match well to prevent the distribution from being tainted by the placebos with extreme rarity of negative instability effect. If K g m denotes the number of controls that match as well as the treated unit g for the same time period, then N P l a c e b o m = g = 1 G J g m . Furthermore, if b is the selection index where a single placebo effect is drawn from each treatment placebo set, let λ P l a c e b o ( i ) the mean of the placebo selection. Inference on the instability effect with multiple treated regions is then conducted through the following two-sided p-value:

P ( λ ˆ ) = P r o b ( | λ P l a c e b o | | λ | ) = i N P l a c e b o 1 [ | λ P l a c e b o ( i ) | | λ | ] N P l a c e b o

where we perform to basic checks on the internal validity of synthetic control estimator in approximating the counterfactual scenario. In the first step, we examine whether the treated regions attributes and characteristics fall within the convex hull of the control units. In the second step, the distribution of pretreatment RMSPEs is modified by discarding the units that have the pretreatment RMSE at least twice as high as that of the treated regions because such regions cannot be matched appropriately. Although this is not a lenient criterion, discarding the control units that fail to match well with the treated regions in pre-T0 period partially avoids overestimation of the p-value based on placebos where the relative rarity of obtaining artificially large effect with poor quality of pretreatment match is neither trivial nor low. For a total of 248 regions in the donor pool, 12 multiple-treated regions and five outcome variables, the estimated number of placebos is very large for each outcome (i.e., 1.297e+28). This implies that instead of standard treatment permutation traditionally used in smaller samples, our placebo analysis fully relies on the random sampling algorithm to obtain the sequence of p-values associated with the institutional quality effect of instability.

Table 4 presents the parametric analysis of the placebo effects through the application of difference-in-differences analysis of the estimated gaps compared to the full set of placebos. The underlying parameter of interest is the post-treatment indicators of the change in the estimated gap in comparison with the placebos. The evidence suggests that the estimated institutional quality gaps induced by political instability appear to be both large and statistically significant. For each of post-treatment gap coefficient, 95 % confidence bounds are computed. Each specification also conveys the full set of region-fixed effects and time-fixed effects to control for the confounding influence of unobserved heterogeneity bias and common time-varying shocks. The estimated gap coefficients are statistically significant at either 5 % or 1 % threshold, respectively. The largest magnitudes of the gap coefficients are found for the regulatory quality and control of corruption dimensions, while the smallest ones are found for government effectiveness and voice and accountability dimensions.

Table 4:

Parametric analysis of estimated and in-space placebo institutional quality gaps.

Voice and accountability Rule of law Government effectiveness Regulatory quality Control of corruption
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
λ 1,k = full −0.074*** (0.015) −0.094*** (0.019) −0.044** (0.019) −0.218*** (0.022) −0.174*** (0.023)

95 % confidence bounds {−0.104, −0.044} {−0.133, −0.056} {−0.082, −0.005} {−0.104, −0.044} {−0.104, −0.044}

# Observations 6500 6500 6500 6500 6500
# Regions 260 260 260 260 260
R2 0.015 0.037 0.008 0.058 0.05
# Placebo averages >12 billion >12 billion >12 billion >12 billion >12 billion
Permutation method Random sampling Random sampling Random sampling Random sampling Random sampling
Region-fixed effects (p-value) YES (0.000) YES (0.000) YES (0.000) YES (0.000) YES (0.000)
Time-fixed effects (p-value) YES (0.000) YES (0.000) YES (0.000) YES (0.000) YES (0.000)
  1. Notes: The table reports the postinstability coefficients associated with institutional quality gaps after the government crackdown in 2008. In each specification, the full set of region-fixed effects and time-fixed effects is included. Standard errors of the actual and placebo gap coefficients are adjusted for arbitrary heteroscedasticity and serially correlated stochastic disturbances using finite-sample adjustment of the empirical distribution function with the error component model. Cluster-specific standard errors are denoted in the parentheses. Asterisks denote statistically significant coefficients at 10 % (*), 5 % (**), and 1 % (***), respectively.

Figure 9 reports the intertemporal distribution of p-values associated with the institutional quality effect of political instability. The evidence indicates the embedded presence of the institutional quality breakdown triggered by the rising instability. The associated p-values are both low and relatively stable over time with two distinctive observable characteristics. First, the p-values linked with the effect of instability on voice and accountability, regulatory quality, and control of corruption are within 10 % significance threshold immediately from the initial post-treatment year onward. Without the loss of generality, this implies that political instability has triggered a bold and substantial institutional quality breakdown through the decline of liberal democracy, deteriorating quality of regulation and significantly weakened control of corruption. The negative effect of political instability on these particular quality dimensions is both immediate and apparent. And second, the p-values on the rule of law and government effectiveness dimensions appear to be initially high and gradually become low, falling well within the 10 % threshold. This implies that the negative effect of instability does not materialize immediately but tends to loom large over time in a more gradual fashion. Hence, it can be implied that the deterioration of the rule of law and government effectiveness in response to political instability appears to be time-contingent and substantially more gradual compared to the immediate negative effects on corruption, regulatory quality, and voice and accountability. Taken altogether, the evidence offers ample support for the notion of political instability leading to the institutional quality breakdown with a heterogeneous pattern across the rule of law and government effectiveness on one hand and corruption–regulation–accountability dimensions on the other hand.

Figure 9: 
Lead-specific p-values of the institutional quality effects of political instability.
Figure 9:

Lead-specific p-values of the institutional quality effects of political instability.

5.4 Discussion

Perhaps the most obvious question concerning the validity of our results concerns the mechanisms through which either gradual or permanent deterioration in the specific institutional quality indicator has materialized over time. Although a more exhaustive analysis would harness transmission mechanisms in a more rigorous quantitative manner. For the sake of data limitations, many variables capturing possible mechanisms such as public trust, fiscal spending, and pressure of interest groups cannot be constructed at the local and regional level. For this reason, a more nuanced and plausible qualitative assessment can be buttressed.

The deterioration of institutional quality can be seen through the erosion of the freedom of expression and civil liberties (De Haan and Siermann 1996), more distortionary regulation (Daude and Stein 2007), and more widespread power abuses (Damania et al. 2004) alongside a steady and more gradual erosion of the rule of law (Helmke and Rosenbluth 2009). Several possible channels of transmission can be established. First, the political instability has eroded the trust in public institutions. The assessment of trust in public institutions by OECD in 2015 has shown that Slovenia has had the lowest level of trust in both political and legal system in the OECD together with Portugal, Greece, and Spain.[10] By eroding trust in public institutions, political instability has decimated the confidence of citizens and firms in the institutional framework, curtailed government integrity, further weakening the institutional fabric, which has first-order implications for both quality and economic outcomes such as per capita income, total factor productivity, innovation, and unemployment, among several others.

Second, the onset of political instability has exacerbated the institutional backsliding that is perhaps best exemplified by the deterioration of economic freedom.[11] Country-level assessment of economic freedom by Kim (2023) suggests that the level of economic freedom in Slovenia after the beginning of political instability has consistently declined. The estimated drop in the Heritage Foundation’s economic freedom index between 2009 and 2017 is around 5 basis point, which represents the largest deterioration among OECD member states. The largest drop has been was observed with respect to the integrity of government administration and tax burden. Similar evidence of deterioration of the quality of economic institutions is reported in Fraser’s index of economic freedom (Gwartney et al. 2022). In response to political instability, prolonged worsening of economic institutions has led to stalled economic and structural reforms associated with austerity measures after the economic and financial crisis, which have been repeatedly resisted and blocked by powerful interest groups, positing a source of coordinated disruption and other less institutional forms of policy influence (Scartascini and Tommasi 2012) that appear costly to economic growth, R&D, innovation and creative destruction (Aghion and Howitt 1992). The decline in government integrity further worsened both fiscal health and stability. Prior to the political instability, Slovenia has maintained both relatively balanced budget without continued deficit spending and one of the public debt-to-GDP ratios in the OECD. In particular, the share of public debt in GDP increased from 21 % in 2008 to 82 % in 2015, respectively, while government net borrowing spiraled from a balanced budget in 2007 into the fiscal deficit of 14 % of GDP in 2015.

A combination of soaring public debt and prolonged deficit-based spending proved costly to economic growth and macroeconomic stability (Rodrik 2018), especially in the presence of weak and unstable political environment. It reflected the sizeable losses of economic growth and institutional quality emanating from the institutional environment based on clientelistic networks and dominated by small elites and widespread cronyism in various branches of government and public sector, especially public procurement, health care, as well as across the private sector where the interplay between widespread state ownership and interference has been particularly pervasive. Political instability also eroded the incentives for institutional reforms and modernization. The gridlock imposed by the weak and unstable political environment has been particularly noteworthy in the judiciary. A series of reports by World Bank’s Doing Business projects emphasized long and cumbersome judicial delays as one of the major stumbling blocks against private sector development. In particular, together Italy and Cyprus, Slovenia’s judiciary has been characterized by long delays that have consistently exceeded 1000 days. Alternative estimates by Council of Europe’s European Commission for the Efficiency of Justice (CEPEJ) also indicate and confirm long judicial delays in Slovenia’s judiciary as one of the highest ones in Europe. The erosion of judicial efficiency further reinforced a vicious cycle of low public trust in the judiciary, increased transaction costs, and ameliorated the resistance to institutional reform by powerful interest groups in the judiciary. In turn, the interplay between deteriorating economic conditions and worsening judicial effectiveness in the presence of political instability and low social trust increased the demand for regulation, taxes, and redistribution (Alesina and Giavazzi 2008).

The increased demand for over-regulation and state interference (Gratton et al. 2021) posited a series of major disincentives to innovate and engage in various other forms of productive behavior. By increasing the demand for regulation, taxes, and redistribution, political instability further amplified the power of vested interest groups by incentivizing powerful actors, particularly labor unions and public sector employees to resist regulatory and institutional reforms, austerity measures, and privatization of state-owned enterprises through coordinated disruption, lobbying, influence peddling, and other forms of entry barriers (Parente and Prescott 2002). It should be noted that at the height of political crisis and gridlock, state-owned enterprises’ share of employment represented almost 10 % of overall employment, one of the highest ratios among OECD member states.

Furthermore, the increased demand for regulation and redistribution encouraged a deep co-optation between the economic and political elites where the hostility and aversion toward the reforms became a mode of political survival and ignited social conflict (Ippolito and Cicatiello 2019). The hostility toward reforms raised the overall cost of doing business, leading to a disproportionate drop of foreign direct investment, which prolonged both the length and severity of the economic downturn (Kim 2010). By inducing a permanent institutional sclerosis, political instability further eroded both medium-term and long-term fiscal sustainability, worsening adverse demographic pressures arising from rapidly aging population and high implicit liabilities of the pension system (Röth et al. 2018). At the same time, the political consequences of instability should not be neglected (Guriev 2018). A vicious cycle between political instability and deteriorating economic conditions fueled the demand for both right-wing and left-wing populism (Boeri et al. 2021), leading to the runoff victory of euroskeptic and right-wing Slovenian Democratic Party in 2020 (Taggart and Pirro 2021). Hence, instability helped to erode institutional quality particularly through the erosion of postmodern cosmopolitan liberal values (Beugelsdijk et al. 2022), increased political polarization, and undermined social cohesion coupled with distrust in science and less effective combat of COVID19 pandemic (Algan et al. 2021) that proved costly not only to institutional quality but also to human capital accumulation, talent acquisition, research and development, public health, and economic growth.

6 Conclusions

In this paper, we examine the effect of political instability on institutional quality. To this end, we exploit the crackdown of government cabinet in 2008 that led to almost two decades of pervasive political instability using the unique case of Slovenia and estimate the average treatment effect of political instability and the missing counterfactual scenario for the period 1996–2020. We construct novel estimates of institutional quality at the subnational level for a sample of regions and a full-cross section of Slovenian regions and municipalities. By adopting the residual component approach to measure institutional quality (Magnusson and Tarverdi 2020), we estimate the residual score of institutional quality from the variation in plausibly exogenous geographic characteristics in repeated cross sections using Bayesian approach through Monte Carlo Markov Chain (MCMC) sampling method with Metropolis–Hastings algorithm. More specifically, we perform around 1,500,000 million random sequences of samples, decompose the latent residual institutional quality score for each year into deterministic and stochastic components, and smooth the latent series using Hodrick–Prescott filtering technique (Ravn and Uhlig 2002). By comparing the trajectory of institutional quality within and across the treated regions and municipalities, we examine the relationship between political instability and institutional quality in greater detail.

While the notion of negative economic growth effects of political instability has received widely acclaimed support in the literature, the relationship between quality and instability has received relatively little attention in the literature. Some scholars argue that political instability debilitates institutional quality through greater insecurity of property rights and higher transaction costs. Yet, others argue that some political instability might be a necessary condition to break the status quo and implement institutional and policy reforms that allow for flexible adjustment to a series of external and internal shocks. Our difference-in-differences and synthetic control estimates provide no evidence of institutional quality-enhancing effect of political instability. A wide range of estimates suggests that political instability debilitates political accountability, restricts the freedom of the press, decreases government effectiveness, weakens the rule of law, renders regulatory quality downward, and deteriorates the control of corruption substantially. Our evidence based on difference-in-differences with two-way fixed estimator of the treatment effect (De Chaismartin and D’Haultfoeuille 2020) suggests that at the local level, political instability has a somewhat beneficial effect on the regulatory quality and improves the ability of local governments to formulate and implement sound economic and structural policies and regulation that promotes private sector development. At the same time, political instability deteriorates the rule of law, widens the opportunities for corrupt behavior, renders local government administration less effective, and holds local political elites less accountable, suggesting that institutional quality costs substantially outweigh the minor benefits thereof.

Our synthetic control estimates of the instability effect at the regional level indicate even more pervasive drop of institutional quality. Compared to a sample of 468 regions with a high degree of political stability, our evidence suggests that political instability tends to have a debilitating effect on institutional quality, resulting in widespread corruption, weaker rule of law, lower quality of regulation, and substantially less effective functioning of government. Thus, the evidence lends no support to the thesis of institutional quality-enhancing effect of political instability. Compared to the synthetic control groups, the regional trajectories of institutional qualities tend to undergo an institutional breakdown with clear signs of permanent deterioration, which suggests that political instability may be a door opener to the rise of illiberal democracy. The estimated negative effects of political instability are robust to a variety of placebo checks where more than 12 billion placebo averages are computed for each outcome variable using random sampling method of treatment permutation.

From a general perspective, our research contributes to the scholarly debate on the implications, causes, and consequences of political instability by estimating the effects of instability at the subnational level using Bayesian analytical approach to measure institutional quality with random sampling sequences and posterior distributions. The advantage of our approach is that compared to cross-country analyses, many factors that affect institutional quality such as culture and historical differences can be held reasonably fixed in identifying the effect of instability. More specifically, we show that political instability incurs a costly deterioration of institutional quality that does not seem to recover. Extending the proposed approach to other subnational contexts appears to be the first necessary step to tackle the external validity of our approach. Nevertheless, exploring the nexus between political instability and economic outcomes, labor market outcomes and human capital differences at the local levels comprise a fruitful area for future research.


Corresponding author: Rok Spruk, Associate Professor of Economics, School of Economics and Business, University of Ljubljana, Kardeljeva Ploscad 17, SI-1000 Ljubljana, Slovenia, E-mail:

The authors would like to thank the participants of 39th Annual Conference of European Association of Law and Economics (Nova School, Lisbon), 16th International Symposium on Econometric Theory and Applications (Yonsei University, Seoul), 2022 COMPIE Conference (University of Mannheim), and 33rd Annual Conference of Italian Public Economics Society (University of Bari) for comments, feedback, and suggestions on the earlier draft version of the manuscript.


References

Abadie, A. (2021). Using synthetic controls: feasibility, data requirements, and methodological aspects. J. Econ. Lit. 59: 391–425, https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.20191450.Search in Google Scholar

Abadie, A. and Gardeazabal, J. (2003). The economic costs of conflict: a case study of the Basque Country. Am. Econ. Rev. 93: 113–132, https://doi.org/10.1257/000282803321455188.Search in Google Scholar

Abadie, A. and Imbens, G.W. (2006). Large sample properties of matching estimators for average treatment effects. Econometrica 74: 235–267, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00655.x.Search in Google Scholar

Abadie, A., Diamond, A., and Hainmueller, J. (2010). Synthetic control methods for comparative case studies: estimating the effect of California’s tobacco control program. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 105: 493–505, https://doi.org/10.1198/jasa.2009.ap08746.Search in Google Scholar

Abadie, A., Diamond, A., and Hainmueller, J. (2015). Comparative politics and the synthetic control method. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 59: 495–510, https://doi.org/10.1111/ajps.12116.Search in Google Scholar

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., and Robinson, J.A. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation. Am. Econ. Rev. 91: 1369–1401, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.91.5.1369.Search in Google Scholar

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., and Robinson, J.A. (2002). Reversal of fortune: geography and institutions in the making of the modern world income distribution. Q. J. Econ. 117: 1231–1294, https://doi.org/10.1162/003355302320935025.Search in Google Scholar

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Kermani, A., Kwak, J., and Mitton, T. (2016). The value of connections in turbulent times: evidence from the United States. J. Financ. Econ. 121: 368–391, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2015.10.001.Search in Google Scholar

Ades, A. and Chua, H.B. (1997). Thy neighbor’s curse: regional instability and economic growth. J. Econ. Growth 2: 279–304, https://doi.org/10.1023/a:1009782809329.10.1023/A:1009782809329Search in Google Scholar

Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60: 323–351, https://doi.org/10.2307/2951599.Search in Google Scholar

Aisen, A. and Veiga, F.J. (2006). Does political instability lead to higher inflation? A panel data analysis. J. Money Credit Bank. 38: 1379–1389, https://doi.org/10.1353/mcb.2006.0064.Search in Google Scholar

Aisen, A. and Veiga, F.J. (2008). Political instability and inflation volatility. Publ. Choice 135: 207–223, https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-007-9254-x.Search in Google Scholar

Aisen, A. and Veiga, F.J. (2013). How does political instability affect economic growth? Eur. J. Polit. Econ. 29: 151–167, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2012.11.001.Search in Google Scholar

Alberola, E. and Urrutia, C. (2020). Does informality facilitate inflation stability? J. Dev. Econ. 146: 1–27, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2020.102505.Search in Google Scholar

Alesina, A., Özler, S., Roubini, N., and Swagel, P. (1996). Political instability and economic growth. J. Econ. Growth 1: 189–211, https://doi.org/10.1007/bf00138862.Search in Google Scholar

Alesina, A. and Tabellini, G. (1989). External debt, capital flight and political risk. J. Int. Econ. 27: 199–220, https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-1996(89)90052-4.Search in Google Scholar

Alesina, A. and Perotti, R. (1996). Income distribution, political instability, and investment. Eur. Econ. Rev. 40: 1203–1228, https://doi.org/10.1016/0014-2921(95)00030-5.Search in Google Scholar

Alesina, A. and Giavazzi, F. (2008). The future of Europe: reform or decline. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Search in Google Scholar

Algan, Y., Cohen, D., Davoine, E., Foucault, M., and Stantcheva, S. (2021). Trust in scientists in times of pandemic: panel evidence from 12 countries. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 118 (40): 1–8, https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.2108576118.Search in Google Scholar

Asteriou, D. and Price, S. (2001). Political instability and economic growth: UK time series evidence. Scot. J. Polit. Econ. 48: 383–399, https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9485.00205.Search in Google Scholar

Azzimonti, M. (2011). Barriers to investment in polarized societies. Am. Econ. Rev. 101: 2182–2204, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.101.5.2182.Search in Google Scholar

Barro, R.J. (1991). Economic growth in a cross section of countries. Q. J. Econ. 106: 407–443, https://doi.org/10.2307/2937943.Search in Google Scholar

Beck, H.E., Zimmermann, N.E., McVicar, T.R., Vergopolan, N., Berg, A., and Wood, E.F. (2018). Present and future Köppen-Geiger climate classification maps at 1-km resolution. Sci. Data 5: 1–12, https://doi.org/10.1038/sdata.2018.214.Search in Google Scholar

Benhabib, J. and Spiegel, M.M. (1994). The role of human capital in economic development evidence from aggregate cross-country data. J. Monetary Econ. 34: 143–173, https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(94)90047-7.Search in Google Scholar

Ben-Michael, E., Feller, A., and Rothstein, J. (2021). The augmented synthetic control method. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 116: 1789–1803, https://doi.org/10.1080/01621459.2021.1929245.Search in Google Scholar

Berggren, N., Bergh, A., and Bjørnskov, C. (2012). The growth effects of institutional instability. J. Inst. Econ. 8: 187–224, https://doi.org/10.1017/s1744137411000488.Search in Google Scholar

Beugelsdijk, S., van Herk, H., and Maseland, R. (2022). The nature of societal conflict in Europe; an Archetypal analysis of the postmodern cosmopolitan, rural traditionalist and Urban precariat. J. Commun. Media Stud.: J. Common. Mark. Stud. 60: 1701–1722, https://doi.org/10.1111/jcms.13342.Search in Google Scholar

Billmeier, A. and Nannicini, T. (2013). Assessing economic liberalization episodes: a synthetic control approach. Rev. Econ. Stat. 95: 983–1001, https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_00324.Search in Google Scholar

Boeri, T., Mishra, P., Papageorgiou, C., and Spilimbergo, A. (2021). Populism and civil society. Economica 88: 863–895, https://doi.org/10.1111/ecca.12374.Search in Google Scholar

Campos, N.F., Karanasos, M.G., and Tan, B. (2012). Two to tangle: financial development, political instability and economic growth in Argentina. J. Bank. Finance 36: 290–304, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2011.07.011.Search in Google Scholar

Caporale, T. and Leirer, J. (2010). Take the money and run: political turnover, rent-seeking and economic growth. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 76: 406–412, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2010.07.005.Search in Google Scholar

Carmignani, F. (2003). Political instability, uncertainty and economics. J. Econ. Surv. 17: 1–54, https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-6419.00187.Search in Google Scholar

Cattaneo, M.D., Feng, Y., and Titiunik, R. (2021). Prediction intervals for synthetic control methods. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 116: 1865–1880, https://doi.org/10.1080/01621459.2021.1979561.Search in Google Scholar

Cavallo, E., Galiani, S., Noy, I., and Pantano, J. (2013). Catastrophic natural disasters and economic growth. Rev. Econ. Stat. 95: 1549–1561, https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_00413.Search in Google Scholar

Chow, G.C. (1960). Tests of equality between sets of coefficients in two linear regressions. Econometrica 28: 591–605, https://doi.org/10.2307/1910133.Search in Google Scholar

Collins, S.M. (1996). On becoming more flexible: exchange rate regimes in Latin America and the Caribbean. J. Dev. Econ. 51: 117–138, https://doi.org/10.1016/s0304-3878(96)00428-2.Search in Google Scholar

Cukierman, A. (1992). Central Bank strategy, credibility, and independence: theory and evidence. J. Econ. Etudes Hum. 3: 581–590.10.1515/jeeh-1992-0410Search in Google Scholar

Cukierman, A., Web, S.B., and Neyapti, B. (1992). Measuring the independence of central banks and its effect on policy outcomes. World Bank Econ. Rev. 6: 353–398, https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/6.3.353.Search in Google Scholar

Cukierman, A. and Webb, S.B. (1995). Political influence on the central bank: international evidence. World Bank Econ. Rev. 9: 397–423, https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/9.3.397.Search in Google Scholar

Damania, R., Fredriksson, P.G., and Mani, M. (2004). The persistence of corruption and regulatory compliance failures: theory and evidence. Publ. Choice 121: 363–390, https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-004-1684-0.Search in Google Scholar

Daude, C. and Stein, E. (2007). The quality of institutions and foreign direct investment. Econ. Polit. 19: 317–344, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0343.2007.00318.x.Search in Google Scholar

De Chaisemartin, C. and d’Haultfoeuille, X. (2020). Two-way fixed effects estimators with heterogeneous treatment effects. Am. Econ. Rev. 110: 2964–2996, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20181169.Search in Google Scholar

De Haan, J. and Siermann, C.L. (1996). Political instability, freedom, and economic growth: some further evidence. Econ. Dev. Cult. Change 44: 339–350, https://doi.org/10.1086/452217.Search in Google Scholar

Deveraux, M.B and Wen, J.F (1998). Political instability, capital taxation, and growth. Eur. Econ. Rev. 42: 1635–1651, https://doi.org/10.1016/S0014-2921(97)00100-1.Search in Google Scholar

Docquier, F., Lohest, O., and Marfouk, A. (2007). Brain drain in developing countries. World Bank Econ. Rev. 21: 193–218, https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/lhm008.Search in Google Scholar

Firpo, S. and Possebom, V. (2018). Synthetic control method: inference, sensitivity analysis and confidence sets. J. Causal Inference 6: 1–35, https://doi.org/10.1515/jci-2016-0026.Search in Google Scholar

Galiani, S. and Quistorff, B. (2017). The synth_runner package: utilities to automate synthetic control estimation using synth. STATA J. 17: 834–849, https://doi.org/10.1177/1536867x1801700404.Search in Google Scholar

Gates, S., Hegre, H., Jones, M.P., and Strand, H. (2006). Institutional inconsistency and political instability: polity duration, 1800–2000. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 50: 893–908, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5907.2006.00222.x.Search in Google Scholar

Gobillon, L. and Magnac, T. (2016). Regional policy evaluation: interactive fixed effects and synthetic controls. Rev. Econ. Stat. 98: 535–551, https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_00537.Search in Google Scholar

Gratton, G., Guiso, L., Michelacci, C., and Morelli, M. (2021). From Weber to Kafka: political instability and the overproduction of laws. Am. Econ. Rev. 111: 2964–3003, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20190672.Search in Google Scholar

Guriev, S. (2018). Economic drivers of populism. Am. Econ. Rev., Pap. Proc. 108: 200–203, https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20181123.Search in Google Scholar

Gwartney, J., Lawson, R., Hall, J., Murphy, R., Djankov, S., and McMahon, F. (2022). Economic freedom of the world: 2022 annual report. Fraser Institute, Vancouver, BC.10.53095/88975001Search in Google Scholar

Hartmann, S. and Spruk, R. (2021). Long-term effects of institutional instability. Empir. Econ. 61: 2073–2112, https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-020-01934-z.Search in Google Scholar

Hastings, W.K. (1970). Monte Carlo sampling methods using Markov chains and their applications. Biometrika 57: 97–109, https://doi.org/10.1093/biomet/57.1.97.Search in Google Scholar

Helmke, G. and Rosenbluth, F. (2009). Regimes and the rule of law: judicial independence in comparative perspective. Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 12: 345–366, https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.polisci.12.040907.121521.Search in Google Scholar

Hodrick, R.J. and Prescott, E.C. (1997). Postwar US business cycles: an empirical investigation. J. Money Credit Bank 29: 1–16, https://doi.org/10.2307/2953682.Search in Google Scholar

Ippolito, M. and Cicatiello, L. (2019). Political instability, economic inequality and social conflict: the case in Italy. Panoeconomicus 66: 365–383, https://doi.org/10.2298/pan1903365i.Search in Google Scholar

Jarner, S.F. and Roberts, G.O. (2007). Convergence of heavy‐tailed Monte Carlo Markov chain algorithms. Scand. J. Stat. 34: 781–815, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9469.2007.00557.x.Search in Google Scholar

Jeffreys, H. (1946). An invariant form for the prior probability in estimation problems. Proc. Roy. Soc. Lond. Math. Phys. Sci. 186 (1007): 453–461, https://doi.org/10.1098/rspa.1946.0056.Search in Google Scholar

Jong-A-Pin, R. (2009). On the measurement of political instability and its impact on economic growth. Eur. J. Polit. Econ. 25: 15–29, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2008.09.010.Search in Google Scholar

Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., and Mastruzzi, M. (2011). The worldwide governance indicators: methodology and analytical issues1. Hague J Rule Law 3: 220–246, https://doi.org/10.1017/s1876404511200046.Search in Google Scholar

Keefer, P. and Knack, S. (2002). Polarization, politics and property rights: links between inequality and growth. Publ. Choice 111: 127–154, https://doi.org/10.1023/a:1015168000336.10.1023/A:1015168000336Search in Google Scholar

Kim, H. (2010). Political stability and foreign direct investment. Int. J. Econ. Finance 2: 59–71, https://doi.org/10.5539/ijef.v2n3p59.Search in Google Scholar

Kim, A.B. (2023). Index of economic freedom. Heritage Foundation, Washington, DC.Search in Google Scholar

Lucifora, C. and Moriconi, S. (2015). Political instability and labour market institutions. Eur. J. Polit. Econ. 39: 201–221, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2015.05.003.Search in Google Scholar

Magnusson, L.M. and Tarverdi, Y. (2020). Measuring governance: why do errors matter? World Dev. 136: 1–16, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2020.105061.Search in Google Scholar

Metropolis, N., Rosenbluth, A.W., Rosenbluth, M.N., Teller, A.H., and Teller, E. (1953). Equation of state calculations by fast computing machines. J. Chem. Phys. 21: 1087–1092, https://doi.org/10.1063/1.1699114.Search in Google Scholar

Muralidharan, K. and Prakash, N. (2017). Cycling to school: increasing secondary school enrollment for girls in India. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 9: 321–350, https://doi.org/10.1257/app.20160004.Search in Google Scholar

North, D.C. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. Norton, New York, NY.Search in Google Scholar

North, D.C. (2005). Understanding the Process of economic change. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.10.1515/9781400829484Search in Google Scholar

Olson, M. (1963). Rapid growth as a destabilizing force. J. Econ. Hist. 23: 529–552, https://doi.org/10.1017/s0022050700109210.Search in Google Scholar

Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations: economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. Yale University Press, New Haven, CT.Search in Google Scholar

Özler, Ş. and Rodrik, D. (1992). External shocks, politics and private investment: some theory and empirical evidence. J. Dev. Econ. 39: 141–162, https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3878(92)90060-m.Search in Google Scholar

Parente, S.L. and Prescott, E.C. (2002). Barriers to riches. MIT press, Cambridge, MA.Search in Google Scholar

Powell, D. (2022). Synthetic control estimation beyond comparative case studies: does the minimum wage reduce employment? J. Bus. Econ. Stat. 40: 1302–1314, https://doi.org/10.1080/07350015.2021.1927743.Search in Google Scholar

Ravn, M.O. and Uhlig, H. (2002). On adjusting the Hodrick–Prescott filter for the frequency of observations. Rev. Econ. Stat. 84: 371–376, https://doi.org/10.1162/003465302317411604.Search in Google Scholar

Rodrik, D. (2018). Is populism necessarily bad economics? Am. Econ. Rev., Pap. Proc. 108: 196–199, https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20181122.Search in Google Scholar

Roe, M.J. and Siegel, J.I. (2011). Political instability: effects on financial development, roots in the severity of economic inequality. J. Comp. Econ. 39: 279–309, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2011.02.001.Search in Google Scholar

Roubini, N. (1991). Economic and political determinants of budget deficits in developing countries. J. Int. Money Finance 10: S49–S72, https://doi.org/10.1016/0261-5606(91)90046-m.Search in Google Scholar

Röth, L., Afonso, A., and Spies, D.C. (2018). The impact of populist radical right parties on socio-economic policies. Eur. Polit. Sci. Rev. 10: 325–350, https://doi.org/10.1017/s1755773917000133.Search in Google Scholar

Scartascini, C. and Tommasi, M. (2012). The making of policy: institutionalized or not? Am. J. Polit. Sci. 56: 787–801, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5907.2012.00591.x.Search in Google Scholar

Spruk, R. and Kovac, M. (2020). Does a ban on trans fats improve public health: synthetic control evidence from Denmark. Swiss J. Econ. Stat. 156: 1–32, https://doi.org/10.1186/s41937-019-0048-0.Search in Google Scholar

Svensson, J. (1998). Investment, property rights and political instability: theory and evidence. Eur. Econ. Rev. 42: 1317–1341, https://doi.org/10.1016/s0014-2921(97)00081-0.Search in Google Scholar

Taggart, P. and Pirro, A.L. (2021). European populism before the pandemic: ideology, Euroscepticism, electoral performance, and government participation of 63 parties in 30 countries. Ital. Polit. Sci. Rev. 51: 281–304, https://doi.org/10.1017/ipo.2021.13.Search in Google Scholar

Xu, Y. (2017). Generalized synthetic control method: causal inference with interactive fixed effects models. Polit. Anal. 25: 57–76, https://doi.org/10.1017/pan.2016.2.Search in Google Scholar

Received: 2022-12-22
Accepted: 2023-07-27
Published Online: 2023-09-05
Published in Print: 2023-12-15

© 2023 the author(s), published by De Gruyter, Berlin/Boston

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.

Downloaded on 19.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/jbnst-2022-0074/html
Scroll to top button