Home Leadership in Tax Competition with Fiscal Equalization Transfers
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

Leadership in Tax Competition with Fiscal Equalization Transfers

  • Junichi Haraguchi and Hikaru Ogawa EMAIL logo
Published/Copyright: June 8, 2018

Abstract

We propose a timing game of asymmetric tax competition with fiscal equalization scheme. The study finds that governments tend to play a sequential-move game as the scale of equalization transfer increases, which explains the emergence of tax leaders in tax competition. The presence of a tax leader is likely to exacerbate capital misallocation among countries, suggesting that equalization transfers aimed at narrowing the interregional fiscal gap might cause an inefficient capital allocation.

JEL Classification: H30; H87

Funding statement: We are grateful to participants of the seminars at Nanzan University for their helpful comments and suggestions. We also thank Keisuke Kawachi for his helpful comments, The authors acknowledge the financial support of JSPS Grant nos.16K12374, 17J07949, and 17H02533.

Appendix

A Appendix

We derive the sequential equilibrium in game GL, in which country L leads and country S follows. The maximization problem of the larger country is given by

maxtLuL=(ALkL)kL+r(θkˉkL)+α(tSkStLkL),s.t.(3),(4),(5),and(7).

The first-order conditions give the equilibrium tax rates as

(14)tLL(α,θ)=212α25α+4α2Λ8kˉ4θ+14α18α2+8α39θα+4θα24254α12α2,
(15)tSL(α,θ)=Λ1α12α4α14kˉ3θ+12α18α2+8α37θα+4θα2354α12α2.

Using eqs. (14) and (15) with eqs. (3)–(5), we obtain the equilibrium values:

kLL(α,θ)=kˉ+12αΛ21θkˉ212α54α,kSL(α,θ)=kˉ12αΛ21θkˉ212α54α,rL(α,θ)=Ω212αΛ4kˉ7θ+50α72α2+32α316θα+8θα212254α12α2.

Notice that kiL\gt0 for i=S,L if Assumption 2 holds. Substituting these values into the objective functions, we obtain the following utility:

(16)uLL(α,θ)=N(α,θ)+Λkˉ(36α216α347θα+83θ)212α54α,
(17)uSL(α,θ)=Z(α,θ)+kˉΛ(224α364α44α2734θ+4α438θ+11θ36)212α54α2,

where

N(α,θ)Ωkˉθ2+Λ24(54α)+kˉ21632θ+11θ2(54α)12α24k2α(4α234θα2740θ+4θ231θ+7θ2+18)12α254α,Z(α,θ)Ωkˉθ2+Λ2(34α)454α2kˉ2(216θ83θ2108)12α254α24αkˉ2(16α34θ3+8α22130θ+2θ2α215340θ+56θ2+122219θ+62θ2)12α254α2.

B Appendix

We derive the sequential equilibrium in game GS, in which country S leads and country L follows. The maximization problem of country S is given by

maxtSuS=(ASkS)kS+r(θkˉkS)+α(tLkLtSkS),s.t.(3),(4),(5),and(6).

The first-order condition yields the equilibrium tax rate as

(18)tLS(α,θ)=Λ1α12α4α1+4kˉ3θ+12α18α2+8α37θα+4θα234α512α2,
(19)tSS(α,θ)=212α25α+4α2Λ+8kˉ4θ+14α18α2+8α39θα+4θα2424α512α2.

Using eqs. (18) and (19) with eqs. (3)–(5), we obtain the following equilibrium values:

kLS(α,θ)=kˉ+12αΛ+2kˉ1θ212α54α,kSS(α,θ)=kˉ12αΛ+2kˉ1θ212α54α,rS(α,θ)=Ω2+12αΛ+4kˉ7θ+50α72α2+32α316θα+8θα212254α12α2.

Notice that kiS\gt0 for i=S,L if Assumption 2 holds. Substituting these values into the objective functions, we obtain the following utility:

(20)uLS(α,θ)=Z(α,θ)Λkˉ(224α364α44α2734θ+4α438θ+11θ36)212α54α2,
(21)uSS(α,θ)=N(α,θ)Λkˉ(36α216α347θα+83θ)212α54α.

C Appendix

Based on Theorems II, III, and IV shown in Hamilton and Slutsky (1990), we prove the equilibrium timing of moves by comparing the utilities with the three orders of moves, i.e., uiN,uiL, and uiS. The comparison of their utility gives the following inequalities.

uLN(α,θ)uLS(α,θ)=HL{12αΛ8kˉ1α1θ}0,uLL(α,θ)uLN(α,θ)={12αΛ+8kˉ1α1θ}26454α12α21α2>0,uSN(α,θ)uSL(α,θ)=HS{Λ12α98α8kˉ1α118α1θ}0,uSS(α,θ)uSN(α,θ)={12αΛ8kˉ1α1θ}26454α12α21α2>0,

where

HL34α{8kˉ1α118α1θ+Λ12α98α}6454α21α212α2>0,HS34α{12αΛ+8kˉ1α1θ}6454α21α212α2>0.

Here, uLNuLS if Λkˉ8(1θ)(1α)12α and uSNuSL if Λkˉ8(1θ)(1α)(118α)(12α)(98α). Hence, when Λkˉ<8(1θ)(1α)12α, both countries prefer their Stackelberg follower utilities to the simultaneous-move utility: uLS\gtuLN and uSL>uSN. Then, with uLL>uLN and uSS>uSN, both sequential outcomes are Nash equilibria. When 8(1θ)(1α)(118α)(12α)(98α)<ΛkˉuLN\gtuLS and uSN<uSL. Then, with uLL>uLN and uSS>uSN, a sequential-move outcome in which country L is a Stackelberg leader is the unique subgame perfect Nash equilibrium. When Λkˉ>8(1θ)(1α)(118α)(12α)(98α), each country prefers its simultaneous-move equilibrium utility to its payoff as a Stackelberg follower, i.e., uLN\gtuLS and uSN\gtuSL. Then, with uLL>uLN and uSS>uSN, the equilibrium is that both countries move early, yielding the simultaneous-move outcome.

D Appendix

The government i maximizes ui=(Aiki)ki+r(θkˉki)+αtˉ(kjki). The reaction functions of countries L and S are given by

(22)tL=13tS+4kˉ(1θ)3+4tˉα3+Λ3,
(23)tS=13tL+4kˉ(1θ)3+4tˉα3Λ3.

Notice that we here assume that the government i sees the standard tax rate, tˉ, to be given and chooses its tax rate, ti.

While each government does not account for its effects on tˉ,

the central government sets the standard tax rate to the average tax rates of both countries, tˉ=(tL+tS)/2. In this case, the actual reaction function can be given as follows:

tL=2α+132αtS+4kˉ(1θ)+Λ32αandtS=2α+132αtL+4kˉ(1θ)Λ32α.

The equilibrium values in the simultaneous-move outcome are tLN=[8kˉ(1θ)+Λ(12α)]/4(12α), tSN=[8kˉ(1θ)Λ(12α)]/4(12α), kLN=kˉ+(Λ/8), kSN=kˉ(Λ/8), tˉN=2kˉ(1θ)/(12α), and rN=0.5Ω+[2kˉ(θ2(1α))]/(12α). If we assume Λ/kˉ<8, kiN>0 is ensured.[10] Using these values, we obtain the equilibrium utility levels:

(24)uLN=kˉAL(1θ)(2ΩΛ)kˉ4+3Λ264+(2α(12θ)+6θ2θ23)kˉ22α1,
(25)uSN=kˉAS(1θ)(2Ω+Λ)kˉ4+3Λ264+(2α(12θ)+6θ2θ23)kˉ22α1.

Next, we derive the sequential equilibrium in game GL, in which country L leads and country S follows. The government L maximizes uL=(ALkL)kL+r(θkˉkL)+αtˉ(kSkL) taking eq. (23) into account. The tax rate chosen by country L is tL=2tˉα+[16(1θ)+3Λ]/5. Using tˉ=(tL+tS)/2 and eq. (23), we obtain the equilibrium tax rates in Game L as

tLL=911αΛ+12kˉ4α1θ15(12α)andtSL=11α2Λ+12kˉα+31θ15(12α).

Using these, we obtain the equilibrium values in Game L as kLL=kˉ+[Λ3kˉ(1θ)]/15, kSL=kˉ[Λ3kˉ(1θ)]/15, rL=0.5Ω(144kˉ+7Λ84kˉθ120kˉα)/30(12α), and tˉL=7[Λ+12kˉ(1θ)]/30(12α), which yields the utility levels when country L leads are obtained as follows:

(26)uLL=3kˉ(4+θ)+Λ15AL2α(4θ+3θ22)32θ+11θ2+165(2α1)kˉ2+(θ1)15(65α)Λ+6(2α1)Ω2α1kˉΛ(3ΩΛ)90,
(27)uSL=3kˉ(6θ)Λ15AS+2α(3876θ+13θ2)+216θ83θ210825(2α1)kˉ2+(θ1)75(17α+9)Λ+45(2α1)Ω2α1kˉ+Λ(5Ω3Λ)150.

In a similar way, we obtain the utility levels in Game GS in which country S leads and country L follows:

(28)uSS=3kˉ(4+θ)Λ15AS2α(4θ+3θ22)32θ+11θ2+165(2α1)kˉ2+(θ1)156(2α1)Ω(65α)Λ2α1kˉ+Λ(3Ω+Λ)90,
(29)uLS=3kˉ(6θ)+Λ15AL+2α(3876θ+13θ2)+216θ83θ210825(2α1)kˉ2+(θ1)7545(2α1)Ω(17α+9)Λ2α1kˉΛ(5Ω+3Λ)150.

The comparison of utility levels reveals that

uLN><uLSΛ(1θ)kˉ><247,uLL><uLNΛ(1θ)kˉ<>24(6α+1)(12α),uSN><uSLΛ(1θ)kˉ><8(3326α)23(12α),uSS><uSNΛ(1θ)kˉ<>247,

which gives Proposition 2 and the equilibrium classification in Figure 2.

E Appendix

The government i maximizes ui=ki2+rθkˉ+(1+β)[tiki+α(tjkjtiki)]. The reaction functions of countries L and S are given by

tL=(1+2β)tS+4(2(1α)β+1θ2α)k+Λ(2(1α)β+(12α))4(1α)β+34α,tS=(1+2β)tL+4(2(1α)β+1θ2α)k+Λ(2(1α)β(12α))4(1α)β+34α.

The equilibrium values in the simultaneous-move outcome are

tLN=2kˉ(12α)(1+β)+Λ(12α+2β(1α))2(2(1α)+β(32α)),tSN=2kˉ(12α)(1+β)Λ(12α+2β(1α))2(2(1α)+β(32α)),kLN=kˉ+Λ(1+β)4(2(1α)+β(32α)),kSN=kˉΛ(1+β)4(2(1α)+β(32α)),

and

rN=Ω22kˉ(2(12α)+(34α)βθ)(12α)(1+β).

Using these values, we obtain the equilibrium utility levels:

uLN=O(α,θ,β)+kˉΛ(1+β)(3θ6α+4α2+4β8αβ+4α2β)2(β(32α)+2(1α)),uSN=O(α,θ,β)kˉΛ(1+β)(3θ6α+4α2+4β8αβ+4α2β)2(β(32α)+2(1α)),

where

O(α,θ,β)θΩkˉ2+Λ2(1+β)2(4β(1α)+34α)16(β(32α)+2(1α))2+kˉ2(41αβ2+710αβ+312α421αβ+12αθ)(12α)(1+β).

In the same way as before, we can derive the equilibrium utilities in two sequential-move outcomes as [uLL(α,θ),uSL(α,θ)] and [uLS(α,θ),uSS(α,θ)].[11]

The comparison of utility levels reveal that

uLNuLS=RL{Λ(12α)(1+β)24kˉ(1+βθ)(3β2αβ+22α)}0,uLLuLN=(1+2β)2{4kˉ(1+βθ)(3β2αβ+22α)Λ(12α)(1+β)2}216(12α)2(1+β)2(3β2αβ+22α)2[42αβ+54α]>0,uSNuSL=RS{(12α)(1+β)2(14β8αβ+98α)Λ4kˉ(1+βθ)(3β2αβ+22α)(18β8αβ+118α)}0,uSSuSN=(1+2β)2{4kˉ(1+βθ)(3β2αβ+22α)Λ(12α)(1+β)2}216(12α)2(1+β)2(3β2αβ+22α)[42αβ+54α]>0,

where RL and RS are the positive constant. Hence, we obtain the followings:

uLNuLSΛkˉ4(1+βθ)(3β2αβ+22α)(12α)(1+β)2,uSNuSLΛkˉ4(1+βθ)(3β2αβ+22α)(12α)(1+β)2(18β8αβ+118α)(14β8αβ+98α),

which shows the proposition.

References

Altshuler, R., and T. Goodspeed. 2002. “Follow the Leader? Evidence on European and US Tax Competition.” Working Papers 200226, Rutgers University.Search in Google Scholar

Altshuler, R., and T. Goodspeed. 2015. “Follow the Leader? Evidence on European and US Tax Competition.” Public Finance Review 43: 485–504.10.1177/1091142114527781Search in Google Scholar

Bucovetsky, S., and M. Smart. 2006. “The Efficiency Consequences of Local Revenue Equalization: Tax Competition and Tax Distortions.” Journal of Public Economic Theory 8: 119–144.10.1111/j.1467-9779.2006.00255.xSearch in Google Scholar

Bucovetsky, S. 2009. “An Index of Capital Tax Competition.” International Tax and Public Finance 16: 727–752.10.1007/s10797-008-9093-9Search in Google Scholar

Buettner, T. 2006. “The Incentive Effect of Fiscal Equalization Transfers on Tax Policy.” Journal of Public Economics 90: 477–497.10.1016/j.jpubeco.2005.09.004Search in Google Scholar

Cardarelli, R., E. Taugourdeau, and J. Vidal. 2002. “A Repeated Interactions Model of Tax Competition.” Journal of Public Economic Theory 4: 19–38.10.1111/1467-9779.00086Search in Google Scholar

Chatelais, N., and M. Peyrat. 2008. Are Small Countries Leaders of the European Tax Competition?, Documents de travail du Centre d’Economie de la Sorbonne 2008.58-ISSN: 1955-611X.2008.Search in Google Scholar

Egger, P., M. Köthenbürger, and M. Smart. 2010. “Do Fiscal Transfers Alleviate Business Tax Competition? Evidence from Germany.” Journal of Public Economics 94: 235–246.10.1016/j.jpubeco.2009.10.002Search in Google Scholar

Eichner, T. 2014. “Endogenizing Leadership and Tax Competition: Externalities and Public Goods Provision.” Regional Science and Urban Economics 46: 18–26.10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2014.01.006Search in Google Scholar

Gaigne, C., and S. Riou. 2007. “Globalization, Asymmetric Tax Competition, and Fiscal Equalization.” Journal of Public Economic Theory 9: 901–925.10.1111/j.1467-9779.2007.00337.xSearch in Google Scholar

Hamilton, J., and S. Slutsky. 1990. “Endogenous Timing in Duopoly games: Stackelberg or Cournot Equilibria.” Games and Economic Behavior 2: 29–46.10.1016/0899-8256(90)90012-JSearch in Google Scholar

Hindriks, J., and Y. Nishimura. 2015. “A Note on Equilibrium Leadership in Tax Competition Models.” Journal of Public Economics 121: 66–68.10.1016/j.jpubeco.2014.11.002Search in Google Scholar

Hindriks, J., and Nishimura, Y. 2017. “Equilibrium Leadership in Tax Competition Models with Capital Ownership: A Rejoinder.” International Tax and Public Finance 24: 338–349.10.1007/s10797-016-9421-4Search in Google Scholar

Hindriks, J., S. Peralta, and S. Weber. 2008. “Competing in Taxes and Investment Under Fiscal Equalization.” Journal of Public Economics 92: 2392–2402.10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.11.012Search in Google Scholar

Ida, T. 2014. “International Tax Competition with Endogenous Sequencing.” International Tax and Public Finance 21: 228–247.10.1007/s10797-012-9264-6Search in Google Scholar

Itaya, J., and C. Yamaguchi. 2015. Does Endogenous Timing Matter in Implementing Partial Tax Harmonization?, Discussion paper series no. 286, Hokkaido University.Search in Google Scholar

Kawachi, K., H. Ogawa, and T. Susa. 2015. “Endogenous Timing in Tax and Public Investment Competition.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 171: 641–651.10.1628/093245615X14307274621224Search in Google Scholar

Keen, M., and K. A. Konrad 2013. The Theory of International Tax Competition and Coordination, Chapter 5. In Handbook of Public Economics, vol. 5, edited by A.J. Auerbach, R. Chetty, M. Feldstein, E. Saez, 257–328. Amsterdam: North-Holland.10.1016/B978-0-444-53759-1.00005-4Search in Google Scholar

Kempf, H., and G. Rota-Graziosi. 2010. “Endogenizing Leadership in Tax Competition.” Journal of Public Economics 94: 768–776.10.1016/j.jpubeco.2010.04.006Search in Google Scholar

Kempf, H., and G. Rota-Graziosi. 2015. “Further Analysis on Leadership in Tax Competition: The Role of Capital Ownership–A Comment.” International Tax and Public Finance 22: 1028–1039.10.1007/s10797-014-9339-7Search in Google Scholar

Köthenbürger, M. 2002. “Tax Competition and Fiscal Equalization.” International Tax and Public Finance 9: 391–408.10.1023/A:1016511918510Search in Google Scholar

Köthenbürger, M. 2005. “Leviathans, Federal Transfers, and the Cartelization Hypothesis.” Public Choice 122: 449–465.10.1007/s11127-005-7518-xSearch in Google Scholar

Köthenbürger, M. 2007. “Ex-Post Redistribution in a Federation: Implications for Corrective Policy.” Journal of Public Economics 91: 481–496.10.1016/j.jpubeco.2006.08.004Search in Google Scholar

Kotsogiannis, C. 2010. “Federal Tax Competition and the Efficiency Consequences for Local Taxation of Revenue Equalization.” International Tax and Public Finance 17: 1–14.10.1007/s10797-008-9094-8Search in Google Scholar

Ogawa, H. 2013. “Further Analysis on Leadership in Tax Competition: The Role of Capital Ownership.” International Tax and Public Finance 20: 474–484.10.1007/s10797-012-9238-8Search in Google Scholar

Ogawa, H., and T. Susa. 2017. “Majority Voting and Endogenous Timing in Tax Competition.” International Tax and Public Finance 24: 397–415.10.1007/s10797-016-9424-1Search in Google Scholar

Ogawa, H., and W. Wang. 2016. “Asymmetric Tax Competition and Fiscal Equalization in a Repeated Game Setting.” International Review of Economics and Finance 41: 1–10.10.1016/j.iref.2015.10.004Search in Google Scholar

Pi, J., and X. Chen. 2017. “Endogenous Leadership in Tax Competition: A Combination of the Effects of Market Power and Strategic Interaction.” The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 17: 1–8.10.1515/bejeap-2016-0191Search in Google Scholar

Redoano, M. 2007. “Fiscal Interactions Among European Countries: Does the EU Matter?,” CESifo Working Paper Series No.1952.10.2139/ssrn.980667Search in Google Scholar

Smart, M. 2007. “Raising Taxes Through Equalization.” Canadian Journal of Economics 40: 1188–1212.10.1111/j.1365-2966.2007.00448.xSearch in Google Scholar

Wang, W., K. Kawachi, and H. Ogawa. 2014. “Fiscal Transfer in a Repeated Interaction Model of Tax Competition.” FinanzArchiv 70: 556–566.10.1628/001522114X685483Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2018-06-08

© 2018 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 21.10.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejeap-2017-0217/html
Scroll to top button