Home Proportionality in the European Banking Law.Lessons from Silicon Valley Bank
Article Open Access

Proportionality in the European Banking Law.Lessons from Silicon Valley Bank

  • Matteo Arrigoni EMAIL logo and Enrico Rino Restelli
Published/Copyright: February 26, 2024

Abstract

936European prudential regulation imposes significant compliance costs on banks, justifying extensive use of proportionality. However, the failure of Silicon Valley Bank raised numerous objections to this approach. According to many scholars and practitioners, the crisis of SBV originated from a substantial loosening of the regulatory standards and the corresponding supervisory enforcement. In this context, the article discusses the intricate relations between proportionality and financial stability, reaching an articulated conclusion. While concerning prudential capital requirements it seems reasonable to adopt a uniform discipline, as to supervision (e. g., SREP), a proportional approach seems more appropriate. At the same time, the failure of SVB advocates in favor of a partly different approach toward corporate governance.

1. Banking Regulation and Proportionality After Silicon Valley Bank

Banking law is usually characterized by a highly articulated prudential regulation, primarily aimed at containing the spread of negative externalities and limiting the systemic effects generally associated with bank failures.[1] Such rules, however, entail relevant compliance costs, penalizing smaller intermediaries (who often lack adequate economies of scale)[2] and incentivizing market concentration.[3]

For this reason, both banks and supervisors are required to adjust regulatory prescriptions proportionally,[4] according to the general principle outlined in Articles 5(4) TEU and 69 TFEU.[5] Nonetheless, with the so-called ‘CRD V package’, the European regulator has sought to better mitigate the incidence of the aforementioned regulatory costs by introducing a special discipline for “small and non-complex institutions” compared to that for “large institutions” (respectively, art. 4(1)(145) and (146), CRR). In particular, according to this new regulatory scheme, these institutions can benefit from simplified transparency and reporting requirements (art. 433b and arts. 415 and 430 CRR, respectively), while art. 97(4) CRD IV provides for a lighter supervisory regime, re938quiring competent authorities to proportionate “the frequency and intensity” of SREPs with the size, nature, and risks concretely posed by each bank’s business.[6] At the same time, small and non-complex institutions can use a “simplified standardized methodology” to evaluate the risks arising from their non-trading book activities, although independent authorities may decide otherwise (art. 84(1)(4)(5) CRD IV).

Indeed, the ECB Supervisory Board recently made a case for a broader use of its discretionary powers “to enable supervisors to plan their activities in a more flexible way, in accordance with a multi-year SREP. This approach will allow supervisors to better calibrate the intensity and frequency of their analyses, in line with the individual bank’s vulnerability and broader supervisory priorities. This will also streamline the supervisory activities in a proportionate and risk-based manner, as [they] wouldn’t tick all the boxes every year. As a result, we expect a reduced burden for the banks too”.[7]

Against this background – in order to amend some loopholes related to the application of the principle of proportionality for banking groups[8] – the European Parliament has also recently proposed to amend Article 97(4) CRD IV to require supervisors to differentiate the exercise of ‘group SREPs’ according to (i) the possible mutualistic nature of member banks, as well as (ii) their individual qualification as small and non-complex institutions.[9]

In this context, though, the European approach to proportionality was recently challenged by the crisis of Silicon Valley Bank (SVB), a California-based depository institution specialized in financing technology start-ups and venture capital. As a matter of fact, the failure of SVB is generally attributed to some “regulatory failures” that led to a substantial loosening of prudential regulation and supervision.[10] Indeed, in 2018, U. S. banking law was extensively 939reformed precisely to mitigate the impact of the main regulatory costs on smaller banks.[11] However – it has been observed – “with the rollback of several key Dodd-Frank provisions, [and] the introduction of several easing requirements and lighter oversight for midsize banks ..., regulators have not supervised these banks sufficiently”.[12] Critics honed in on the loosening of liquidity requirements and capital discipline,[13] but also (and perhaps mostly) the introduction of ‘lighter’ supervisory practices.[14]

All these drawbacks – along with the magnitude of the consequences the crisis of SVB generated – cast some doubt over the desirability of further strengthening the application of the proportionality principle in the European legal system, and emphasise the dangers potentially associated with the weakening of supervision and prudential regulation.[15]

Against this backdrop, the present paper discusses potential lessons to be learned from the SVB failure. After briefly summarising the events that brought to the collapse of SVB, Section 2 and 3 will discuss the aforementioned regulatory fail940ures to assess the actual fitness of EU prudential regulation. Section 4, then, will address the issues related to supervision to investigate the soundness of the reforms currently proposed by the European Parliament. Lastly, Section 5 will debate the problems arising from the increasing use of supervisory discretion to cope with the new risks highlighted by the failure of SVB. Section 6 concludes.

2. The Loosening of the U. S. Prudential Regulation and the Overall Architecture of the European Banking System

During the pandemic, due to the favourable market conditions experienced by tech start-ups, SVB tripled its deposits collection.[16] In the absence of alternative solutions, SVB invested the resulting liquidity in buying (low interest rate-bearing) Treasury bonds and other financial instruments with long maturities to profit on the associated interest margin.[17] However, the progressive tightening of monetary policy caused a sudden devaluation of these investments,[18] just as the bank’s customers had begun to withdraw their deposits to cope with the rising cost of money and changing market conditions.[19]

Facing a severe liquidity problem, SVB was then forced to sell these assets at a steep discount and suffered a $1.8 billion loss which prompted the bank to approve a substantial capital increase (amounting to $2.25 billion).[20] Such 941events, however, made investors fully aware of the difficulties that SVB was experiencing, triggering a large ‘bank run’.[21] Indeed – according to SVB’s own estimates[22] – the guarantee provided by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) did not cover as much as 96 percent of the overall deposits, directly exposing these customers to the consequences of possible insolvency.

In order to curb the spreading of negative externalities throughout the entire financial system, on March 10, 2023, SVB was declared insolvent and the FDIC assumed control of the bank.[23] In this context, the FDIC recurred also to the “systemic risk exception” provided by 12 U. S.C. § 1823(c)(4)(G) in order to bail out all SVB depositors and prevent negative spillovers (as a general rule, in the U. S., such a guarantee is limited only to deposits up to $250,000).[24] On March 27, 2023, First Citizens Bank purchased SVB.[25]

2.1. The Impact of Liquidity and Capital Requirements in the SVB Failure

As already mentioned, one of the most controversial issues in the SVB crisis concerned the waivers to the Liquidity Coverage Ratio (LCR) and Net Stable Funding Ratio (NSFR) requirements devised by the 2018 reform in favour of smaller U. S. banks. Indeed, the institutions with consolidated assets of less than $250 billion and wholesale weighted short-term funding of 942less than $50 billion were fully exempted from the application of these provisions.[26]

Such amendments were highly criticized, because “bank insolvency is ... usually triggered by illiquidity”, often generated by the difficulty of coping with sudden asset depreciation and subsequent deposit withdrawal.[27] This was true also for SVB failure. Indeed, according to official estimates, such exemption allowed SVB to drastically reduce its short-term liquidity requirements (LCR) and set aside high-quality liquid assets (HQLA) of just 82.6 percent of the net cash flows needed to cope with adverse market conditions over a 30-day time horizon[28]. In this regard – as assessed by other studies – to align with the average of the U. S. banking industry (i.e., 125%), SVB would have had to set aside HQLA for an additional $36 billion.[29]

Most strikingly, also market dynamics proved to be incapable to correct such failure, spontaneously directing banks towards socially virtuous behaviour even without clear-cut rules.[30] Indeed, the 2018 reform of LCR requirements has exempted banks from numerous disclosure obligations,[31] making it more complex for depositors and investors to obtain the information needed to police management decision.[32]

943As to capital requirements, some authors have also pointed out loopholes in the U. S. accounting and prudential regulations of non-trading book activities[33]: i.e., those investments that a bank has decided, in the exercise of its managerial discretion,[34] to keep in its portfolio until their natural maturity. Because of this peculiar feature, intermediaries can evaluate their ‘held-to-maturity assets’ without considering possible market price fluctuations and focusing only on credit risk and their amortized historical cost.[35] Nonetheless, such investments are still exposed to changes in interest rates. This should prompt banks to arrange appropriate hedging strategies should it be necessary – despite the original expectations – to sell a substantial portion of these assets.[36] However, in the absence of a specific regulation,[37] such risks may not be adequately reflected in the regulatory capital and corporate accounting.[38]

As of 31 December 2022, held-to-maturity assets represented 76% (i.e., $91,32 billion) of the SVB investment securities and half of its total assets,[39] “nearly double” the average of the U. S. large institutions.[40] Still, in the absence of an appropriate regulation, SVB was able to conceal in its balance-sheet potential losses of approximately $15.1 billion,[41] finding itself unable to sell these assets to relieve the sudden liquidity shortfall safely. Indeed, had SVB sold part of its held-to-maturity investments, it would have been required to recognise the unrealized losses on a substantial portion of its portfolio.[42]

944In conclusion, as the Federal Reserve expressly acknowledged, there is little doubt that the 2018 reform of the U. S. banking system created a “weaker regulatory framework”. Indeed, “in the absence of these changes”, SVB “would have been subject to enhanced liquidity risk management requirements, full standardized liquidity requirements,” and “enhanced capital requirements”, bolstering its resilience and possibly mitigating the systemic effects of its crisis.[43]

2.2. Liquidity and Capital Requirements and the Scope of Proportionality. The European Framework

Liquidity and capital requirements represent the backbone of prudential regulation. Not only do they provide additional funds and high-quality assets in times of market distress, but they also restrict banks (ex-ante) from taking up excessive risks by adding ‘artificial’ regulatory costs: that is, by making banks ‘internalise’ the social costs of their activity.[44] For this reason, as the crisis of SVB clearly shows, such requirements should not be incautiously relaxed, even for smaller banks.

In principle, the case for proportionality may appear weaker in relation to liquidity and capital requirements as such, while it may advocate for simpler regimes applicable to smaller institutions (for example, providing simplified calculation criteria and formulae). In general terms, the rationale for proportionality is to mitigate the fixed costs of regulation for smaller intermediaries, which do not possess adequate economies of scale. Capital requirements and liquidity provision, instead, represent variable costs (proportional ‘in nature’ and calibrated according to the actual risks taken by each institution): for this very reason, the level of coverage against such risks should be outside the scope of proportionality. Indeed, the choice to provide a milder regulatory capital regime for smaller institutions is likely to be a political one, aiming at promoting specific economic and industrial goals[45] rather than implementing proportionality and creating a level playing field.

945Accordingly, acknowledging the importance of liquidity requirements, the international financial standards of the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision[46] refrained from introducing any waiver on the LCR, even for small and non-complex institutions.[47] Similar conclusions – with minimal exemptions – also hold for LCR reporting requirements.[48] As a single exception, subject to supervisory approval, small and non-complex institutions can benefit from a simplified methodology for calculating NSFR requirements (art. 428ai CRR).

Overall, there is no doubt that this regulatory framework contributed to the development of a resilient banking system. Indeed – against a minimum LCR requirement of 100% of net cash flows (art. 412 CRR) – European banks have, on average, HQLA equal to 160% and “more than half of the existing buffers ... are made up of cash and central bank reserves, which sensibly mitigates the risk of mark-to-market losses when liquidity needs arise”.[49]

As to the interest rate risk (one of the major drivers of SVB’s crisis),[50] the European regulatory capital regimes are also shaped according to these principles. Banks, in particular, must set aside adequate regulatory capital even for their non-trading books assets,[51] while supervisors retain a discretionary power to impose additional Pillar-2 capital requirements against this risk. In this context – specifically addressing one of the most dramatic issues that 946brought to the collapse of SVB – European intermediaries are also required to “take into account ... the potential for actual losses to be incurred under stressed conditions, or as a result of secular changes in the market environment” (e. g., “where it might become necessary to liquidate positions that are intended as a long-term investment to stabilise earnings”).[52]

At the same time, European institutions must implement appropriate governance arrangements to “identify, measure, monitor and control” all the risks arising from changes in interest rates (the so-called interest rate risk arising from the banking book, or IRRBB).[53] In particular, the management body is expected to implement a proper IRRBB strategy, identifying stringent limits to the bank’s exposure to these risks.[54] This strategy must be fully aligned with the bank’s overall risk appetite framework,[55] and it must consider “the extent to which the business model relies on generating net interest income by ‘riding the yield curve’” (i.e., “funding assets with a comparatively long repricing period with liabilities with a comparatively short repricing period”). Notably, should the bank rely heavily on this source of earnings, (as SVB did[56]) the management body must specifically address how the institution “plans to survive periods of flat or inverse yield curves”.[57] Against this background, it is also expressly stated that accounting principles “should not drive” the bank’s “risk management approach” (still, directors should always “be aware of the effects of accounting policies”).[58]

Once again, small and non-complex institutions are subject to the same discipline, although they can apply these rules “in a proportionate manner, depending on the level, complexity and riskiness” of their overall portfolio.[59]

3. The Role of Corporate and Risk Governance.

Poor corporate governance and risk management policies certainly played a crucial role in the crisis of SVB.[60] Indeed – as noted by the Federal Reserve – the board of directors and the chief risk officer “lacked large bank experience” 947and “failed to establish appropriate risk management”. In addition, “internal governance structures were inadequate given [the bank’s rapid] growth”, and “internal audit coverage” was insufficient, too.[61]

Notably, internal rules on directors’ and managers’ compensation were also largely ineffective.[62] Most strikingly, the variable part of the remuneration accounted for as much as 90% of the total amount paid to the CEO (81% for the other board members) and was calculated exclusively according to the company’s profitability, without any reference to the bank’s risk profile. In such a context, the power of the nomination and compensation committee to “adjust payouts for negative risk outcomes” was the only (clearly insufficient) counterbalance to excessive risk-taking.[63] The SVB compensation policies also defined claw-backpolicies in rather general terms by leaving too much discretion over the conditions under which the bank could have recouped the incentive paid to the management.

3.1. The European Framework on Corporate Governance

It is broadly acknowledged that the establishment of organisational, administrative, and accounting arrangements is essential to ensure a credit institution’s sound and prudent management.[64] For this reason – with few exceptions (e. g., theappointment of a risk committee inside the board;[65] the possibility to combine risk management and compliance functions;[66] or the assignment of the outsourcing function to a board’s member[67]) – all European banks are required to comply with the same set of rules, especially with reference to risk management and internal controls. In this framework, proportionality is very limited 948in scope and only represents a simple criterion to ‘shape’ the general application of uniform rules according to “the nature, scale, and complexity of the risks inherent in the business model and the institution’s activities” (art. 74(2) CRD IV).[68]

More so, similar conclusions hold for the regulatory provisions on management remuneration, the variable part of which should always “reflect a sustainable and risk-adjusted performance” (art. 92(2)(g)(ii) CRD IV). According to this, the “variable remuneration components” – which should not generally exceed the amount of the total compensation fixed part (art. 94(1)(g)(i) CRD IV) – must be adjusted “for all types of current and future risks” and must take also “into account the cost of the capital and the liquidity required” (art. 94(1)(j) CRD IV). Although smaller banks may benefit from some minor exemptions (art. 94(3)(a) CRD IV),[69] these latter do not undermine the effectiveness of the overall regulatory framework.

Once again, the European framework already provides a detailed regulatory solution to all the major concerns raised by the failure of SVB, although – it has been argued – “rules on corporate governance could be further enhanced at least in relation to remuneration and risk management”.[70]

3.2. The Quest for Proportionality After SVB

Still, perhaps surprisingly, the analysis of the SVB crisis may suggest a partially different approach. Despite the startling deficiencies in SVB risk management and internal controls functions, the bank’s crisis had partly been caused by the materialisation of risks overlooked or underestimated even by the supervisor.[71] To be sure, correctly identifying and evaluating all the risks to which a bank is currently exposed may be very challenging: new unaccounted risks can suddenly materialise, while supposed negligible risks may easily turn into a significant problem for a bank’s sound and prudent management.[72]

949At the same time, predicting how a future banking crisis might unfold may be difficult, too,[73] and cognitive biases can undermine managers’ ability to make informed decisions. As it often happens, for example, people tend to “assess the likelihood of risks by asking how readily examples come to mind” (availability heuristic),[74] and even managers – although professionals – are prone to such biases. Banks’ directors “spent the past decade worrying about credit and liquidity risks”, while interest rates grabbed far less attention.[75] According to behavioural economics, this cognitive background could easily drive managers toward incorrect assumptions, “influencing” how they “prepare for and respond to crisis” and make “business choices”.[76] Such considerations may explain – at least in part – why SVB managers (and supervisors) were so blind to the risks arising from changes in interest rates.

In conclusion, it is undisputed that effective management of risks and conflicts of interest should be a primary goal of corporate governance arrangements, clearly advising against an incautious loosening of these regulatory standards. At the same time, a generalized tightening of corporate governance rules may also be counterproductive. Indeed, the need to provide more robust risk management does not necessarily require stricter limits in the banking activity and more burdensome and meticulous procedures: the European regulatory framework already addresses all the major issues the SVB crisis brought to light, and more stringent rules will only further limit the scope of proportionality affecting mostly the smallest banks. Instead, it may be helpful to rethink the global architecture of governance structures, in order to provide innovative solutions to better cope with cognitive limitations of individuals in the banking 950sector (e. g., group thinking, heard effect, or – as shown by SVB – availability heuristic).

At the same time, it should be noted that even introducing a more detailed, punctual, and overarching set of rules on risk management and internal controls does not necessarily result in a more efficient and reliable outcome[77] (whereas it certainly increases compliance costs, especially for smaller institutions). Indeed, the current corporate governance regime relies upon pervasive networks of internal procedures and arrangements intermediaries must adopt according to the supervisory guidelines. However, “to operate successfully”, every bureaucracy “must attain a high degree of reliability of behavior” and “an unusual degree of conformity with prescribed patterns of action”, often perceived by the bank staff as an authentic ‘liturgy’. Such “ritualism ensues with an unchallenged insistence upon punctilious adherence to formalized procedure”, and it “may be exaggerated to the point where primary concern with conformity to the rules interferes with the achievement of the purposes” of the procedure itself.[78] This structure, though, “interferes with ready adaptation under special conditions not clearly envisaged” by the management.[79] On the other hand, highly detailed procedures and behavioral patterns also tend to ‘encapsulate’ people thinking in predefined clusters and prevent banking personnel from adapting their activity to the ever-changing economic contest, spotting the appearance of new risks, and exacerbating the problems posed by path dependencies and cognitive biases.

4. The Intensity and Frequency of Supervisory Activity May Be Graduated According to the Characteristics of the Supervised Entity

There are many opinions on which the weakening of the supervisory activity has contributed to the SVB crisis. In addition to external observers,[80] the Fed951eral Reserve itself[81] has also underlined this aspect. The consequence of such an analysis is thus to emphasise the importance of high-level supervision[82] and, consequently, the need to strengthen that power.[83] In even more explicit terms, to avoid other cases like the SVB case, the intensity and frequency of bank stress tests conducted by the supervisory authority should then be increased,[84] abandoning the current approach of graduating both the frequency and the supervisory effort according to the banks’ characteristics instead.

In support of this approach, it has been pointed out that SVB would not be subjected to stress tests until 2024, three years after crossing the $100 billion asset threshold, which is suitable for increasing such tests in the United States.[85] In the U. S. system, the frequency of the checks then increases for banks in the categories which followed – indeed, starting with banks with consolidated assets over USD 250 billion (Category III banks), the stress tests become annual. The conclusion of the reasoning is straightforward: such critical elements “raise questions over how closely the Fed was following developments at SVB”.[86]

952However, as will be shown below, the supervisory malfunctioning was not due to a lack of frequent supervision or thorough testing. Given the reduced benefits that an increase in the intensity or depth of analysis of the supervisory activity entails and, simultaneously, because of the increased costs for the supervised entities, it seems reasonable to envisage a proportionate approach to supervisory activity.

4.1. The Federal Reserve’s Supervisory Activity in the SVB Case

At a closer look, the SVB crisis cannot be attributed to a limited frequency of checks or a reduced intensity of investigation by the supervisory authority due to the little power conferred on it. On the contrary, supervisory interventions relating to SVB have not been lacking in recent years,[87] even if a simplified regime has been introduced with reference to banks considered to be small.

Specifically, the Federal Reserve made some significant interventions. For example, in January 2019, the authority underlined the concern about risk management by the SVB through the Matter Requiring Attention. Towards the end of 2021, deficiencies in the bank’s liquidity risk management were found. Further findings were highlighted in May 2022. In summer 2022, the bank’s management rating was downgraded, thus activating the bank’s growth restrictions envisaged by law (Sec. 4(m) Bank Holding Company Act). In October 2022, there was the meeting with the bank’s senior management to express new concerns regarding the risk profile relating to the intermediary’s interest rate. The Federal Reserve transmitted a supervisory finding on the management of this risk in November 2022. Finally, in February 2023, there was an analysis of a report on the impact that rising interest rates could have on the financial condition of some banks in general, and with specific reference to SVB.[88]

953In the light of this evidence, the words of the Federal Reserve chairman were not implausible when he claimed that, in relation to SVB, “supervisors did get in there and they were, as you know obviously, they were on this issue, but nonetheless, this still happened”.[89] Even more clearly, it was recognized that “SVB’s foundational problems were widespread and well-known, yet core issues were not resolved, and stronger oversight was not put in place”.[90]

4.2. The Main Explanations for the Supervisory Failure in the SVB Case

Given the activities undertaken by the Federal Reserve just mentioned in the previous subparagraph, the authority could not avert the SVB crisis. Therefore, as the same authority has asked,[91] one is expected to wonder what went wrong: in other words, why the supervisory authority was unable to prevent the SVB crisis. On this point, it should be noted that the Federal Reserve has identified the main risks; instead, the problem must be underestimating these risks’ impact. In this regard, the primary explanations for this result are the following.[92]

954First, the business of correctly identifying and estimating the extent of risks present in the financial system is very complex: “even if the authorities successfully identify a lot of risk and areas where it is taken, there is an infinite scope for risk to emerge elsewhere”[93] or that the relevance attributed to the risks identified is different from what occurs. Therefore, Barr’s point on this matter makes sense: “we must be humble about our ability—and that of bank managers—to predict how a future financial crisis might unfold, how losses might be incurred, and what the effect of a financial crisis might be on the financial system and our broader economy”.[94]

Furthermore, as was mentioned earlier, an evaluation error may be influenced by cognitive biases. As graphically described, supervision is ‘trained to fight the last war’: in the past decade, the main risks have been credit and liquidity; interest rate risk, on the other hand, was not a significant threat before the SVB case. The influence of this cognitive bias may therefore have been an outcome-determinative factor.[95]

In the light of these arguments, it is possible to draw an initial conclusion: an increase in supervisory activity does not solve the problems described above.

Other dynamics may have influenced a light supervisory approach. First, it was argued that the Federal Reserve had no incentive to raise the alarm about potential interest rate risk after it was the unintended but accepted consequence of its monetary policy decisions. Second, the fact that the Basel regulatory framework assigns a zero-risk weight to sovereign bonds could explain why the risk of assets invested in sovereign bonds has been underestimated[96]. Overall, there may have been a temptation to reduce rules and controls to encourage investments of a technological nature[97] or, more generally, due to the 955‘culture’ of decreasing administrative costs for banks and, conversely, increasing the burden of proof for vigilance.[98] To this, it was pointed out that the CEO of SVB (the most important bank supervised by the San Francisco Federal Reserve) served on the board of directors of the San Francisco Federal Reserve itself until the day the bank went bankrupt,[99] even if the supervisory authority itself maintained that “the report found no evidence of unethical behaviour on the part of supervisors”.[100]

In conclusion, the risks borne by SVB appear to have been rather simple, and indeed have been identified by the supervisor. The critical issue was instead that of having underestimated the identified risks. Consequently, it is not correct to attribute a reduced frequency of checks and a superficial analysis to supervision. These explanations could help understand why, with specific reference to SVB, it was stated that “staff relayed that they were actively engaged with SVB but, as it turned out, the full extent of the bank’s vulnerability was not apparent until the unexpected bank run on March 9”[101]. Therefore, more than the number of controls, their quality is relevant and, above all, the way the supervised entity respects the indications of the regulatory authority.956

4.3. The European Regime

In any case, the European rules have more significant safeguards than the U. S. ones.

First, due to its size, SVB would have been qualified as a category 1 or 2 bank (large institution), with the consequence that the evaluation of all the elements of the SREP would have had a frequency, respectively, of at least one year or two years.

From a different point of view, the three-year assessments are contemplated for category 3 and 4 banks, which, however, include intermediaries with significantly different characteristics from SVB: category 3 includes small-medium institutions which, among other things, are “operating domestically or with non-significant cross-border operations, and operating in a limited number of business lines”; category 4, on the other hand, includes small and non-complex entities. In the case of banks included in category 3 or 4, however, the addition of other defence mechanisms is envisaged, among which, for example, the duty of the supervisory authorities to monitor key indicators on a quarterly basis, to produce a documented summary of the overall SREP assessment at least annually, and, finally, to update the assessments of all individual SREP elements at least every 3 years, or sooner in light of material new information emerging on the risk posed.[102]

Suppose we draw some lessons from the SVB case. In that case, we must therefore consider that the principle of proportionality is applied differently by the U. S. and the E.U. and that the regulatory system in which it operates has peculiar characteristics. Therefore, it is incorrect to deduce from the SVB incident a need to increase supervision in the European Union. Not only was the problem mainly qualitative, and not quantitative; but also, the rules on the supervision of banks already allow for more in-depth control in Europe, compared to the U. S. regime.

5. The Importance of the Business Model and the Powers and Limits of the Supervisor

Among the problematic aspects of SVB, the one that most contributed to the crisis was undoubtedly the peculiar business model adopted by the bank. Particular attention must therefore be paid to the supervision of this characteristic.957

5.1. The SVB’s Business Model and Its Criticalities

More specifically, SVB’s business model featured several critical elements.

As regards balance sheet liabilities, for example, the dizzying growth of bank deposits (about $212 billion at the end of 2022, compared to only $115 billion in 2020) could lead to problems for a bank because “risk controls and buffers against potential losses often don’t grow in line with new risks being taken by fast-growing banks”.[103] Similarly, the fact that a high percentage of deposits were not protected by the FDIC (about 96%) increases the risk of a bank run.[104] The concentration of deposits and the consequent reduction in coordination costs between depositors (who communicate with each other easily) also explain the possible herd effect which facilitates the bank run.[105] Finally, the fact that most depositors were tech start-ups entails a high concentration risk in a specific sector. This ultimately exposes a bank to a deposit outflow if these companies need to raise liquidity, not having access to further funding rounds.

On the other hand, concerning the balance sheet assets, the purchase – during the period of explosive growth 2019-2021 – of more than $100 billion of mortgage-backed securities issued at low-interest rates, without having adequate hedges to protect their value in the event of an increase in interest rates, exposed SVB to high risk.[106]

An inadequate business model adopted by a bank can compromise its solvency and, in the event of bank failure, the stability of the entire financial system. Therefore, to avoid this undesirable outcome, the power should be conferred upon supervisory authorities to intervene to correct a bank’s business model.

5.2. The Powers and Limits of Intervention of the Supervisory Authority on the Business Model of a Bank in the European Union

Within the European regulatory framework, the above considerations justify the powers conferred on the supervisory authority to “require the reinforcement of the arrangements, processes, mechanisms, and strategies implemented”, as well as to “restrict or limit the business, operations or network of in958stitutions or to request the divestment of activities that pose excessive risks to the soundness of an institution” (art. 104(1)(b) and (e) CRD IV; see also art. 16(2)(b) and (e) SSMR).

At the same time, the intervention of the supervisory authority with regard the business model of banks contrasts with a decision previously taken by the directors and therefore involves a constriction of the freedom to conduct a business (protected by art. 16 of the Charter of Fundamental Rights of the European Union and by the European Convention for the Protection of Human Rights and Fundamental Freedoms).[107] Therefore, although the SREP assessment contemplates it, is a delicate aspect.

Still, the freedom to conduct business is not absolute. Protecting a specific constitutional freedom could prejudice another freedom or general interest. Therefore, it is possible to restrict the freedom to conduct a business to pursue another interest (such as stability), provided that an adequate balance between potentially conflicting interests is guaranteed. From this perspective, “it likewise seems legitimate that these rights should, if necessary, be subject to certain limits justified by the overall objectives pursued by the Community, on condition that the substance of these rights is left untouched”.[108]

959Regarding the matter under analysis, therefore, it is necessary to limit any excessive discretion of the supervisory authority in reviewing the business model of a bank. As has been pointed out, supervisors can identify what is not working to banks, but they cannot tell them which business areas to focus on.[109]

Specifically, the problem also emerges from reading the EBA Guidelines on the SREP: if, on the one hand, “competent authorities may require the institution to make adjustments to risk management and control arrangements, or to governance arrangements, to match the desired business model or strategy” and, at the same time, “may require the institution to make changes to the business model or strategy”;[110] on the other hand, “competent authorities should conduct regular business model analysis (BMA) to assess business and strategic risks”, but “without undermining the responsibility of the institution’s management body for running and organising the business, or indicating preferences for specific business models”.[111]

What are the limits to the discretion of the supervisory authority? In addition to a constraint about the content of its intervention, the supervisory authority must verify the existence of the conditions for its intervention. It can intervene in the business model or strategy of a bank if: “a. they are not supported by appropriate organisational, governance or risk control and management arrangements; b. they are not supported by capital and operational plans, including allocation of appropriate financial, human and technological (IT) resources; and/or c. there are significant concerns about the sustainability of the business model”.[112]

To be compliant with the indications of the Court of Justice mentioned above, of the three conditions, the third deserves further study. When exactly do “significant concerns about the sustainability of the business model” arise? This sentence is vague and lends itself to multiple interpretations. To avoid possible abusive use of this condition, it seems correct to consider this condition satisfied only when it emerges, from a stress test, that a bank cannot contain the risks assumed within its risk appetite. Indeed, internally, “the outputs of stress tests (quantitative and qualitative) should be used as inputs to the process of establishing an institution’s risk appetite and limits”.[113] In establishing its risk appetite, a bank has then to identify a risk threshold within the risk capacity, taking into account a “forward-looking and, where applicable, subject to sce960nario and stress testing to ensure that the financial institution understands what events might push the financial institution outside its ... risk capacity”.[114]

In conclusion, if a bank, even under conditions of stress, satisfies its risk appetite, the supervisory authority cannot intervene on the bank’s business model. Conversely, the supervisory authority would violate the criteria identified by the Court of Justice. Rather, the supervisory authority can intervene ‘indirectly’ by identifying the stress scenarios that limit the choices of banks in setting the risk appetite.[115]

6. Conclusion

As part of the process of revising the rules on European banks, the case of SVB has led to a slowdown in the choice of introducing more significant elements of proportionality about the supervision – and, in particular, to the SREP – on small and non-complex banks. Even the crisis of a bank, such as SVB, considered ‘small’, in fact, involves systemic risks.

As we have demonstrated, the reforms proposed in the European Union are nonetheless heading in the right direction, also in consideration of the marked difference that the notion of proportionality assumes in the United States. Indeed, in the European Union, the principle of proportionality rests on the notions of “small and non-complex institution” and “large institution” (respectively, art. 4(1)(145) and (146), CRR).[116] The first qualification, in particular, encompasses banks with consolidated assets of no more than €5 billion and whose activities – due to their nature, features, riskiness, interconnections, and cross-border operations – are not reasonably capable of threatening the stability of the system, according to a discretionary judgment referred to the super961visory authority.[117] Instead, it is sufficient for a bank to have consolidated assets worth more than €30 billion for it to necessarily be considered a “large institution”. In the U. S. legal system, by contrast, all credit institutions with consolidated assets of less than $250 billion (Category IV banks) enjoy the lighter regulatory framework introduced by the 2018 banking reform.[118] All the more so, despite the power to impose specific additional obligations on individual banks with assets over $100 billion, the supervisory authority never resorted to it for SVB, although the latter was the 16th largest commercial bank in the U. S.,[119] with consolidated assets of $211.8 billion.[120] In other words, SVB in the EU would have qualified as a large institution.

The reforms proposed in the European Union – to amend Article 97(4) CRD IV to require supervisors to differentiate the exercise of ‘group SREPs’ according to (i) the possible mutualistic nature of member banks, as well as (ii) their qualification as small and non-complex institutions (see fn. 9) – are heading in the right direction for many reasons.

First, the case of SVB shows that there are no reasons for derogating from the rules on capital and liquidity: the financial risks associated with the bank’s business – such as credit, liquidity, and interest rate risks – do not depend on the entity who bears them, so that it would be unreasonable to grade the application of a rule according to the characteristics of the addressee. In this sense, the European legislator appropriately provides for a uniform application of these rules for all banks. Indeed, prudential capital can be a ‘buffer’ against unexpected risks and losses, which not even complex risk weighting models or supervisory inspections can identify and manage.[121]

A somewhat different argument can be made regarding corporate governance. Since it is difficult to correctly identify and estimate the risks that a bank assumes, also due to cognitive biases, the ‘quality’ of the verification is more important than the ‘quantity’. Therefore, proportionality can also be applied to corporate governance rules while safeguarding some key elements that can represent distorting incentives (for example, the regulation of remuneration).

In any case, the reforms proposed in the EU intend to reduce banks’ compliance costs, at least the ones that are linked to the activities that a bank per962forms to respond to the indications of the supervisory authority. As emerges from the analysis, the intensity of controls is not one of the major causes of the crisis suffered by SVB, and, in any case, the European legal system has more excellent controls for banks similar in size to that of the Californian bank. Instead, the main problem arose from the difficulty in identifying or correctly assessing the risks identified, which derived above all from the business model, which is very different from that of European banks.[122] Moreover, reducing compliance costs for smaller banks also has a further positive effect: it does not incentivise concentration operations that can lead to the creation of larger banks, whose crisis is then challenging to manage without public interventions.

Finally, the SVB case and the other recent banking crises bring to light a fundamental problem: the trust of depositors plays a fundamental role in the banking system and must therefore be adequately preserved.[123] Indeed, even if a bank is essentially sound, it can suddenly risk fail if its customers lose confidence and withdraw their deposits.[124] From this point of view, if we want to contribute to strengthening the stability of the banking system, instead of disregarding proportionality to increase rules and controls, the most effective solution is to complete the Banking Union and, therefore, to set up the European deposit insurance scheme, at least at Eurozone level.[125] In the case of SVB, the withdrawal of funds by depositors has mainly taken place from ‘unsecured’ deposits, which would also be excluded from the guarantee from a European perspective. Moreover, it is true that even depositors within the ‘insured range’ can choose to devolve their savings elsewhere, for example, in search of more profitable prospects.[126] Nonetheless, it is equally sure that such a scheme would help create a more robust environment,[127] because the risk of depositors in one Member State’s banks moving their savings outward would be re963duced.[128] Therefore, it is correct to follow the further and recent institutional indication on the completion of the Banking Union.[129]


Note

Although the essay is the outcome of a shared work, Sections 1, 2, and 3 can be attributed to Enrico Rino Restelli, while Sections 4, 5, and 6 are to Matteo Arrigoni.937


Published Online: 2024-02-26
Published in Print: 2024-02-06

© 2023 the author(s), published by Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.

Downloaded on 16.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/ecfr-2023-0031/html
Scroll to top button