Abstract
This paper examines the incentive to adopt a new technology resulting from common payment systems, namely mixed cost reimbursement and DRG reimbursement. Adoption is based on a cost–benefit criterion. We find that retrospective payment systems require a large enough patient benefit to yield adoption, while under DRG-linked payment, adoption may arise in the absence of patients benefits when the differential reimbursement for the old vs new technology is large enough. Also, mixed cost reimbursement leads to higher adoption under conditions on the differential reimbursement levels and patient benefits. In policy terms, mixed cost reimbursement system may be more effective than a DRG payment system to induce technology adoption. Our analysis also shows that current economic evaluation criteria for new technologies do not capture the different ways payment systems influence technology adoption. This gives a new dimension to the discussion of prospective vs retrospective payment systems of the last decades centered on the debate of quality vs cost containment.
1 Introduction
Recent decades have witnessed an increasing share of the level of spending on health care relative to the GDP (see OECD 2005a, 2005b). There is a general consensus that technological development (and diffusion) is a prime driver of this phenomenon. The recent account by Smith, Newhouse, and Freeland (2009) estimates that medical technology explains a fraction of between 27–48% (depending on different estimation techniques) of growth in the US health spending in the period 1960–2007. Despite the relatively large literature documenting empirically the impact of innovation in health care, a theoretical corpus has not been fully developed yet. In this paper we address a particular issue: the relationship between payment systems and the rate of technology adoption. To avoid unnecessary confusion, let us point out that we refer to adoption as the decision of a provider to acquire a piece of new technology available. We do not consider the process by which such a new technology has become available, nor the R&D involved in it, nor any other considerations. Neither we consider the issue of diffusion of a new technology. Our departing point is that a new way to provide some treatment has become available, and thus providers must decide whether to acquire it. An illustrative example of the situation we have in mind is the adoption of the laser technology in ophthalmology.
We contribute to the theoretical literature by setting up a model of uncertain demand, where the novelty lies in relating the technological shift to the increased benefit for patients, financial variables, and the reimbursement system to providers. We seek to assess the impact of the payment system to providers on the rate of technology adoption. We propose two payment schemes, a reimbursement according to the cost of treating patients, and a DRG payment system where the new technology may or may not be reimbursed differently from the old technology. We find that under a mixed cost reimbursement system, large enough patient benefits are necessary for adoption to occur. However, when the DRG offers a higher reimbursement for new technology, adoption occurs even in the absence of patients’ benefits. In this case, the new technology must be reimbursed sufficiently higher than the old one. Finally, to compare the levels of technological adoption in the different payment regimes, we take as reference an investment level yielding to the provider the same marginal return of investment in new technology across regimes. Mixed cost reimbursement leads to higher adoption of the new technology if the rate of reimbursement is high relative to the margin of new vs old DRG. Having larger patient benefits favors more adoption under the mixed cost reimbursement payment system, provided that adoption occurs initially under both payment systems. In policy terms, it may well be the case that for some objectives of the regulator regarding the level of technological adoption, a retrospective payment system to the providers is more effective than a prospective reimbursement system. This opens again the discussion of prospective versus retrospective payment systems in a wider framework than the debate of quality vs cost containment developed along the last decade. To evaluate the impact of the adoption of new technology, we study how adjusting the parameters of the payment function affect adoption for a given level of total expenditure. We use this approach as a proxy for a welfare analysis of adoption, due to the inherent difficulties in our model to define a social welfare function for the health authority. We obtain that under risk neutrality, more mixed cost reimbursement always increases adoption. More generally, risk aversion leads to ambiguity of how the level of adoption adjusts to changes in the payment system.
In general, the main findings in the empirical literature can be grouped in three related classes: (i) technological development induces an increase in health care expenditures, (ii) the reimbursement system in the health care sector has an impact on the R&D effort, and (iii) the R&D effort determines the type of technological development, either brand new technology, or improvements in existing technologies (or both).
Some of the main conclusions of this mainly empirical literature stress the fact that (a) prospective payment systems encourage cost efficient new technologies but have perverse effects on quality improvement, and (b) retrospective payment systems encourage quality but dim sensitivity toward cost efficiency. Illustrative references include Di Tommaso and Schweitzer (2005), OECD (2005c), Bodenheimer (2005), Duggan and Evans (2005), and Bokhari (2009).
Sorenson et al. (2014) report on the use of separate payments, supplementary payments, and cost-outlier funding to compensate the short-run lack of information in the initial stages of the adoption of a new technology. These payments are either additional funds or retrospective reimbursement of reported costs beyond the DRG system. New technologies adopted must satisfy a set of criteria for the hospital to receive the additional funds. Among them, (i) costs exceeding standard deviation of the respective DRGs; (ii) apply the new technology to a sufficiently large base of patients; and (iii) being more cost effective compared with existing services. The review of experiences in Sorenson et al. (2014) reveals that diversity exists, with different approaches being adopted within the DRG-like payment framework. In some cases, a new DRG is created, while in others extra payments are negotiated. The use of (negotiated) supplemental payments on top of DRG value to pay for innovation is close to what we term below as mixed payment systems. These supplemental payments pay cover fully or partially the cost of the innovation (for a review of the UK NHS experience, see Sorenson, Drummond, and Wilkinson 2013). An illustration of this diversity is provided by the diffusion of drug eluting stents in Italy during the early 2000s, as described in Capellaro, Ghislandi, and Anessi-Pessina (2011): the Italian health system is decentralized to the regional level and it introduced an ad hoc DRG to accommodate the new technology in some regions while in others different extra payments in existing DRGs were adopted. They find that hospitals funded by DRG had higher technology adoption than hospitals paid by global budget (linked to the region’s capitation and not paying explicitly for innovation).
The findings advanced in the empirical literature link health care expenditure and technology diffusion based on a number of factors, including (i) the degree of substitutability/complementarity between the old and new technologies, (ii) the efficiency of the innovation in terms of effort reduction and output improvement, (iii) the impact of expenses of the adoption of new technologies in accordance with the treatment expansion and treatment substitution effects, (iv) the presence of agents whose objective functions need not be profit maximization, and (v) the characteristics of the health care system, its financing and regulation.
These and other elements determine the incentives to develop and diffuse new medical technologies. However, there are very few theoretical models providing support to the empirical modeling, and allowing for addressing the incentives for technological development, the rate of its diffusion in the health care system, or the welfare effects of the adoption of such (expensive) medical innovations. Among those few contributions we find Goddeeris (1984a, 1984b), Baumgardner (1991), and Selder (2005), who examine the effects of technical innovation on the insurance market, and Miraldo (2007) who studies the feed-back effects between the health care and the R&D sectors, Grebel and Wilfer (2010) who study the diffusion of two competing technologies, and Levaggi, Moretto, and Pertile (2010) who consider how the uncertainty on patients’ benefits affects the incentives to invest in new technologies.
There are several relevant topics that we do not address in our analysis. One is the role of the malpractice system, with extra tests and procedures ordered in response to the perceived threat of medical malpractice claims (Kessler and McClellan 1996). On the effects of hospital competition on health care costs see Kessler and McCellan (2000). Another topic is the use of technology assessment criteria to measure the value of new health care technologies brought about by R&D investments. Economic evaluation (cost–benefit analysis) of new technologies is common in pharmaceutical innovation and has led to a wide body of literature, both on methodological principles and on application to specific products. For a recent view on the interaction between R&D and health technology assessment criteria, see Philipson and Jena (2006).
Most of our analysis is set in the context of a health care sector organized around a NHS. We do not explicitly account for a specific role of the private sector in the provision of health care services as a driver in the adoption of new available technologies. Our analysis is applicable to both private and public sectors to the extent that they use the payment mechanisms we explore below. At this point of the analysis, we do not include strategic aspects related to the adoption decision. Rather, we focus in the decision making of an isolated hospital trading off costs and benefits given some popular reimbursement schemes.
The structure of the paper is as follows. Section 2 introduces the model and behavioral assumptions. Sections 3 and 4 deal with the adoption decision of a new technology under the different payment regimes. Section 5 compares the levels of adoption across payment schemes. Section 6 studies whether the different reimbursement regimes induce over- or under adoption with respect to the first-best associated with the social welfare. A section with conclusions and a technical appendix close the paper.
2 The model
We consider a semi-altruistic provider, who values financial results (represented by an increasing and concave utility function,
The potential population of patients is known (from say, epidemiological studies). It is represented by
The uncertainty on demand gives content to the problem. Should demand be deterministic the hospital would know before hand the capacity to be used with the new technology, and thus the decision to adopt would become trivial. Also, the endogenous character of
Adoption of a new technology is an investment decision in capacity to treat patients, represented by a continuous endogenous variable
Uncertainty is symmetric for the two technologies. In other words, we assume the total number of patients is uncertain, not how many treatments will be required with the new technology. Implicitly, this implies the new technology represents a step forward in the development of the treatment rather than a break through improvement.
Note that uncertainty over the actual number of patients induces uncertainty over the use of the new technology (even though we assume it is used prior to the old one, up to capacity), and thus over the financial result of the investment. We capture this uncertainty by assuming a risk adverse behavior on the part of the hospital. Also note that risk neutrality would imply that the marginal valuation of the financial results of the hospital is independent of its level of activity.
Finally, we also consider the patients’ benefits as the criterion for the use of the new technology. Patients are treated with the new technology up to capacity, and if there is demand left, it is treated with the old technology. This is a simple mechanism that in our context of homogeneous patients is meaningful. More general set-ups where patients are differentiated in severity allow for more sophisticated mechanisms (see Siciliani 2006, and Hafsteinsdottir and Siciliani 2010 for the analysis of treatment selection mechanisms when patients differ in severity).
Hospitals receive a payment transfer R. Such payment may be prospective, retrospective, or mixed. We will analyze two payment systems. On the one hand, we will study a mixed cost reimbursement scheme flexible enough to accommodate total mixed cost reimbursement, fixed fee/capitation, and partial mixed cost reimbursement. On the other hand, we look at the effects of a DRG-based payment system with payments by sickness episode. [3] We assume that the payer can commit to the rule announced. Otherwise, “hold-up” issues à la Bös and de Fraja (2002) could arise.
The new technology has an investment cost per patient treated of p.
[4] There is also a constant marginal cost per patient treated, given by
We assume that the average and marginal costs of the new technology is higher than the corresponding average and marginal costs of the old technology:
Assumption 1
With this assumption we capture the generally accepted claim that new technologies are not cost savers relative to existing ones and are one of the main drivers of the cost inflation in the health care sectors in developed countries. Of course, a technology with more benefits and lower costs poses no trade-off to adoption decisions, in particular if the condition in Assumption 1 is reversed. Note that the assumption allows marginal cost of treatment-only in the new technology to be lower that in the old one (
We abstract from explicitly considering fixed costs. As the optimal adoption decision is made of marginal arguments, they do not play a role. Implicitly, we are assuming that demand is large enough to cover for the fixed cost.
Patient benefits measured in monetary units are given by
Economic evaluation criteria will often require that incremental benefits from the new technology exceed incremental costs, that is:
Assumption 2Economic evaluation criterion for approval of new technology requires incremental benefits greater than incremental costs from the new technology. That is,
Hereinafter, whenever we mention that economic evaluation criteria (or health technology assessment) are used, we mean that incremental benefits are greater than incremental costs (or equivalently Assumption 2 holds). [5]
The expected utility for the hospital decision maker is given by the valuation of the financial results of the hospital and by valuation of patients’ benefits from treatment.
This function captures a semi-altruistic provider who weights its private benefits and the social benefits implicitly through the function V and the parameter
The other element of the utility function of the hospital is made up of benefits to patients. These are
The (adoption) decision problem of the hospital is to choose the level
Note that the question that we tackle is not the design of an optimal payment system to incentivate adoption, but the study the impact of some popular reimbursement systems (see Mossialos and Le Grand 1999) on the level of adoption of new technology.
To clarify the intuition behind some of the results, we illustrate their content with a restricted version of the model characterized by risk-neutrality and a uniform distribution
An assumption maintained throughout the analysis is the fact that the new technology does not convey any demand expansion. It is often argued that new technologies generate new protocols and treatments that can be applied to patients already under treatment but also opens the possibility to treat other patients for which the previous technology was not well-suited. In terms of our model, we can accommodate this feature by assuming that the old technology can treat a maximum of
3 Technology adoption under mixed cost reimbursement
Let us assume that the hospital is reimbursed according to the cost of treating patients. We want to characterize the optimal choice of
The total cost depends on the level of realized demand and is defined as the fixed cost of investment in the new technology (
We propose a mixed cost reimbursement system flexible enough to accommodate a total cost reimbursement, a partial cost reimbursement, and a fixed fee/capitation payment system. The system is described by (Ellis and McGuire 1986):
where TC stands for total cost and
To keep the model as simple as possible we do not introduce an explicit participation constraint for the provider. In turn, this implies that we assume that R will always suffice to guarantee a non-negative surplus for the provider. In other words, we implicitly assume that the regulator selects
Substituting eqs [5] into [4] the hospital’s utility function becomes
The problem of the hospital is to identify the value of
In words,
Proposition 1Under a mixed cost reimbursement system, full adoption is never optimal (utility-maximizing) for the provider. Patients’ benefits above a threshold ensure positive adoption for every level of reimbursement the payment system may define.
Proof. The optimal level of adoption
Note that for
Looking at the second order condition, after noting that
Given that by construction
Remark 1Positive patients’ benefits are a necessary condition for adoption given the assumption of no cost savings in treatment with the new technology and both technologies being reimbursed in the same way (
To gain insight into the content of this proposition note that the first term in eq. [7] represents the marginal gain from treating one additional patient with the new technology when the realized demand is greater than
Assume now risk neutrality (
or
The second-order condition guarantees that the denominator of the fraction is positive.
Note that we cannot state whether, or not, passing a health technology assessment criterion (assumption 2) is restrictive over the desired adoption level by health care providers. To see it, rewrite eq. [9] as,
The sign of the first term is given by assumption 2. If it is satisfied is positive, otherwise is non-positive. The second term is negative, and the last term is positive. Therefore, it may well be that for certain constellations of parameters, the optimal adoption level is achieved even without satisfying assumption 2. In other words, assumption 2 is sufficient but not necessary for adoption. Thus imposing that it must hold by law will clash in some cases with the decision of the semi-altruistic provider. For
Under risk neutrality, uniform distribution, and
Note that the assumption
Remark 2Interestingly enough, the usual cost–benefit rule does not capture the mechanism through which payments systems induce adoption.
We introduced the cost–benefit assessment rule in assumption 2. It can be rewritten as
On the other hand, the rule governing the optimal level of adoption is given by eq. [8], that can be rewritten as
where
3.1 Cost-sharing and optimal technology adoption
We are interested in assessing how adoption changes with the level of mixed cost reimbursement. In other words, we want to study the impacts of a variation of
Technically, we want to compute the sign of
Let us thus compute,
Recall that we have assumed a concave utility function V, that is
In a similar fashion, we study the impact of a variation of
Given the concavity of
Remark 3Under risk neutrality, the level of technology adoption is insensitive to
Given that
3.2 Technological adoption under an exogenous budget
The previous comparative statics exercise says that in general, higher transfers lead to higher levels of technology adoption by the hospital, because the increased patients’ benefits offset the increased marginal cost (assumption 2). A full analysis of the impact of the adoption of the new technology requires the definition of a reference point, or of a common threshold. In our case, it is not obvious how to define either of them. Accordingly, we propose two alternatives. One consists in assuming a given budget on the level of adoption; the alternative assumes that the hospital’s expected surplus is constant. In this way, we have a well-defined reference point to evaluate the consequences of technological adoption. We consider first the case where the budget to invest in the adoption of the new technology is given.
Consider keeping payment constant in expected terms, that is,
To assess the impact on the level of adoption, besides adjusting the parameters
Remark 4Under risk neutrality, moving to more mixed cost reimbursement always increases adoption, even if (expected) payment is kept constant overall. Risk aversion leads to ambiguity of how the level of adoption adjusts to changes in the payment system.
We can examine the ambiguity induced by the presence of risk aversion. The solution of the system [38] is given by (see Appendix B),
Note that the numerators in eq. [12] have an ambiguous sign. They are positive iff
To assess the impact on hospital utility, while maintaining
The first term of eq. [13] is zero because we are evaluating the impact on hospital utility at
The intuition under risk aversion follows the same lines of reasoning as before. The hospital only improves its utility through patients’ benefits. Then, any increase in the cost sharing favors adoption because the new technology improves patients’ benefits. Given that total payment remains constant, the increase in cost sharing is adjusted through a lower
Remark 5Keeping the expected payment constant implies no change in the objective function when changing the parameters of the mixed cost reimbursement system.
Remark 4 and remark 5 together tell us that a move toward more reimbursement leads to more adoption. Thus, the extra benefits to patients are compensated with a lower surplus for the hospital to maintain the objective function constant.
3.3 Constant hospital surplus
A potential alternative to fixing the level of expenditure of the health care system, we could envisage a set-up where the expected surplus of the hospital is kept constant. Denote such surplus as S. It is defined as,
Similarly as in the previous case, we have a system of two equations given by the adjustment of parameters
Remark 6Under risk neutrality and constant trade-off of surplus against patient benefits, an increase in the mixed cost reimbursement adjusted in a way that total expected surplus of the hospital remains constant, results in an increase in the objective function. This results from patients’ benefits due to more adoption given the absence of costs to raising money for the payment to be made.
4 Technology adoption under DRG payment
Consider a health care system where the provision of services is reimbursed using a DRG catalog. A DRG payment system means that a fixed amount is paid for every type of disease. We are considering a single-disease model, where two technologies are available. We will distinguish two cases. The first one consists in paying the hospital the same amount regardless of the technology used. We term it as homogenous DRG reimbursement. It corresponds to a situation where each patient treated is an episode originating a payment through a given DRG and technology adoption will keep the DRG. Hence the payment received by the hospital remains constant. In the second case the level of reimbursement is conditional upon the choice of technology to provide treatment. It is interpreted as a situation where adoption of technology leads to the coding of the sickness episode in a different DRG, receiving a different payment. In this sense we refer to it as heterogeneous DRG reimbursement. As before, we assume that R will always suffice to guarantee a non-negative surplus for the provider.
4.1 Homogeneous DRG reimbursement
Let us consider first that the adoption of a new technology does not convey a variation in the DRG classification. Then, the payment received by the hospital for patients treated is defined as,
Substituting eqs [15] into [4] the hospital’s utility function becomes,
Let us define the net revenues obtained when the new technology can cover all the demand (
Proof. The optimal level of adoption is given as before, by the solution of the first-order condition,
For
Remark 7Note that sufficiently large patients’ benefits are necessary for the first-order condition [17] to have an interior solution. Otherwise, the hospital optimally does not adopt the new technology.
Let us consider a simplified version of the model by assuming risk neutrality, a uniform distribution for the number of patients, and without loss of generality
This simplified version of the model allows us to obtain an explicit solution of the optimal level of technical adoption. It is given by,
The denominator of eq. [19] is positive from the second-order condition. Thus,
Note that under homogenous DRG payment systems, adoption by the health care provider occurs (i.e.
Remark 8Note that
Next, we look at the comparative statics analysis of the impact of the level of reimbursement K on adoption. It follows from,
Given the concavity of
Remark 9Risk aversion is a necessary condition for the DRG payment being able to affect the level of adoption.
4.2 Heterogeneous DRG reimbursement
Assume now that the hospital is reimbursed conditionally upon the technology used in the treatments. This makes sense as long as the costs of the new and old technologies are sufficiently disperse so that each treatment falls in a different DRG, which typically elicits a different payment. With this framework in mind, let us define
where
Now the utility function of the hospital is given by,
Proof. The first-order condition characterizing the optimal level of adoption is
For
Remark 10Note that in contrast with the case of homogenous DRG, now patients’ benefits may not be necessary for adoption to occur if the margin the hospital obtains with the new technology, (
To gain some intuition of the level of adoption, assume risk neutrality, and a uniform distribution once again. Also, normalize
so that,
and second-order conditions guarantee that the denominator of the fraction is positive. Note that
In this case, technology adoption by the health care provider will always be greater than implied by application of the health technology assessment. That is, in cases where economic evaluation indicates no adoption of the new technology (
Summarizing we have obtained that assuming the hospital obtains a higher margin with the new technology than with the old one, is a sufficient condition for adoption (because the new technology produces no harm). However, it is not necessary. In particular, we will observe adoption when such assumption does not hold but patients’ benefits are large enough. In other words, patients’ benefits are a necessary condition for adoption but not sufficient.
5 Comparing payment regimes
We have presented the adoption decision under two payment regimes, mixed cost reimbursement, and DRG payments. The respective optimal levels are difficult to compare. The very particular scenario of risk neutrality (under the form of
Let us recall the expressions for the respective levels of adoption under mixed cost reimbursement and DRG payment systems, given by eqs [9], [19] and [22] respectively, and let
where the superscripts cr, hom and het refer to the mixed cost reimbursement, homogeneous DGR, and heterogeneous DRG respectively. Direct comparison of the difference in adoption levels yields:
Comparison between the adoption levels across DRG regimes is clear cut. Under heterogeneous DRG reimbursement the optimal level of technical adoption is greater than under homogeneous DRG reimbursement. This is not surprising. The hospital has more incentive to invest in the new technology when the payment associated with it is larger than the payment for the old technology.
To interpret expression [27], suppose the provider decides to invest an amount p in the new technology under the DRG system. Such investment allows to treat one extra patient with the new technology. The benefits to the provider in our setting under additive utility and risk neutrality, are the gain in patients’ benefits (
Consider now the same investment under the mixed cost reimbursement payment system. Since the provider knows that it will obtain a reimbursement

Optimal adoption: CR vs heterogeneous DRG
We represent this comparison in Figure 1. The dividing line represents the locus of
Note that as the new technology embodies higher patients’ benefits compared to the old one, the constellation of
A similar argument can be put forward to analyze expression [28]. The net gains to the provider of an additional unit of the new technology under a homogenous DRG reimbursement scheme are
6 Welfare analysis
So far we have identified the levels of technology adoption under different reimbursement rules and we have compared them as well, under some particular conditions. To complete the analysis we need to assess whether these payment rules induce over-adoption or under-adoption with respect to the first-best associated with the social welfare.
For our purpose, we define the social welfare, in line with Levaggi, Moretto, and Pertile (2010)) and the literature in general, as the difference between benefits and costs. To obtain explicit solutions and compare them with the corresponding adoption levels in eqs [23], [24] and [25], we shall assume again risk neutrality and a uniform distribution and also normalize
where
The expected revenues under the different reimbursements rules are given by
6.1 Mixed cost reimbursement rule
After substituting eqs [30] into [29] we compute the first-order condition:
Solving for
This is the welfare maximizing level of adoption under the mixed cost reimbursement rule. We want to compare this level of adoption
A direct comparison of eqs [23] and [33] yields
Accordingly, under mixed cost reimbursement the provider over-adopts the new technology with respect to a welfare maximizing policy. The intuition behind the result comes from the fact that the provider does not bear the full cost of the adoption.
6.2 Homogeneous DRG reimbursement rule
Substituting eqs [31] into [29] we compute the first-order condition,
Solving for
Now, comparing eqs [24] and [34] we obtain
That is for
6.3 Heterogeneous DRG reimbursement rule
Substituting eqs [32] into [29] we compute the first-order condition,
Solving for
A direct comparison of eqs [25] and [35] yields
Again, as under mixed cost reimbursement, the provider over-adopts the new technology. The intuition now relies in the fact that the new technology has a higher reimbursement thus providing the incentives to over-invest in the new technology.
Note that the same (qualitative) results are obtained if we do not consider the social cost of public funds (
7 Final remarks
Adoption of new technologies is usually considered a main driver of growth of health care costs. [10] Arguments in favor of cost–benefit analysis (health technology assessment) before the introduction of new technologies has made its way into policy. We now observe in many countries the requirement of an “economic test” before payment for new technologies is accepted by third-party payers (either public or private). This is especially visible in the case of new pharmaceutical products and it has a growing trend in medical devices.
However, there is a paucity of theoretical work related to the determinants of adoption and diffusion of new technologies. We contribute toward filling this gap.
The novelty of our approach consists in allowing for an integrated treatment of payment systems and the incentives they create for adoption of new technology under demand uncertainty. We identify conditions for adoption under two common different payment systems. Also, we compare technology adoption across reimbursement systems in a simplified set-up. We now summarize the main results.
Under a mixed cost reimbursement system, large enough patient benefits are required for adoption to occur. As long as patient benefits are above a certain threshold, adoption of the new technology always occurs at strictly positive levels. However, it is never optimal to expand the level of adoption to cover all demand (full adoption). The threshold is given, in the case of risk neutrality and uniform distribution for patient benefits, by the cost of treating a patient under the new technology accounting for the savings resulting from not treating him under the old technology. The mixed cost reimbursement allows for the extreme cases of full mixed cost reimbursement and capitation (a fixed fee is paid, regardless of actual costs).
The other payment system we have considered is prospective payments on a sickness episode basis (the DRG system). Two different regimes can be envisaged regarding the impact of using a new technology in the payment received by the provider. In the first one, the treatment performed with the new technology is classified into the same DRG (and payment made by the third-party payer) as the old technology. The second possibility is that the new technology leads to a payment in a different DRG. When the DRG is not adjusted by the use of a new technology, patients’ benefits are necessary to induce adoption. Whenever the DRG for payment of the new technology has a higher price, adoption may occur even in the absence of patients’ benefits. However in that case, the margin gained with the new DRG associated with treatment must be sufficiently high to compensate the cost of adoption. As in the case of mixed cost reimbursement, full adoption is not optimal either with prospective reimbursements schemes, regardless of whether the reimbursement rate differs or not between the new and the old technology.
The role of patient benefits is a crucial one. The desired levels of technology adoption of health care providers can be compared with the implications of requiring technology adoption to pass a health technology assessment (incremental benefit above incremental cost). Except for the case of a new technology being paid in the same DRG of the old technology, private adoption levels are always higher than allowed by this criterion. This holds the testable prediction that health care providers will always find, in the other payment systems, regulation imposing health technology assessments to be actively constraining their decisions. Thus, they will voice the complaint that regulation reduces their desired level of adoption.
Under parameters for the payment systems in which adoption always occurs, mixed cost reimbursement leads to greater adoption of the new technology if the rate of reimbursement is high relative to the margin of new vs old technology under DRG. A larger patient benefit favors more adoption under the mixed cost reimbursement payment system, provided adoption occurs initially under both payment systems (i.e. in the case of uniform distribution of demand and risk neutrality, when patient benefits from the new technology are positive).
To evaluate the impact of technology adoption we keep fixed the level of total expenditure of the health system and study the impact on adoption of adjustments in the parameters of the payment function. Under risk neutrality the result is clear-cut: more mixed cost reimbursement induces more adoption. However, results are ambiguous under risk aversion. Thus, in policy terms, our analysis also vindicates the virtues (under sufficiently large difference between the DRGs of the competing technologies) of retrospective payment systems as a driver toward adoption of a new technology after a decade where the debate between cost containment versus quality issues has favored prospective reimbursement over mixed cost reimbursement. A full assessment of this issue would require an investigation of the optimal definition of policy parameters within each reimbursement scheme. This is left for future research. Also, we compare adoption levels under the different reimbursement rules to its first-best level. We find that under homogeneous DRG reimbursement, given that both technologies are reimbursed at the same price the provider’s decision is driven by cost minimization concerns allowing to adopt optimally. Under the other rules the provider always over-invests in the new technology although for different reasons. Under mixed cost reimbursement the cost sharing between provider and payer induces the former with incentives to adopt the new technology beyond the optimal level. Under heterogeneous DRG reimbursement it is the price difference.
In our analysis we assume that the new technology does not convey any demand expansion. We can accommodate the popular argument that new technologies generate new protocols and treatments that can be applied to patients already under treatment but also opens the possibility to treat other patients for which the previous technology was not well-suited. Simply we need to assume that the old technology can treat a maximum of
We do not explicitly address the issue of uniqueness of the solutions. Our main concern lies in studying the adoption decision. Should multiple solutions exist, we would be forced to introduce more structure in the model to implement a selection criterion. However, qualitatively the intuitions would remain unaltered.
Our analysis also shows that standard health technology assessment (economic evaluation studies) does not capture the channels by which payment mechanisms may lead to more (or less) adoption.
Our model and results are the first to theoretically address the role of payment systems in the adoption of new technologies. In contrast with the theoretical contributions referenced in the introduction, our analysis does not look at adoption as the result of the interaction of the health care sector with other sectors of the economy, but as the strict consequence of the reimbursement system in place. The results obtained are to be used to interpret empirical evidence that addresses speed of diffusion of new technologies and payment systems. Some caveats are worth pointing out. First, we take a relationship between the provider and the third-party payer to take place without influence from other forces. In particular, there is no role for competition between hospitals in our model. Second, investment in the new technology is perfectly lumpy. It is done once and it cannot be adjusted further within the same time frame of uncertain demand. Third, we acknowledge the limitation of the analysis associated to not considering how the payment system will affect the number and type of new technologies available rather than simply whether existing technologies are adopted. Finally, we also acknowledge the difficulties both for patients and providers to assess the level of patient benefits. In the same vein, there may be substantial heterogeneity across patients with respect to the net health benefits. Both features will blur the distinction between the effect and desirability of one payment system versus another.
The model proposed in the analysis is static because we focus the attention in the decision of technological adoption. Closely related to adoption we find the diffusion of technology that is a dynamic phenomenon. Although beyond the scope of the present analysis, we can link our model to existing literature on technological diffusion by considering as a reference point the ``epidemic" model, and assume information on the existence of the new technology follows a word of mouth diffusion process in which the main source of information is previous users.
[11] In this context we can envisage hospitals that have already adopted the new technology until today and a (probabilistic) mechanism by which a hospital running the old technology contacts with a hospital that has adopted the new technology. Then, we propose to link our results on adoption to the diffusion process assuming that the “infection” is determined by
Acknowledgments
We acknowledge our gratitude to A. McGuire for an inspiring presentation delivered at the APES Conference held in Coimbra in November 2005, and David Cutler, Pau Olivella, Rosella Levaggi, several anonymous referees, and participants in several seminars and conferences for comments and suggestions. Financial support of Acção Integrada E97/04 and PTDC/Eco/71867/2006 (Pedro P. Barros) and partial support from research projects 2009SGR-169, ECO2012-31962 and the Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness, through the Severo Ochoa Programme for Centres of Excellence in R&D (SEV-2011-0075) (Xavier Martinez-Giralt) is gratefully acknowledged. Xavier Martinez-Giralt is affiliated professor of the Barcelona Graduate School of Economics. The usual disclaimer applies.
Appendix
Appendix A
A.1 Welfare analysis under an exogenous budget
Assuming that the payment to the hospital remains constant after adjusting the parameters
Finally, let us recall the first-order condition [7] characterizing the optimal value of
Thus, we have a system of equations given by eqs [36] and [37], that we can write in a compact form as
where we use the following notation:
Note that if we assume risk neutrality, the system simplifies to
where
Appendix B
B.1 Technical analysis of Remark 4
The first-order condition for the hospital is given by,
To obtain the impact of the policy change on technology adoption (that is, on
Total differentiation of the first-order condition yields,
Substituting
and further collecting terms, eq. [43] becomes,
The first two terms in square brackets in the right-hand side are positive, while the third and fourth terms have negative signs. Therefore the impact on
This can be made clearer in the special case of risk neutrality, that is
The first two terms of eq. [45] are positive, whilst the last one is positive if
To better assess the meaning of this result, assume
In this case, a decrease in the price of treating patients with the new technology, at the cost of increasing the price of consumables does result in a smaller adoption level (and consequently a lower diffusion rate) of the new technology. This result holds for a sufficiently high value of
Also,
To address the welfare effect to the hospital, the impact on the utility of the decision maker, by application of the envelope theorem, is given by
Noting that,
expression [46] can be rewritten as
implying
Therefore, in general, the subsidization of equipment has a negative impact on a hospital’s utility due to the extra costs associated with consumables.
Appendix C
C.1 Welfare analysis under constant hospital surplus
Totally differentiating eq. [14] allows us to introduce the restriction of keeping the hospital surplus constant as,
As before, we have a system of two equations given by eqs [37] and [48], which in compact form are
where we use the following notation:
Imposing risk neutrality to better assess its content, the system [49] simplifies to,
so that
Finally, note that
Assume under risk neutrality that
References
Abbey, D. C.2009. Health Care Payment Systems. New York: An introduction. CRC Press.10.1201/b10253Suche in Google Scholar
Armstrong, M., and D. E. M.Sappington. 2007. “Recent Developments in the Theory of Regulation.” In Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol 3, chapter 27, edited by M.Armstrong and R.Porter, 1557–700. Amsterdam: Elsevier North-Holland.10.1016/S1573-448X(06)03027-5Suche in Google Scholar
Baron, D., and R.Myerson. 1982. “Regulating a Monopolist with Unknown Costs.” Econometrica50(4):911–30.10.2307/1912769Suche in Google Scholar
Baumgardner, J. R.1991. “The Interaction Between Forms of Insurance Contract and Types of Technical Change in Medical Care.” RAND Journal of Economics22:36–53.10.2307/2601006Suche in Google Scholar
Bodenheimer, T.2005. “High and Rising Health Care Costs.” Annals of Internal Medicine142:932–37. Part 2: Technologic Innovation10.7326/0003-4819-142-11-200506070-00012Suche in Google Scholar
Bokhari, F. A. S.2009. “Managed Care Competition and the Adoption of Hospital Technology: The Case of Cardiac Catheterization.” International Journal of Industrial Organization27:223–37.10.1016/j.ijindorg.2008.08.001Suche in Google Scholar
Bös, D., and G.de Fraja. 2002. “Contracts for Health Services: Quality versus Excess Capacity.” Journal of Public Economics84:199–218.10.1016/S0047-2727(01)00125-6Suche in Google Scholar
Capellaro, G., S.Ghislandi, and E.Anessi-Pessina. 2011. “Diffusion of Medical Technology: The Role of Financing.” Health Policy100(1):51–9.10.1016/j.healthpol.2010.10.004Suche in Google Scholar
Culyer, A. J., and J. P.Newhouse. 2000. Handbook of Health Economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier North-Holland.Suche in Google Scholar
Di Tommaso, M.Schweitzer, S. O., eds. 2005. Health Policy and High-Tech Industrial Development. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.10.4337/9781845424565Suche in Google Scholar
Duggan, M. G., and W. N.Evans. 2005. “Estimating the Impact of Medical Innovation: The Case of HIV Antiretroviral Treatments.” NBER, Working paper No. 11109.10.3386/w11109Suche in Google Scholar
Ellis, R., and T.McGuire. 1986. “Provider Behavior under Prospective Reimbursement: Cost Sharing and Supply.” Journal of Health Economics5(2):129–51.10.1016/0167-6296(86)90002-0Suche in Google Scholar
Geroski, P. A.2000. “Models of Technology Diffusion.” Research Policy29:603–25.10.1016/S0048-7333(99)00092-XSuche in Google Scholar
Godager, G., T.Iversen, and C. A.Ma. 2015. “Competition, Gatekeeping, and Health Care Access.” Journal of Health Economics 39:159–70.10.1016/j.jhealeco.2014.11.005Suche in Google Scholar
Goddeeris, J. H.1984a. “Medical Insurance, Technological Change, and Welfare.” Economic EnquiryXXII:56–67.Suche in Google Scholar
Goddeeris, J. H.1984b. “Insurance and Incentives for Innovation in Medical Care.” Southern Economic Journal51(2):530–39.10.2307/1057830Suche in Google Scholar
Grebel, T., and T.Wilfer. 2010. “Innovative Cardiological Technologies: A Model of Technology Adoption, Diffusion, and Competition.” Economies of Innovation and New Technology19(4):325–47.10.1080/10438590802482019Suche in Google Scholar
Hafsteinsdottir, E. J. G., and L.Siciliani. 2010. “DRG Prospective Payment Systems: Refine or Not Refine.” Health Economics19:1226–39.10.1002/hec.1547Suche in Google Scholar
Kessler, D. P., and M. B.McClellan. 1996. “Do Doctors Practice Defensive Medicine?” The Quarterly Journal of Economics111(2):353–90.10.2307/2946682Suche in Google Scholar
Kessler, D. P., and M. B.McClellan. 2000. “Is Hospital Competition Socially Wasteful?” The Quarterly Journal of Economics115(2):577–615.10.1162/003355300554863Suche in Google Scholar
Laffont, J. J., and J.Tirole. 1986. “Using Cost Observation to Regulate Firms.” Journal of Political Economy94(3):614–41.10.1086/261392Suche in Google Scholar
Levaggi, R., M.Moretto, and P.Pertile. 2010. “Static and Dynamic Efficiency of Irreversible Health Care Investments under Alternative Payment Rules, Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei.” Nota Di Lavoro130:2010.10.2139/ssrn.1709400Suche in Google Scholar
Liu, T., and A. C.Ma. 2013. “Health Insurance, Treatment Plan, and Delegation to Altruistic Physician.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization85:79–96.10.1016/j.jebo.2012.11.002Suche in Google Scholar
Miraldo, M.2007. Hospital Financing and the Development and Adoption of New Technologies. Center for Health Economics, University of York. CHE Research Paper 26.Suche in Google Scholar
Mossialos, E. and J.Le Grand, eds. 1999. Health Care and Cost Containment in the European Union. Aldershot: Ashgate.Suche in Google Scholar
OECD. 2005a. OECD Health Data 2005. Paris: OECD.Suche in Google Scholar
OECD. 2005b. Health at a Glance: OECD Indicators 2005. Paris: OECD.Suche in Google Scholar
OECD. 2005c. Health Technologies and Decision Making. Paris: OECD.10.1787/9789264016224-enSuche in Google Scholar
Philipson, T. J., and A. B.Jena. 2006. “Surplus Appropriation from R&D and Health Care Technology Assessment Procedures.” NBER Working paper No. 12016.10.3386/w12016Suche in Google Scholar
Selder, A.2005. “Physician Reimbursement and Technology Adoption.” Journal of Health Economics24:907–30.10.1016/j.jhealeco.2005.03.004Suche in Google Scholar
Siciliani, L.2006. “Selection Treatment under Prospective Payment Systems in the Hospital Sector.” Journal of Health Economics25:479–99.10.1016/j.jhealeco.2005.09.007Suche in Google Scholar
Smith, S., J. P.Newhouse, and M. S.Freeland. 2009. “Income, Insurance, and Technology: Why Does Health Spending Outpace Economic Growth.” Health Affairs28:1276–84.10.1377/hlthaff.28.5.1276Suche in Google Scholar
Sorenson, C., M.Drummond, A.Torbica, G.Callea, and C.Mateus. 2014. “The Role of Hospital Payments in the Adoption of New Technologies: An International Survey of Current Practice.” Health Economics, Policy and Law, available on CJO2014. doi:10.1017/S1744133114000358.10.1017/S1744133114000358Suche in Google Scholar
Sorenson, C., M.Drummond, and G.Wilkinson. 2013. “Use of Innovation Payments to Encourage the Adoption of New Medical Technologies in the English NHS.” Health Policy and Technology2(3):168–73.10.1016/j.hlpt.2013.05.001Suche in Google Scholar
©2015 by De Gruyter
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Frontmatter
- Advances
- Effects of Fatherhood on Male Wage and Labor Supply in Japan
- Energy Taxes and Oil Price Shocks
- Contributions
- International Factor Mobility, Production Cost Components, and Wage Inequality
- Eliminating Persistent Statistical Discrimination: An Analysis of Several Policy Options
- Effects of Childcare Subsidies on Employment and Earnings of Low-Income Mothers
- Flexibility Policies and Re-employment Probabilities in Italy
- Extended Unemployment Insurance and Job Search: Evidence from Time Use Data
- Financing High-tech Start-ups: Moral Hazard, Information Asymmetry and the Reallocation of Control Rights
- Technological Adoption in Health Care – The Role of Payment Systems
- Topics
- The Effect of Vertically Differentiated Entry Under Retail-Minus Access Pricing
- Is the Highway Patrol Really Tougher on Out-of-State Drivers? An Empirical Analysis
- Antitrust as Facilitating Factor for Collusion
- Price Disclosure Rules and Consumer Price Comparison
- Nurse Practitioners and Their Effects on Visits to Primary Care Physicians
- A Model of the Academic Review Process with Informed Authors
- Discriminatory Pricing and Spatial Competition in Two-Sided Media Markets
- Income Inequality and Health: Panel Data Evidence from Canada
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Frontmatter
- Advances
- Effects of Fatherhood on Male Wage and Labor Supply in Japan
- Energy Taxes and Oil Price Shocks
- Contributions
- International Factor Mobility, Production Cost Components, and Wage Inequality
- Eliminating Persistent Statistical Discrimination: An Analysis of Several Policy Options
- Effects of Childcare Subsidies on Employment and Earnings of Low-Income Mothers
- Flexibility Policies and Re-employment Probabilities in Italy
- Extended Unemployment Insurance and Job Search: Evidence from Time Use Data
- Financing High-tech Start-ups: Moral Hazard, Information Asymmetry and the Reallocation of Control Rights
- Technological Adoption in Health Care – The Role of Payment Systems
- Topics
- The Effect of Vertically Differentiated Entry Under Retail-Minus Access Pricing
- Is the Highway Patrol Really Tougher on Out-of-State Drivers? An Empirical Analysis
- Antitrust as Facilitating Factor for Collusion
- Price Disclosure Rules and Consumer Price Comparison
- Nurse Practitioners and Their Effects on Visits to Primary Care Physicians
- A Model of the Academic Review Process with Informed Authors
- Discriminatory Pricing and Spatial Competition in Two-Sided Media Markets
- Income Inequality and Health: Panel Data Evidence from Canada