Startseite Marginal Cost of Public Funds: From the Theory to the Empirical Application for the Evaluation of the Efficiency of the Tax-Benefit Systems
Artikel
Lizenziert
Nicht lizenziert Erfordert eine Authentifizierung

Marginal Cost of Public Funds: From the Theory to the Empirical Application for the Evaluation of the Efficiency of the Tax-Benefit Systems

  • Francesco Figari , Luca Gandullia EMAIL logo und Emanuela Lezzi
Veröffentlicht/Copyright: 18. September 2018

Abstract

We estimate the marginal cost of public funds (MCF) as an overall indicator of the efficiency of tax-benefit systems and their reforms. The novelty of our work is the calculation of a MCF indicator fully based on empirical micro-data representative of the Italian population. This indicator combines the incentives embodied in the tax-benefit system at the intensive and extensive margins with the respective elasticities of labour supply at both margins. Our results first show the importance of taking into account the heterogeneity of the population with women (both single and in couples) facing a more inefficient system than men. Second, our micro-data based indicator shows the potential bias of MCF indicators based on stylized and hypothetical measures of work incentives.

JEL Classification: H21; H41; H20

Appendix: Labour supply model

Static structural discrete choice models of labour supply (e. g. Van Soest 1995; Blundell et al. 2000. For a review see Aaberge and Colombino 2014) provide direct estimations of preferences through the specification of the functional form of the utility function. The assumption behind the discrete choice models is that utility-maximizing individuals choose from a discrete set of alternatives in terms of working hours to maximize the utility of the household on the basis of “preferences” over hours H and net income Y. At each point in the choice set corresponds a given budget on the basis of the earnings of each individual and the tax-benefit system rules simulated by EUROMOD (Sutherland and Figari 2013).

Suppose the utility function for a household is given by:

(5)U(Y,Hf,Hm)

subject to household income:

Y=Efwf,Hf+Emwm,Hm+N+B(Ef,Em,N|X)t(Ef,Em,N | X)

where the utility depends on the female Hf and male Hm hours of work and the household disposable income Y, given earnings of both partners (Ef, Em), other income (N), and benefits (B), and taxes t according to individual and household characteristics X. Other individuals living in the household and their behaviour are taken as exogenous as well. Female and male wage rate, wf and wm, are estimated for all the observations of our sample (workers and non-workers) through a Heckman wage equation to take into account the selection bias in the observed working conditions (see Table 4 and Table 5 in the Appendix).

Table 4:

Wage estimation: women

CoefficientRobust standard errorp-Value
Log wage
Age0.8000.43310.065
Age square−0.1430.11070.195
Age cubic0.0100.00920.282
Education middle0.3040.03490.000
Education high0.5460.03870.000
In couple0.0410.02500.102
Regiona−0.0100.00310.002
Number of children0.0160.01480.259
Number of children 0–20.0160.03680.652
Constant2.9380.56590.000
Participation
Age2.3990.79280.002
Age square−0.3860.20530.060
Age cubic0.0150.01700.392
Education middle0.6600.04080.000
Education high1.0300.06140.000
In couple−0.4070.04840.000
Region−0.0950.00470.000
Children 0–2−0.2680.07270.000
Children 3–6−0.2890.06070.000
Children 7–12−0.2450.05080.000
Children 13–17−0.1230.05270.019
Children 18+0.0720.05920.225
Other income−0.0240.00860.006
Constant−3.1320.97720.001
Rho0.0190.03430.573
Sigma−0.6050.05430.000
Observations8449
  1. Note: aRegion = Regional Unemployment Rate

  2. Source: own simulations with EUROMOD.

Table 5:

Wage estimation: men

CoefficientRobust standard errorp-Value
Log wage
Age1.0940.32590.001
Age square−0.1990.08680.022
Age cubic0.0130.00740.071
Education middle0.2260.01940.000
Education high0.5270.02940.000
In couple0.0250.02210.259
Region−0.0270.00300.000
Number of children0.0220.01150.058
Number of children 0–2−0.0310.03150.330
Constant2.7220.39060.000
Participation
Age3.7340.83680.000
Age square−0.8230.22750.000
Age cubic0.0590.01970.003
Education middle0.3360.04900.000
Education high0.3800.08210.000
In couple0.3960.06790.000
Region−0.1030.00730.000
Children 0–20.0050.10180.958
Children 3–60.0850.08790.336
Children 7–120.1470.07550.052
Children 13–17−0.0450.07980.570
Children 18+0.1020.10090.312
Other income−0.0150.01200.221
Constant−4.0950.97400.000
Rho0.0190.01430.180
Sigma−0.6280.04580.000
Observations7480
  1. Source: own simulations with EUROMOD.

The two-stage procedure – namely first estimating wage rates and then using them in the labour supply estimations – is common practice (e. g. Creedy and Kalb 2005; Bargain, Orsini, and Peichl 2014).

The choice set of each individual is made up of five j = 1, … ., J alternatives, which means J = 5 for singles and J = 5 × 5 for couples, with choices characterized by 0–60 hours per week (specifically we have the following five hours range brackets: 1. (0–9), 2. (10–24), 3. (25–34), 4. (35–44), 5. (45–60)).[8]

The utility function can be decomposed into a deterministic and a stochastic component:

(6)Uj=Vj+j

for each choice j = 1, …, J, where V is the portion of utility given by the observable characteristics while the error term j captures the portion from unobservable characteristics. Error terms are also assumed to represent possible observational errors, optimization errors, or transitory errors.

At each alternative j, the realization of the deterministic part of the utility function (i. e. Vj) is given by the following quadratic functional form with fixed costs linear in the parameters:

(7)Vj=αYj+βYj2+γHjf+δHjm+ε(Hjf)2+ζ(Hjm)2+ηYjHjf+θYjHjm+ιHjfHjmκfHjf>0κmHjm>0

where income (Y) and hours of work (Hf and Hm) enter in both level and square.

Fixed costs improve the fit of the estimated model as in Callan, Van Soest, and Walsh (2009) or Blundell et al. 2000. These costs, denoted κf and κm, are nonzero for positive hour choices and depend on observed characteristics (for example, the presence of young children).

Observed heterogeneity, captured by observable characteristics, cannot be identified directly because these characteristics do not vary across alternatives and would be ruled out in the estimation. It enters through the linear utility parameters:

(8)α=α0+α1X
(9)γ=γ0+γ1X
(10)δ=δ0+δ1X

allowing marginal utilities of income (Y) and hours of work (Hf and Hm) to depend on a vector of family characteristics (X) including polynomial form of age, education level, region, and presence of children.

Assuming that the error terms is independently and identically distributed across alternatives and households according to the Extreme Value Type I distribution, the (conditional) probability of choosing the alternative k is given by the following logit expression (McFadden 1974):

(11)Prk=expUkjexpUkkJ

The choice an individual faces follows in fact the probability rule

Prchoice = k = PrUHj> UHjkj,j=1,,J

according to which the probability that an individual chooses the alternative k is equal to the probability that the utility associated with the choice k is larger than the utility associated with any other choice j.

The parameters, estimated using Maximum simulated Likelihood, are shown in Table 6, 7, and 8, respectively for couples, single women, and single men.

Table 6:

Labour supply estimation: couples

CoefficientRobust standard errorp-Value
Income square−0.00020.00000.009
Income0.0010.00070.048
Hm1.0320.04700.000
Hf0.2590.03350.000
Hm × Hf0.3530.10510.001
Hm Square−14.1270.35600.000
Hf Square−5.6670.24320.000
Hm × Income−0.0010.00150.554
Hf × Income0.0010.00100.226
Spouses’ mean age × Income−0.0000.00030.125
Spouses’ mean age square × Income0.0000.00000.108
Number of children × Income0.0000.00000.638
Hm × male age0.0630.01780.000
Hm × male age square−0.0070.00200.000
Hf × female age0.0650.01460.000
Hf × female age square−0.0080.00180.000
Hm × number of children0.0030.00340.342
Hf × 1(children 0–2)0.0080.00730.249
Hf × 1(children 3–6)−0.0120.00280.000
Hf × 1(children 7–12)−0.0150.00270.000
Hf × 1(children 13–17)−0.0090.00270.001
Hm × 1(region)−0.0230.00260.000
Hf × 1(region)−0.0350.00200.000
Fixed cost (FC) for male labour22.4770.61890.000
FC for male labour × n. of children0.0770.13940.579
FC for male labour × 1(children 0–2)0.1170.17380.501
Fixed cost (FC) for female labour7.2940.30170.000
FC for female labour × n. of children−0.0860.06960.215
FC for female labour × 1(children 0–2)0.5130.27310.060
Log-likelihood−9862.8699
Pseudo R20.2505
Observations4088
  1. Source: own simulations with EUROMOD.

Table 7:

Labour supply estimation: single women

CoefficientRobust standard errorp-Value
Income square0.00050.00030.154
Income0.00060.00170.720
Hours0.3990.07520.000
Hours square−6.1760.46750.000
Hours × Income−0.0210.00530.000
Age × Income0.0000.00080.904
Age square × Income0.0000.00010.994
Number of children × Income−0.0000.00010.000
Hours × age0.0570.03460.096
Hours × age square−0.0070.00430.089
Hours × 1(children 0–2)−0.0670.02390.005
Hours × 1(children 3–6)−0.0160.00770.041
Hours × 1(region)−0.0330.00450.000
Fixed cost (FC)9.5900.63940.000
FC × n. of children−0.4360.19990.029
FC × 1(children 0–2)−1.6840.85740.049
Log-likelihood−1433.9093
Pseudo R20.1359
Observations1031
  1. Source: own simulations with EUROMOD.

Table 8:

Labour supply estimation: single men

CoefficientRobust standard errorp-Value
Income square−0.00000.00060.923
Income−0.00100.00180.576
Hours0.99490.09640.000
Hours square−13.08870.79860.000
Hours × Income−0.00620.00960.518
Age × Income0.00070.00090.420
Age square × Income−0.00010.00010.431
Number of children × Income0.00000.00030.939
Hours × age0.04830.04030.231
Hours × age square−0.00660.00500.188
Hours × 1(children 0–2)−0.01830.11970.878
Hours × 1(children 3–6)0.07490.09820.445
Hours × 1(region)−0.02950.00500.000
Fixed cost (FC)20.7721.21620.000
FC × n. of children−0.82030.86130.341
FC × 1(children 0–2)−11.6082616.3740.985
Log-likelihood−963.23904
Pseudo R20.2909
Observations844
  1. Source: own simulations with EUROMOD.

Table 9:

Kleven and Kreiner’s (2006) elasticity scenarios.

Income decile groups12345678910
Scenario 1
ηi0.40.40.30.30.20.20.10.10.00.0
εi0.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.00.0
Scenario 2
ηi0.40.40.30.30.20.20.10.10.00.0
εi0.10.10.10.10.10.10.10.10.10.1
Scenario 3
ηi0.80.60.40.20.00.00.00.00.00.0
εi0.10.10.10.10.10.10.10.10.10.1
Scenario 4
ηi0.40.30.20.10.00.00.00.00.00.0
εi0.10.10.10.10.10.10.10.10.10.1
Scenario 5
ηi0.60.60.40.40.30.30.20.20.00.0
εi0.10.10.10.10.10.10.10.10.10.1
  1. Source: own simulations with EUROMOD.

References

Aaberge, R., and U. Colombino. 2014. “Labour Supply Models,” in Handbook of Microsimulation Modelling. Contributions to Economic Analysis,. edited by C. O’Donoghue, Vol. 293, 167–222. Bradford: Emerald Group Publishing Limited.10.1108/S0573-855520140000293006Suche in Google Scholar

Atkinson, A. B., and N. H. Stern. 1974. “Pigou, Taxation and Public Goods.” Review of Economic Studies 41: 119–28.10.2307/2296403Suche in Google Scholar

Auerbach, A. J., and H. S. Rosen 1980. “Will the Real Excess Burden Please Stand Up? (Or, Seven Measures in Search of a Concept).” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 495, Cambridge.10.3386/w0495Suche in Google Scholar

Auriol, E., and M. Warlters. 2012. “The Marginal Cost of Public Funds and Tax Reform in Africa.” Journal of Development Economics 97 (1): 58‐72.10.1016/j.jdeveco.2011.01.003Suche in Google Scholar

Ballard, C. L. 1990. “Marginal Welfare Cost Calculations: Differential Analysis Vs. Balanced-Budget Analysis.” Journal of Public Economics 41: 263–76.10.1016/0047-2727(90)90061-LSuche in Google Scholar

Ballard, C. L., and D. Fullerton. 1992. “Distortionary Taxes and the Provision of Public Goods.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 6: 117–31.10.3386/w3506Suche in Google Scholar

Ballard, C. L., J. B. Shoven, and J. Whalley. 1985. “General Equilibrium Computations of the Marginal Welfare Costs of Taxes in the United States.” The American Economic Review 75 (1): 128‐138.Suche in Google Scholar

Bargain, O., K. Orsini, and A. Peichl. 2014. “Comparing Labour Supply Elasticities in Europe and the US: New Results.” Journal of Human Resources 49 (3): 723–838.10.1353/jhr.2014.0017Suche in Google Scholar

Barrios, S., J. Pycroft, and B. Saveyn. (2013).Fiscal Policy and Growth, No. 13, Bank of Italy, Rome The Marginal Cost of Public Funds in the EU: The Case of Labour versus Green Taxes.Suche in Google Scholar

Bjertnæs, G. H. (2018).Working paper No. 879Statistics Norway Research Department The Marginal Cost of Public Funds in Large Welfare State Countries.Suche in Google Scholar

Blundell, R., A. Duncan, J. McCrae, and C. Meghir. 2000. “The Labour Market Impact of the Working Families’ Tax Credit.” Fiscal Studies 21 (1): 75–104.10.1111/j.1475-5890.2000.tb00581.xSuche in Google Scholar

Blundell, R. W., and T. MaCurdy. 1999. “Labor Supply: A Review of Alternative Approaches.” In Handbook of Labour Economics, edited by O. Ashenfelter and D. Card, Vol. 3A. ElsevierScience B.V.: Amsterdam.10.1016/S1573-4463(99)03008-4Suche in Google Scholar

Browning, E. K. 1976 . “The Marginal Cost of Public Funds.” The Journal of Political Economy 84 (2): 283– 98.10.1086/260432Suche in Google Scholar

Browning, E. K. 1987. “On the Marginal Welfare Cost of Taxation.” The American Economic Review 77: 11–23.Suche in Google Scholar

Callan, T., A. Van Soest, and J. R. Walsh. 2009. “Tax Structure and Female Labour Supply: Evidence from Ireland.” Labour 23 (1): 1–35.10.1111/j.1467-9914.2008.00444.xSuche in Google Scholar

Creedy, J., and G. Kalb. 2005. “Discrete Hours Labour Supply Modelling: Specification, Estimation and Simulation.” Journal of Economic Surveys 19 (5): 697–734.10.1111/j.0950-0804.2005.00265.xSuche in Google Scholar

Dahlby, B. 1998. “Progressive Taxation and the Social Marginal Cost of Public Funds.” Journal of Public Economics 67 (1): 105–22.10.1016/S0047-2727(97)00049-2Suche in Google Scholar

Dahlby, B. 2008. The Marginal Cost of Public Funds. Theory and Applications. M.I.T. Press: Cambridge, Mass.10.7551/mitpress/9780262042505.001.0001Suche in Google Scholar

Dahlby, B., and E. Ferede. 2012. “The Effects of Tax Rate Changes on Tax Bases and the Marginal Cost of Public Funds for Canadian Provincial Governments.” International Tax and Public Finance 19: 844–83.10.1007/s10797-012-9210-7Suche in Google Scholar

Decoster, A., S. Perelman, D. Vandelannoote, T. Vanheukelom, and G. Verbist. 2015. “A Bird’s Eye View on 20 Years of Tax-Benefit Reforms in Belgium.” EUROMOD Working Paper Series, EM 10/15, June10.2139/ssrn.2599970Suche in Google Scholar

Dixon, P., J. Honkatukia, and M. Rimmer. "The Marginal Cost of Funds from Different Taxes in Finland", GTAP #Resource3877 2012, https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/resources/res_display.asp?RecordID=3877.Suche in Google Scholar

Figari, F., and C. Fiorio. 2015. “Fiscal Consolidation Policies in the Context of Italy’s Two Recessions.” Fiscal Studies 36 (4): 499–526.10.1111/j.1475-5890.2015.12074Suche in Google Scholar

Figari, F., A. Paulus, and H. Sutherland. 2015. “Microsimulation and Policy Analysis,” in Handbook of Income Distribution, edited by A.B. Atkinson, and F. Bourguignon,,, 2141–221. Oxford: Elsevier: North Holland10.1016/B978-0-444-59429-7.00025-XSuche in Google Scholar

Hansson, I. 1984. Marginal Cost of Public Funds for Different Tax Instruments and Government Expenditures. In Limits and Problems of Taxation. 17–32. Palgrave Macmillan: UK.10.1007/978-1-349-08094-6_3Suche in Google Scholar

Hansson, I., and C. Stuart. 1985. “Tax Revenue and the Marginal Cost of Public Funds in Sweden.” Journal of Public Economics 27 (3): 331–53.10.1016/0047-2727(85)90055-6Suche in Google Scholar

Harberger, A. C. 1964. “The Measurement of Waste.” The American Economic Review 54: 58–76.Suche in Google Scholar

Heckman, J. J. 1993. “What Has Been Learned about Labour Supply in the past Twenty Years?.” The American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 83: 116–21.Suche in Google Scholar

Immervoll, H., H. J. Kleven, C. T. Kreiner, and E. Saez. 2007. “Welfare Reform in European Countries: A Microsimulation Analysis.” The Economic Journal 117: 1–44.10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02000.xSuche in Google Scholar

Immervoll, H. 2004. EUROMOD Working Paper Series, No. EM6/04 Average and Marginal Effective Tax Rates Facing Workers in the EU: A Micro-Level Analysis of Levels, Distributions and Driving Factors.Suche in Google Scholar

Jara, H. X., K. Gasior, and M. Makovec. 2017. EUROMOD Working Paper Series, EM 3/17. Low Incentives to Work at the Extensive and Intensive Margin in Selected EU Countries.Suche in Google Scholar

Jara, H. X., and A Tumino. 2013. “Tax-Benefit Systems, Income Distribution and Work Incentives in the European Union.” International Journal of Microsimulation 6 (1): 27–62.10.34196/ijm.00076Suche in Google Scholar

Kleven, H. J., and C. T. Kreiner. 2006. “The Marginal Cost of Public Funds: Hours of Work versus Labour Force Participation.” Journal of Public Economics 90 (10): 1955–73.10.1016/j.jpubeco.2006.03.006Suche in Google Scholar

Mayshar, J. 1991. “On Measuring the Marginal Cost of Funds Analytically.” The American Economic Review 81: 1329–35.Suche in Google Scholar

McFadden, D. 1974. “Conditional Logit Analysis of Qualitative Choice Behaviour.” In Frontiers in Econometrics, edited by P. Zerembka, New York: Academic PressSuche in Google Scholar

O’Donoghue, C. 2011. “Do Tax-Benefit Systems Cause High Replacement Rates? A Decompositional Analysis Using EUROMOD.” Labour 25 (1): 126–51.10.1111/j.1467-9914.2010.00501.xSuche in Google Scholar

Paulus, A., F. Figari, and H. Sutherland. 2017. “The Design of Fiscal Consolidation Measures in the European Union: Distributional Effects and Implications for Macro-Economic Recovery.” Oxford Economic Papers 69 (3): 632–54.10.1093/oep/gpw054Suche in Google Scholar

Pigou, A.C. 1947. A Study in Public Finance, 3rd ed. Macmillan: London.Suche in Google Scholar

Samuelson, P.A. 1954. “The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure.” Review of Economics and Statistics 36 (4): 387–89.10.2307/1925895Suche in Google Scholar

Sandmo, A. 1998. “Redistribution and the Marginal Cost of Public Funds.” Journal of Public Economics 70 (3): 365–82.10.1016/S0047-2727(98)00040-1Suche in Google Scholar

Stiglitz, J. E., and P. Dasgupta. 1971. “Differential Taxation, Public Goods and Economic Efficiency.” Review of Economic Studies 38: 151–74.10.2307/2296778Suche in Google Scholar

Stuart, C. 1984. “Welfare Costs per Dollar of Additional Tax Revenue in United States.” The American Economic Review 74: 352–62.Suche in Google Scholar

Sutherland, H., and F. Figari. 2013. “EUROMOD: The European Union Tax-Benefit Microsimulation Model.” International Journal of Microsimulation 6 (1): 4–26.10.34196/ijm.00075Suche in Google Scholar

Thomas, A., and P. O’Reilly 2016. “The Impact of Tax and Benefit Systems on the Workforce Participation Incentives of Women.” OECD Taxation Working Papers, No. 29, OECD Publishing, Paris. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/d950acfc-enSuche in Google Scholar

Usher, D. 1984. “An Instructive Derivation of the Expression for the Marginal Cost of Public Funds.” Public Finance 39 (3): 406–11.Suche in Google Scholar

Van Soest, A. 1995. “Structural Models of Family Labour Supply. A Discrete Choice Approach.” The Journal of Human Resources 30: 63–88.10.2307/146191Suche in Google Scholar

Wildasin, D.E. 1984. “On Public Good Provision with Distortionary Taxation.” Economic Inquiry 32: 227–43.10.1111/j.1465-7295.1984.tb00681.xSuche in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2018-09-18

© 2018 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Heruntergeladen am 21.10.2025 von https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejeap-2018-0132/html
Button zum nach oben scrollen