Startseite The Economics of GM Labeling and Implications for Trade
Artikel
Lizenziert
Nicht lizenziert Erfordert eine Authentifizierung

The Economics of GM Labeling and Implications for Trade

  • Jill J. McCluskey und Jason Winfree EMAIL logo
Veröffentlicht/Copyright: 7. April 2017

Abstract

In this article, we model the effects of both voluntary and mandatory genetically modified (GM) food labeling on profits and consumer welfare. The non-GM firms weakly benefit from having the option to voluntarily label their product and will increase their quantities produced if labeling makes their non-GM product more valuable to consumers relative to the increased costs of labeling. GM producers make lower profits when non-GM firms voluntarily label because of increase in non-GM firms production. Mandatory labeling can be a different scenario. Costs of mandatory labeling are borne by the GM producers, and the benefits are reaped by the non-GM producers as it differentiates their product. We also consider the possibility that consumers will view the mandatory GM labels as a warning, such as a mandatory health label on cigarettes. The combination of increased costs along with decreased willingness to pay could be damaging to GM producers. The level of consumer concern about consuming GM food greatly affects the impact of labeling policies. Coordination of policies for a trade agreement will have different effects depending on consumer risk perceptions in that country and the number of GM firms.

JEL Classification: Q16; F13

References

Center for Food Safety. Genetically Engineered Food Labeling Laws. 2015 Accessed November 4, 2015. http://www.centerforfoodsafety.org/ge-map/.Suche in Google Scholar

Crespi, J.M., and S. Marette. 2003. “‘Does Contain’ vs. ‘Does Not Contain’: How Should GMO Labeling Be Promoted?” European Journal of Law and Economics 16: 327–344.10.1023/A:1025362808108Suche in Google Scholar

Curtis, K.R., J.J. McCluskey, and J.F.M. Swinnen. 2008. “Differences in Global Risk Perceptions of Biotechnology and the Political Economy of the Media.” International Journal of Global Environmental Issues 8 (1&2): 77–89.10.1504/IJGENVI.2008.017261Suche in Google Scholar

Fulton, M., and K. Giannakas. 2004. “Inserting GM Products into the Food Chain: The Market and Welfare Effects of Different Labeling and Regulatory Regimes.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86 (1): 42–61.10.1111/j.0092-5853.2004.00561.xSuche in Google Scholar

Giannakas, K., and A. Yiannaka. 2008. “Market and Welfare Effects of Second-Generation, Consumer-Oriented GM Products.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 90 (1): 152–171.10.1111/j.1467-8276.2007.01053.xSuche in Google Scholar

Huffman, W.A., and J.J. McCluskey. 2014. “The Economics of Labeling GM Foods.” AgBioForum 17 (2): 156–160.Suche in Google Scholar

Lapan, H., and G. Moschini. 2004. “Innovation and Trade with Endogenous Market Failure: The Case of Genetically Modified Products.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86 (3): 634–648.10.1111/j.0002-9092.2004.00606.xSuche in Google Scholar

Lapan, H., and G. Moschini. 2007. “Grading, Minimum Quality Standards, and the Labeling of Genetically Modified Products.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 89 (3): 769–783.10.1111/j.1467-8276.2007.01002.xSuche in Google Scholar

National Academies of Science. 2016. Genetically Engineered Crops: Experiences and Prospects Washington, DC: National Academies Press.Suche in Google Scholar

Salop, S.C., and D.T. Scheffman. 1983. “Raising Rivals’ Costs.” American Economic Review 73: 267–271.Suche in Google Scholar

Zilberman, D. Lessons from Prop 37 and the Future of Genetic Engineering in Agriculture. The Berkeley Blog, Energy and Environment 2012 Accessed December 20, 2012. http://blogs.berkeley.edu/2012/12/20/lessons-from-prop-37-and-the-future-of-genetic-engineering-in-agriculture/.Suche in Google Scholar

Appendix

To find the marginal effect of labeling on welfare, we differentiate eq. 13such that

dWdL=daNdLdcNdLQN+aNcNdQNdL+daGMdLdcGMdLQGM+aGMcGMdQGMdLb1QNdQNdLb1QGMdQGMdLb2QNdQGMdLb2QGMdQNdL

We note that dcGMdL=0, but we include it here due to the similarity in the math between voluntary and mandatory labeling. Substituing eqs 5and 6), gives us,

dWdL=daNdLdcNdLQN+daGMdLdcGMdLQGM+b1qNdQNdLb1qGMdQGMdL

Using eqs 9and 10gives us,

dWdL=daNdLdcNdLQNφ+b12NGM+1b1b2QGMNN+daGMdLQGMφ+b12NN+1b1b2QNNGMφ

The effects of mandatory labeling on welfare are found similarly to the effects of voluntary labeling.

Published Online: 2017-4-7

© 2017 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Heruntergeladen am 8.10.2025 von https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/jafio-2016-0017/html
Button zum nach oben scrollen