Home Existence of solutions to contact mean-field games of first order
Article Open Access

Existence of solutions to contact mean-field games of first order

  • Xiaotian Hu and Kaizhi Wang EMAIL logo
Published/Copyright: July 22, 2022

Abstract

This paper deals with the existence of solutions of a class of contact mean-field game systems of first order consisting of a contact Hamilton-Jacobi equation and a continuity equation. Evans found a connection between Hamilton-Jacobi equations and continuity equations from the weak KAM point of view, where the coupling term is zero. Inspired by his work, we prove the main existence result by analyzing the properties of the Mather set for contact Hamiltonian systems.

MSC 2010: 37J51; 35Q89

1 Introduction

The mean-field game system was introduced by Lasry and Lions [21,22,23] and Caines, Huang, and Malhamé [18,19]. In this paper, we only discuss first-order mean-field game systems. It is a coupled system of partial differential equations, one Hamilton-Jacobi equation and one continuity equation. From the view of control theory, a Hamilton-Jacobi equation with an external mean-field term is standard. The mean-field term involves a probability distribution governed by a continuity equation, which depends on the feedback and the viscosity solution [11] of the Hamilton-Jacobi equation. The idea of equilibrium states in the mean-field games theory, which are distributed along optimal trajectories generated from the feedback strategy, is quite enlightening.

In some situations, the ergodic mean-field game system

(1.1) K ( x , D u ) = F ( x , m ) + c ( m ) in X , div m K p ( x , D u ) = 0 in X , X m d x = 1

can be described as the limit system of a finite time ( T > 0 ) horizon mean-field game system

t u T + K ( x , D u T ) = F ( x , m T ( t ) ) in ( 0 , T ) × X , t m T div m T K p ( x , D u T ) = 0 in ( 0 , T ) × X , m T ( 0 ) = m 0 , u T ( T , x ) = u f ( x ) , x X ,

as T goes to infinity. See [4,5,7] for this kind of results, where the state space X is T n = R n / Z n , R n and Ω R n . Obviously, ensuring the existence of solutions to the ergodic mean-field game system is an important issue.

We point out that the works of Evans [12] prior to mean-field games revealed the connection between a Hamilton-Jacobi equation and a continuity equation with F = 0 . Let us see how to obtain a solution of (1.1) from the weak KAM point of view.

In this paper, we always use M to denote a connected, closed (compact, without boundary), and smooth manifold endowed with a Riemannian metric. We choose, once and for all, a C Riemannian metric g . Since all the Riemannian metrics are equivalent on the compact manifold M , the superlinearity assumption ((H2) below) imposed on the Hamiltonian does not depend on the choice of the Riemannian metric. A simple example is M = T n . Denote by diam ( M ) the diameter of M . We will denote by ( x , v ) a point of the tangent bundle T M with x M and v a vector tangent at x . The projection π : T M M is ( x , v ) x . The notation ( x , p ) will designate a point of the cotangent bundle T M with p T x M . Consider a Hamiltonian K = K ( x , p ) : T M R , which is C 2 , superlinear and strictly convex in p . Such a Hamiltonian is called a Tonelli Hamiltonian. We can associate with K a Lagrangian, as a function on T M : l ( x , v ) = sup p T x M { p , v x K ( x , p ) } , where , x represents the canonical pairing between the tangent and cotangent space. Sometimes, we use p v to denote p , v x for simplicity.

Let μ be a Mather measure [26] for the Euler-Lagrange equation:

(1.2) d d t l v = l x .

Then μ is a closed measure (see, for instance, [2]), i.e.,

T M v D φ ( x ) d μ = 0 , φ C 1 ( M ) ,

where C k ( M ) ( k N ) stands for the function space of continuously differentiable functions on M . Recall that

supp ( μ ) A ˜ = ( u , u + ) ( x , v ) T M : u ( x ) = u + ( x ) , D u ( x ) = D u + ( x ) = l v ( x , v ) ,

where A ˜ is the Aubry set for Lagrangian system (1.2), and the intersection is taken on the pairs ( u , u + ) of conjugate functions, i.e., u (resp. u + ) is a backward (resp. forward) weak KAM solution of

(1.3) K ( x , D u ) = c ( K )

and u = u + on the projected Mather set of system (1.2). Here, π ˜ , where ˜ is the union of supports of Euler-Lagrange flow Φ t l -invariant probability measures supported in A ˜ , called the Mather set. The symbol c ( K ) denotes the Mañé critical value of K . See Section 2 for the definition and representation formulas of Mañé’s critical value. Let u be an arbitrary backward weak KAM solution (or equivalently [13], viscosity solution) of equation (1.3), and let σ π μ , where π μ denotes the push-forward of μ through π . Then for each φ C 1 ( M ) ,

0 = supp ( μ ) v D φ ( x ) d μ = supp ( σ ) K p ( x , D u ( x ) ) D φ ( x ) d σ = M K p ( x , D u ( x ) ) D φ ( x ) d σ ,

which means that σ is a solution of the continuity equation

div σ K p ( x , D u ) = 0

in the sense of distributions.

In view of the aforementioned arguments, one can deduce that if there is a Borel probability measure m on M such that l ( x , v ) + F ( x , m ) admits a Mather measure η m with

(1.4) m = π η m ,

then for any viscosity solution u of

K ( x , D u ) = F ( x , m ) + c ( m ) ,

where c ( m ) is the Mañé critical value of K ( x , p ) F ( x , m ) , the pair ( u , m ) is a solution of (1.1), i.e., the Hamilton-Jacobi equation is satisfied in viscosity sense and the continuity equation is satisfied in the sense of distributions. So, to find such a solution of (1.1), it suffices to find a probability measure m satisfying (1.4).

In this paper, we aim to prove the existence of solutions of the following contact mean-field game system:

H ( x , u , D u ) = F ( x , m ) in M , ( 1.5 a ) div m H p ( x , u , D u ) = 0 in M , ( 1.5 b ) M m d x = 1 ( 1.5 c )

using dynamical approaches. Note that the Hamiltonian H = H ( x , u , p ) in (1.5) is defined on T M × R , where ( x , p ) T M and u R . Since the characteristic equations of (1.5a) is a contact Hamiltonian system, we call (1.5) a contact mean-field game system. In the view of the essential differences between weak KAM results for Hamiltonian and contact Hamiltonian systems, we cannot use the aforementioned idea directly to obtain the existence of solutions. A more careful analysis of the structure of Mather sets of contact Hamiltonian systems is needed.

We now list some basic assumptions on H and F , which will be made in most of the results of this paper. Assume that the contact Hamiltonian H is of class C 3 and satisfies:

  1. Positive definiteness: For every ( x , u , p ) T M × R , the second partial derivative 2 H / p 2 ( x , u , p ) is positive definite as a quadratic form;

  2. Superlinearity: For each x M , the function p H ( x , 0 , p ) is superlinear on the fiber T x M ;

  3. Strict monotonicity: There are constants δ > 0 and λ > 0 such that for every ( x , u , p ) T M × R ,

    δ < H u ( x , u , p ) λ ;

  4. Reversibility: H ( x , u , p ) = H ( x , u , p ) for all ( x , u , p ) T M × R .

Remark 1

In view of (H2) and (H3), one can deduce that for every ( x , u ) M × R , H ( x , u , p ) is superlinear in p . Here, we assume that H is of class C 3 , since we will use some dynamical results on the Aubry-Mather theory for contact Hamiltonian systems obtained in [32] under the C 3 assumption.

Example 1

Discounted Hamiltonians

H ( x , u , p ) = ξ u + K ( x , p ) , ξ > 0 ,

where K ( x , p ) is a smooth reversible Tonelli Hamiltonian and satisfies assumptions (H1)–(H4). Discounted Hamilton-Jacobi equations appear in some optimal control problems (see, e.g., [1]).

We denote by P ( M ) the set of Borel probability measures on M , and by P ( T M ) the set of Borel probability measures on T M . Both sets are endowed with the weak- convergence. A sequence { μ k } k N P ( X ) is weakly- convergent to μ P ( X ) , denoted by μ k w μ , if

lim k X f ( x ) d μ k = X f ( x ) d μ , f C b ( X ) ,

where C b ( X ) denotes the function space of bounded uniformly continuous functions on X with X = M , T M . Let us recall that P ( M ) is compact for this topology. We shall work with the Monge-Wasserstein distance defined, for any m 1 , m 2 P ( M ) , by

d 1 ( m 1 , m 2 ) = sup h M h d ( m 1 m 2 ) ,

where the supremum is taken over all the maps h : M R , which are 1-Lipschitz continuous. P 1 ( T M ) denotes the Wasserstein space of order 1, the space of probability measures with the finite moment of order 1.

Let F : M × P ( M ) R be a function, satisfying the following assumptions:

  1. For every measure m P ( M ) , the function x F ( x , m ) is of class C 2 ( M ) and

    F sup m P ( M ) α 1 D α F ( , m ) < + ,

    where α = ( α 1 , , α n ) , D α = D x 1 α 1 D x n α n , and denotes the supremum norm;

  2. F ( , ) and D x F ( , ) are continuous on M × P ( M ) ;

  3. For every x M , the function m F ( x , m ) is Lipschitz continuous and

    sup x M m 1 , m 2 P ( M ) m 1 m 2 F ( x , m 1 ) F ( x , m 2 ) d 1 ( m 1 , m 2 ) < + .

Example 2

Let F ( x , m ) = f ( x ) q ( m ) , where f : M R is of class C 2 , and q : P ( M ) R is Lipschitz. Then

F ( , m ) = f ( ) q ( m ) , D x F ( , m ) = D f ( ) q ( m ) F , m P ( M ) ,

for some F > 0 ; F ( , ) = f ( ) q ( ) and D x F ( , ) = D f ( ) q ( ) are continuous on M × P ( M ) ; for each x M , each m 1 , m 2 P ( M ) ,

F ( x , m 1 ) F ( x , m 2 ) = f ( x ) ( q ( m 1 ) q ( m 2 ) ) f Lip ( q ) d 1 ( m 1 , m 2 ) .

Definition 1

A solution of the contact mean-field game system (1.5) is a couple ( u , m ) C ( M ) × P ( M ) such that (1.5b) is satisfied in distribution sense and (1.5a) is satisfied in viscosity sense.

The main result is stated as follows.

Theorem 1

Assume (H1)–(H4) and (F1)–(F3). There exists at least one solution ( u , m ) of the contact mean-field game system (1.5), which has clear dynamical meaning. More precisely, there is a Mather measure μ m for the contact Hamiltonian system (1.6) such that m = π x μ m , where π x : T M × R M denotes the canonical projection.

Remark 2

  1. Our methods depend on the analysis of dynamical behavior of the following contact Hamiltonian system:

    (1.6) x ˙ = H m p ( x , u , p ) , p ˙ = H m x ( x , u , p ) H m u ( x , u , p ) p , u ˙ = H m p ( x , u , p ) p H m ( x , u , p ) ,

    where H m ( x , u , p ) H ( x , u , p ) F ( x , m ) for all ( x , u , p ) T M × R .

  2. The notion of Mather measures was introduced by Mather in [26] for convex Hamiltonian systems, while the one for convex contact Hamiltonian systems was introduced in [32], where part of Aubry-Mather and weak KAM theories for Hamiltonian systems was extended to contact Hamiltonian systems under assumptions (H1) and (H2) and strict increasing condition in the argument u . See [25,27] for Aubry-Mather and weak KAM results for discounted Hamiltonian systems.

  3. u is Lipschitz and thus, differentiable almost everywhere. Furthermore, u is of class C 1 , 1 on the Mather set of system (1.6), and thus, D u ( x ) exists for m -a.e. x M [32, Proposition 4.2].

  4. m satisfies (1.5b) in the sense of distributions, that is,

    M D φ ( x ) , H p ( x , u ( x ) , D u ( x ) ) x d m ( x ) = 0 , φ C 1 ( M ) .

  5. Let K ( x , p ) be a Tonelli Hamiltonian. Mean-field game systems where the Hamiltonian has the following form:

    H ¯ ( x , u , p ) = u + K ( x , p ) ,

    which appears in certain free-market economy models, see, for instance, [16]. It is clear that H ¯ ( x , u , p ) is a specific example of the Hamiltonians satisfying (H1)–(H3). To the best of our knowledge, Theorem 1 is the first step toward understanding contact mean-field game systems from a dynamical point of view.

See, for example, [8,9, 10,17,20] for recent progresses on first-order mean-field games. [14] by Gomes and Saude is a good survey on mean-field games. We also refer the readers to [15] by Gomes et al. for many interesting aspects of mean-field games.

2 Weak KAM results for Hamiltonian and contact Hamiltonian systems

We recall some weak KAM type results for Tonelli Hamiltonian systems and Tonelli contact Hamiltonian systems. Results presented in Section 2.1 come from [13], and the ones in Section 2.2 come from [31,32].

2.1 Weak KAM results for Hamiltonian systems

2.1.1 Mañé’s critical value

Let K denote a Tonelli Hamiltonian on T M and let l denote the associated Tonelli Lagrangian on T M as given in Section 1. If [ a , b ] is a finite interval and γ : [ a , b ] M is an absolutely continuous curve, we define its l action as follows:

A l ( γ ) = a b l ( γ ( s ) , γ ˙ ( s ) ) d s .

The following estimate for action A l ( ) will be used later.

Proposition 1

([13, Proposition 4.4.4]) For every given t > 0 , there exists a constant C t < + , such that, for each x , y M , there is a C curve γ : [ 0 , t ] M with γ ( 0 ) = x , γ ( t ) = y , and A l ( γ ) C t .

The Mañé critical value of the Lagrangian l , which was introduced by Mañé in [24], is defined by c ( l ) sup { k R : A l + k ( γ ) < 0 for some absolutely continuous closed curve γ } . The Mañé’s critical value has several other representation formulas:

c ( l ) = inf u C 1 ( M ) max x M K ( x , D u ( x ) ) = inf μ T M l ( x , v ) d μ ,

where the second infimum is taken with respect to all Borel probability measures on T M invariant by the Euler-Lagrange flow Φ t l . Furthermore, c ( l ) is the unique value of e for which K ( x , D u ) = e admits a viscosity solution. In the following, we also call c ( l ) the Mañé critical value of the Hamiltonian K , denoted by c ( K ) .

2.1.2 Weak KAM solutions

A backward weak KAM solution of equation (1.3) is a function u : M R such that

  1. u ( x ) u ( y ) inf s > 0 { inf α A l ( α ) + c ( K ) s } , x , y M , where the second infimum is taken over all the absolutely continuous curves α : [ 0 , s ] M with α ( 0 ) = y and α ( s ) = x ;

  2. for every x M , there exists a curve γ x : ( , 0 ] M with γ x ( 0 ) = x such that

    u ( x ) u ( γ ( t ) ) = t 0 l ( γ x ( s ) , γ ˙ x ( s ) ) d s c ( K ) t , t ( , 0 ] .

Fathi introduced this notion and showed that for Tonelli Hamiltonians, backward weak KAM solutions and viscosity solutions of equation (1.3) are the same [13, Theorem 7.6.2]. Similarly, one can define forward weak KAM solutions of equation (1.3).

Proposition 2

([13], Proposition 4.2.1) The family of viscosity solutions of equation (1.3) is equi-Lipschitz with the Lipschitz constant Lip ( u ) B + c ( K ) , where

B = sup { l ( x , v ) : ( x , v ) T M , v x = 1 } ,

where x denotes the norm on T x M induced by a Riemannian metric.

2.2 Weak KAM results for contact Hamiltonian systems

2.2.1 Admissibility

Definition 2

(Admissibility). We call a contact Hamiltonian H ( x , u , p ) is admissible, if there exists a R such that c ( H ( x , a , p ) ) = 0 , where c ( H ( x , a , p ) ) denotes the Mañé critical value of the classical Hamiltonian H ( x , a , p ) .

Under assumptions (H1), (H2), and 0 H u λ , it was proved in [32, Appendix B] that H ( x , u , p ) is admissible if and only if the equation

(2.1) H ( x , u , D u ) = 0

admits at least a viscosity solution. It was also proved in [32, Remark 1.2] that a contact Hamiltonian H ( x , u , p ) satisfying (H1), (H2), and (H3) is admissible, and thus, equation (2.1) has at least a viscosity solution. Furthermore, under (H1), (H2), and (H3), equation (2.1) has a unique viscosity solution, see, for instance, [32, Proposition A.1] for a proof. Denote by u the unique viscosity solution. Moreover, u is Lipschitz on M .

From now on till the end of Section 2, we always assume (H1)–(H3).

2.3 Backward weak KAM solutions and calibrated curves

Let Φ t H denote the local flow of

(2.2) x ˙ = H p ( x , u , p ) , p ˙ = H x ( x , u , p ) H u ( x , u , p ) p , u ˙ = H p ( x , u , p ) p H ( x , u , p ) .

The Legendre transform : T M × R T M × R defined by

: ( x , u , p ) x , u , H p ( x , u , p )

is a diffeomorphism. By using , we can define the contact Lagrangian L ( x , u , v ) associated with H ( x , u , p ) as follows:

L ( x , u , v ) sup p T x M { v , p x H ( x , u , p ) } .

Then L ( x , u , v ) and H ( x , u , p ) are Legendre transforms of each other, depending on conjugate variables v and p respectively. Let Φ t L = Φ t H 1 . We call Φ t L the Euler-Lagrange flow.

Following Fathi, one can define backward weak KAM solutions of equation (2.1) as follows. A function u C ( M ) is called a backward weak KAM solution if: (i) for each continuous piecewise C 1 curve γ : [ t 1 , t 2 ] M ,

u ( γ ( t 2 ) ) u ( γ ( t 1 ) ) t 1 t 2 L ( γ ( s ) , u ( γ ( s ) ) , γ ˙ ( s ) ) d s ;

(ii) for each x M , there exists a C 1 curve γ x : ( , 0 ] M with γ x ( 0 ) = x such that

u ( x ) u ( γ x ( t ) ) = t 0 L ( γ x ( s ) , u ( γ x ( s ) ) , γ ˙ x ( s ) ) d s , t < 0 .

Backward weak KAM solutions and viscosity solutions are still the same [32, Proposition 2.7]. Thus, equation (2.1) has a unique backward weak KAM solution u . The curves in (ii) are called ( u , L , 0 ) -calibrated curves. We can also define forward weak KAM solutions of equation (2.1). Note that backward and forward weak KAM solutions of equation (1.3) always exist in pairs [13, Theorem 5.1.2]. But, this is not the case for equation (2.1), see, for instance, [32, Example 1.1].

Proposition 3

([32], Proposition 4.1) Given x M , if γ : ( , 0 ] M is a ( u , L , 0 ) -calibrated curve with γ ( 0 ) = x , then ( γ ( t ) , u ( γ ( t ) ) , p ( t ) ) satisfies equations (2.2) on ( , 0 ) , where p ( t ) = L v ( γ ( t ) , u ( γ ( t ) ) , γ ˙ ( t ) ) .

Let us recall two semigroups of operators introduced in [31]. Define a family of nonlinear operators { T t } t 0 from C ( M ) to itself as follows. For each φ C ( M ) , denote by ( x , t ) T t φ ( x ) the unique continuous function on ( x , t ) M × [ 0 , + ) such that

T t φ ( x ) = inf γ φ ( γ ( 0 ) ) + 0 t L ( γ ( τ ) , T τ φ ( γ ( τ ) ) , γ ˙ ( τ ) ) d τ ,

where the infimum is taken among absolutely continuous curves γ : [ 0 , t ] M with γ ( t ) = x . { T t } t 0 is called the backward solution semigroup. The infimum can be achieved. Similarly, one can define another semigroup of operators { T t + } t 0 , called the forward solution semigroup, by

T t + φ ( x ) = sup γ φ ( γ ( t ) ) 0 t L ( γ ( τ ) , T t τ + φ ( γ ( τ ) ) , γ ˙ ( τ ) ) d τ ,

where the supremum is taken among absolutely continuous curves γ : [ 0 , t ] M with γ ( 0 ) = x . These two semigroups can be regarded as the contact counterparts of the Lax-Oleinik semigroups for classical Lagrangians defined on T M .

Proposition 4

([32], Propositions 2.9, 2.10) For each φ C ( M ) , the uniform limit lim t + T t φ exists and lim t + T t φ = u . The uniform limit lim t + T t + u exists. Let u + = lim t + T t + u . Then u + is a forward weak KAM solution of equation (2.1).

See [13] for the convergence result for the Lax-Oleinik semigroups associated with autonomous Lagrangian systems l ( x , v ) , and [28,29,30] for the convergence and rate of convergence results for a kind of modified Lax-Oleinik semigroups associated with time-periodic Lagrangian systems z ( t , x , v ) .

Proposition 5

([32], Lemma 4.7) Let u + be as in Proposition 4. For any given x M with u ( x ) = u + ( x ) , there exists a curve γ : ( , + ) M with γ ( 0 ) = x such that u ( γ ( t ) ) = u + ( γ ( t ) ) for each t R , and

u ± ( γ ( t ) ) u ± ( γ ( t ) ) = t t L ( γ ( s ) , u ± ( γ ( s ) ) , γ ˙ ( s ) ) d s , t t R .

Moreover, u ± are differentiable at x with the same derivative D u ± ( x ) = L v ( x , u ± ( x ) , γ ˙ ( 0 ) ) .

2.3.1 Aubry and Mather sets

We recall the definitions of Mather sets and Aubry sets for (2.2) now. We define a subset of T M × R associated with u by G u cl ( { ( x , u , p ) : x is a point of differentiability of u , u = u ( x ) , p = D u ( x ) } ) , where cl ( S ) denotes the closure of S T M × R .

Define the Aubry set for (2.2) by

A ˜ H t 0 Φ t H ( G u ) .

A ˜ H is nonempty, compact, and Φ t H -invariant [32]. Then there exist Borel Φ t H -invariant probability measures supported in A ˜ H . We call these measures Mather measures and denote by M the set of Mather measures. The Mather set is defined by

˜ H = cl ( μ M supp ( μ ) ) .

We call A H π x A ˜ H and H π x ˜ H , the projected Aubry set and the projected Mather set, respectively. The projection π x : T M × R M induces a bi-Lipschitz homeomorphism from A ˜ H to A H [32, Theorem 1.3]. We also have that [32, Theorem 1.3, Formula (1.15)]

(2.3) A ˜ H = G u G u + { ( x , u , p ) T M × R : H ( x , u , p ) = 0 , u = u ( x ) } ,

where u + is as in Proposition 4, and G u + cl ( { ( x , u , p ) : x is a point of differentiability of u + , u = u + ( x ) , p = D u + ( x ) } ) .

We will also use the following notations:

˜ L ( ˜ H ) T M × R , A ˜ L ( A ˜ H ) T M × R .

Proposition 6

([32], Theorem 1.5) Given x M , let γ : ( , 0 ] M be a ( u , L , 0 ) -calibrated curve with γ ( 0 ) = x . Let u u ( x ) , p L x ˙ ( x , u , γ ˙ ( 0 ) ) , where γ ˙ ( 0 ) denotes the left derivative of γ ( t ) at t = 0 . Let α ( x , u , p ) be the α -limit set of ( x , u , p ) . Then

α ( x , u , p ) A ˜ H ,

where A ˜ H denotes the Aubry set for system (2.2).

3 Existence of solutions of mean-field game system

3.1 Mather sets of reversible contact Hamiltonian systems

Under the assumptions (H1)–(H4), we can take a closer look at the Mather set of (2.2).

Proposition 7

Let

K H { ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) : H ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) = 0 } .

Then K H is a nonempty compact subset of the Mather set ˜ H .

Proof

Since H is strictly convex and reversible in p , then by the Legendre transform, we have

L ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) = sup p T x M H ( x , u ( x ) , p ) = inf p T x M H ( x , u ( x ) , p ) = H ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) , x M .

For any ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) K H , let γ ( t ) x for t 0 . Then u ( γ ( t ) ) u ( x ) and γ ˙ ( t ) 0 . Note that

t 0 L ( γ ( s ) , u ( γ ( s ) ) , γ ˙ ( s ) ) d s = t 0 L ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) d s = 0 , t 0 .

Thus, we obtain that

u ( x ) u ( γ ( t ) ) = t 0 L ( γ ( s ) , u ( γ ( s ) ) , γ ˙ ( s ) ) d s , t 0 ,

implying that γ is a ( u , L , 0 ) -calibrated curve with γ ( 0 ) = x . Thus, by Proposition 3, we obtain that

γ ( t ) , u ( γ ( t ) ) , L v ( γ ( t ) , u ( γ ( t ) ) , γ ˙ ( t ) ) = ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) , t 0 ,

which satisfies equation (2.2). It means that ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) is a fixed point of the flow Φ t H . Thus, the α -limit set of ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) is a singleton { ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) } . From Proposition 6, the α -limit set of ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) is contained in the Aubry set A ˜ H , and thus, we deduce that ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) A ˜ H . Since each point in K H is a fixed point of the flow Φ t H , then K H ˜ H .

Next we show that K H is nonempty. Assume by contradiction that K H = . There would be two possibilities: (Case I) H ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) > 0 , x M ; (Case II) H ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) < 0 , x M .

(Case I): For any ( x , p ) T M , since H ( x , u ( x ) , p ) H ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) > 0 , then the set

{ ( x , u ( x ) , p ) : H ( x , u ( x ) , p ) = 0 } = .

Recall (2.3), i.e., A ˜ H { ( x , u ( x ) , p ) : H ( x , u ( x ) , p ) = 0 } . Since A ˜ H is nonempty, then { ( x , u ( x ) , p ) : H ( x , u ( x ) , p ) = 0 } is nonempty, a contradiction.

(Case II): Since

L ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) = H ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) > 0 , x M ,

then

(3.1) L ( x , u ( x ) , v ) L ( x , u ( x ) , 0 ) > 0 , ( x , v ) T M .

Recall that the Mather set ˜ L A ˜ L is nonempty. Taking an arbitrary ( x 0 , u 0 , v 0 ) ˜ L , let ( x ( t ) , u ( t ) , x ˙ ( t ) ) = Φ t L ( x 0 , u 0 , v 0 ) for t R . Then x ( t ) is a ( u , L , 0 ) -calibrated curve implying that

(3.2) u ( x ( t ) ) u ( x 0 ) = 0 t L ( x ( s ) , u ( x ( s ) ) , x ˙ ( s ) ) d s , t > 0 .

In fact, since ( x 0 , u 0 , v 0 ) ˜ L , then by the definition of the Aubry set and (2.3), one can deduce that u 0 = u ( x 0 ) and v 0 = H p ( x 0 , u ( x 0 ) , D u ( x 0 ) ) . In view of Proposition 5, there is a ( u , L , 0 ) -calibrated curve γ : ( , + ) M with γ ( 0 ) = x 0 and γ ˙ ( 0 ) = H p ( x 0 , u ( x 0 ) , D u ( x 0 ) ) . Then by Proposition 3,

( γ ( t ) , u ( γ ( t ) ) , H p ( γ ( t ) , u ( γ ( t ) ) , D u ( γ ( t ) ) ) = Φ t L ( x 0 , u 0 , v 0 )

for all t R . Thus, x ( t ) = γ ( t ) for all t R .

Since ( x 0 , u 0 , v 0 ) ˜ L , then ( x 0 , u 0 , v 0 ) belongs to the support of some Φ t L -invariant probability measure, and thus by Poincaré’s recurrence theorem, we obtain ( x 0 , u 0 , v 0 ) ω ( x 0 , u 0 , v 0 ) , where ω ( x 0 , u 0 , v 0 ) denotes the ω -limit set of the orbit ( x ( t ) , u ( t ) , x ˙ ( t ) ) . Thus, there exists { t n } n N with t n + , such that x ( t n ) x 0 1 n . By (3.2), we deduce that

(3.3) 0 t n L ( x ( s ) , u ( x ( s ) ) , x ˙ ( s ) ) d s = u ( x ( t n ) ) u ( x 0 ) K u x ( t n ) x 0 K u n ,

where K u > 0 is the Lipschitz constant of u . For n large enough, combining (3.1) and (3.3) leads to a contradiction.

Hence, K H is nonempty. In view of the compactness of M , it is clear that K H is also compact.□

Proposition 8

K H = ˜ H .

Proof

Since H ( x , u , p ) is strictly convex in p and H ( x , u , p ) = H ( x , u , p ) for all ( x , u , p ) T M × R , then it is direct to see that H p ( x , u , p ) p 0 , where equality holds if and only if p = 0 .

Let ( x ( t ) , u ( t ) , p ( t ) ) be an arbitrary trajectory in the Mather set ˜ H . Then in view of ˜ H A ˜ H G u and the differentiability of u on A H , we deduce that

( x ( t ) , u ( t ) , p ( t ) ) = ( x ( t ) , u ( x ( t ) ) , D u ( x ( t ) ) ) .

Note that

d d t u ( x ( t ) ) = H p ( x ( t ) , u ( x ( t ) ) , D u ( x ( t ) ) ) D u ( x ( t ) ) H ( x ( t ) , u ( x ( t ) ) , D u ( x ( t ) ) ) = H p ( x ( t ) , u ( x ( t ) ) , D u ( x ( t ) ) ) D u ( x ( t ) ) .

Then d d t u ( x ( t ) ) 0 and d d t u ( x ( t ) ) = 0 if and only if D u ( x ( t ) ) = 0 . If there is t 0 R such that D u ( x ( t 0 ) ) = 0 , then in view of the proof of the aforementioned proposition, ( x ( t 0 ) , u ( x ( t 0 ) ) , D u ( x ( t 0 ) ) ) is a fixed point of Φ t H . If D u ( x ( t ) ) 0 for all t R , then d d t u ( x ( t ) ) > 0 for all t R , which contradicts the recurrence property of points in the Mather set ˜ H . Hence, one can deduce that ˜ H consists of fixed points, which have the form ( x , u ( x ) , D u ( x ) ) with H ( x , u ( x ) , D u ( x ) ) = 0 . So far, we have proved that ˜ H K H , which together with Proposition 7 finishes the proof.□

3.2 Proof of Theorem 1

For each m P ( M ) , H m ( x , u , p ) H ( x , u , p ) F ( x , m ) is a Hamiltonian on T M × R . When H satisfies (H1)–(H4), so does H m . Thus, H m is admissible for all m P ( M ) . Let a m R be such that the Mañé critical value of H ( x , a m , p ) F ( x , m ) is 0, that is,

0 = inf x M ( L ( x , a m , 0 ) + F ( x , m ) ) = sup x M ( H ( x , a m , 0 ) F ( x , m ) ) .

Lemma 1

There is a constant D 1 > 0 such that a m D 1 for all m P ( M ) .

Proof

For any x M , any a R ,

H ( x , a , 0 ) = H ( x , 0 , 0 ) + H u ( x , θ , 0 ) a ,

for some θ R depending on x and a . Recall that 0 < δ H u ( x , u , p ) for all ( x , u , p ) T M × R .

If a > 0 , then H ( x , a , 0 ) H ( x , 0 , 0 ) + δ a . So, we deduce that lim a + H ( x , a , 0 ) = + uniformly in x M . If a < 0 , then H ( x , a , 0 ) H ( x , 0 , 0 ) + δ a . So, we deduce that lim a H ( x , a , 0 ) = uniformly in x M .

By the definition of a m , we obtain that

(3.4) 0 = sup x M ( H ( x , a m , 0 ) F ( x , m ) ) .

Then one can deduce that the set { a m } m P ( M ) is bounded. In fact, if it is unbounded from above, then there would be a sequence a m i + as i + . By the aforementioned arguments we obtain that lim i + H ( x , a m i , 0 ) = + uniformly in x M , which together with the boundedness of F implies for i large enough (3.4) cannot hold true, a contradiction. If the set { a m } m P ( M ) is unbounded from below, we can obtain a contradiction in a similar manner.□

Remark 3

Lemma 1 still holds ture when H satisfies (H1)–(H3). In fact, since a m satisfies

0 = inf u C 1 ( M ) max x M ( H ( x , a m , D u ( x ) ) F ( x , m ) ) ,

then

(3.5) 0 max x M ( H ( x , a m , 0 ) F ( x , m ) ) .

Conversely, for any u C 1 ( M ) , there must be a point x u M such that D u ( x u ) = 0 since M is compact and closed. Thus, we have that

max x M ( H ( x , a m , D u ( x ) ) F ( x , m ) ) H ( x u , a m , 0 ) F ( x u , m ) ,

implying

(3.6) 0 min x M ( H ( x , a m , 0 ) F ( x , m ) ) .

By similar arguments used in the proof of Lemma 1, we can deduce from (3.5), (3.6), and (H3) that { a m } m P ( M ) is bounded.

The following result is a direct consequence of Proposition 2 and Lemma 1.

Lemma 2

For each m P ( M ) , let w m denote an arbitrary viscosity solution of

(3.7) H ( x , a m , D w ) F ( x , m ) = 0 .

Then { w m } m P ( M ) is equi-Lipschitz with a Lipschitz constant D 2 > 0 given by

D 2 sup { L ( x , u , v ) + F : ( x , u , v ) T M × R , u D 1 , v x = 1 } .

Define

h t m ( x , y ) inf γ 0 t ( L ( γ ( s ) , a m , γ ˙ ( s ) ) + F ( γ ( s ) , m ) ) d s , x , y M ,

where the infimum is taken among the absolutely continuous curves γ : [ 0 , t ] M with γ ( 0 ) = x and γ ( t ) = y . By definition and Lemma 2, for any x , y M and any t > 0 , we deduce that

(3.8) h t m ( x , y ) w m ( y ) w m ( x ) D 2 diam ( M ) , m P ( M ) ,

which means that h t m ( x , y ) is bounded from below.

The proof of the following lemma is quite similar to the one of Proposition 1; thus, we omit it here.

Lemma 3

For each given t > 0 , there is a constant E t R such that for any x , y M , there is a C curve γ : [ 0 , t ] M with γ ( 0 ) = x , γ ( t ) = y and

0 t ( L ( γ ( s ) , a m , γ ˙ ( s ) ) + F ( γ ( s ) , m ) ) d s E t , m P ( M ) ,

where E t is given by

E t t E ˜ t , E ˜ t sup L ( x , u , v ) + F : ( x , u , v ) T M × R , u D 1 , v x diam ( M ) t .

Let w m ( x ) w m ( x ) w m ( 0 ) , where w m is as in Lemma 2. Then w m is still a viscosity solution of (3.7) and w m ( 0 ) = 0 . From Lemma 2, Lemma 3, and [13, Lemma 5.3.2 (4)], one can deduce that for any given t 0 > 0 , if t t 0 , then

(3.9) h t m ( x , y ) E t 0 + 2 w m E t 0 + 2 D 2 diam ( M ) , x , y M , m P ( M ) .

We provide a proof of (3.9) in the Appendix.

Based on (3.8) and (3.9), we can obtain the following result.

Proposition 9

Given any t 0 > 0 , for any ϕ C ( M ) , there is a constant D t 0 , ϕ > 0 such that

T t m ϕ ( x ) D t 0 , ϕ , ( x , t ) M × [ t 0 , + ) , m P ( M ) ,

where { T t m } t 0 denotes the backward solution semigroup associated with L ( x , u , v ) + F ( x , m ) .

Proof

Let T t a m denote the backward Lax-Oleinik operator associated with L ( x , a m , v ) + F ( x , m ) , i.e., for each φ C ( M ) and each t 0 ,

T t a m φ ( x ) inf γ φ ( γ ( 0 ) ) + 0 t ( L ( γ ( τ ) , a m , γ ˙ ( τ ) ) + F ( γ ( τ ) , m ) ) d τ ,

where the infimum is taken among absolutely continuous curves γ : [ 0 , t ] M with γ ( t ) = x . The infimum can be achieved.

Boundedness from above: for ( x , t ) M × [ t 0 , + ) with T t m ϕ ( x ) > a m , let γ : [ 0 , t ] M be a minimizer of T t a m ϕ ( x ) . Consider the function s T s m ϕ ( γ ( s ) ) for s ( 0 , t ] . Since T 0 m ϕ ( γ ( 0 ) ) = ϕ ( γ ( 0 ) ) and T t m ϕ ( x ) > a m , then there exists s 0 [ 0 , t ) such that T s 0 m ϕ ( γ ( s 0 ) ) max { ϕ ( γ ( 0 ) ) , a m } and T s m ϕ ( γ ( s ) ) > a m for s ( s 0 , t ] . Hence, by (H3), (3.8), and (3.9), we have that

T t m ϕ ( x ) T s 0 m ϕ ( γ ( s 0 ) ) + s 0 t ( L ( γ ( s ) , T s m ϕ ( γ ( s ) ) , γ ˙ ( s ) ) + F ( γ ( s ) , m ) ) d s max { ϕ ( γ ( 0 ) ) , a m } + s 0 t ( L ( γ ( s ) , a m , γ ˙ ( s ) ) + F ( γ ( s ) , m ) ) d s ϕ + D 1 + h t s 0 m ( γ ( s 0 ) , x ) ϕ + D 1 + E t 0 + 3 D 2 diam ( M ) .

We have proved that T t m ϕ ( x ) is bounded from above by ϕ + 2 D 1 + E t 0 + 3 D 2 diam ( M ) on M × [ t 0 , + ) .

Boundedness from below: For ( x , t ) M × [ t 0 , + ) with T t m ϕ ( x ) < a m , let α : [ 0 , t ] M be a minimizer of T t m ϕ ( x ) . Consider the function s T s m ϕ ( α ( s ) ) for s ( 0 , t ] . Since T 0 m ϕ ( α ( 0 ) ) = ϕ ( α ( 0 ) ) and T t m ϕ ( x ) < a m , then there exists s 0 [ 0 , t ) such that T s 0 m ϕ ( α ( s 0 ) ) min { ϕ ( α ( s 0 ) ) , a m } and T s m ϕ ( α ( s ) ) < a m for s ( s 0 , t ] . Hence, by (H3) and (3.8), we have that

T t m ϕ ( x ) = T s 0 m ϕ ( α ( s 0 ) ) + s 0 t ( L ( α ( s ) , T s m ϕ ( α ( s ) ) , α ˙ ( s ) ) + F ( α ( s ) , m ) ) d s min { ϕ ( α ( s 0 ) ) , a m } + s 0 t ( L ( α ( s ) , a m , α ˙ ( s ) ) + F ( α ( s ) , m ) ) d s ϕ D 1 + h t s 0 m ( α ( s 0 ) , x ) ϕ D 1 D 2 diam ( M ) ,

which shows that T t m ϕ ( x ) is bounded from below by ϕ 2 D 1 D 2 diam ( M ) on M × [ t 0 , + ) .□

By Proposition 4, for each m P ( M ) , the uniform limit of T t m ϕ as t exists and the limit function is a viscosity solution of

H ( x , u , D u ) F ( x , m ) = 0 .

Note that for any fixed m the aforementioned equation has a unique viscosity solution under (H1)–(H3) and (F1)–(F3) (see, for instance, [32, Proposition A.1] for a proof). Denote by

u m ( x ) lim t + T t m ϕ ( x )

the unique viscosity solution. Therefore, by Proposition 9, there is a constant D 3 > 0 such that

(3.10) u m D 3 , m P ( M ) .

Note that F is bounded, then by the aforementioned estimate and [32, Lemma 4.1], we deduce that { u m } m P ( M ) is equi-Lipschitz with a Lipschitz constant

sup { L ( x , u , v ) + F : ( x , u , v ) T M × R , u D 3 , v x = 1 } .

See Lemma 4 in the Appendix for the proof of the equi-Lipschitz property of { u m } m P ( M ) .

Remark 4

Let us point out that the aforementioned Lemmas 13 and Propositions 9 and 10 still hold true under assumptions (H1)–(H3).

Proposition 10

For any m P ( M ) , let u m denote the unique viscosity solution of

H ( x , u , D u ) = F ( x , m ) , x M .

Let m j , m 0 P ( M ) , j N . If m j w m 0 , as j , then u m j converges uniformly to u m 0 on M , as j .

Proof

Let H m ( x , u , p ) H ( x , u , p ) F ( x , m ) . Then by (F3) and m j w m 0 as j , H m j converges uniformly to H m 0 on compact subsets of T M × R , as j . Since { u m } m P ( M ) is uniformly bounded and equi-Lipschitz, then by the stability of viscosity solutions and the uniqueness of viscosity solutions of

H ( x , u , D u ) = F ( x , m 0 ) , x M ,

we conclude that u m j converges uniformly to u m 0 on M , as j .□

Now we prove Theorem 1.

Proof

(Proof of Theorem 1) For any m P ( M ) , in view of Proposition 8, we know that

˜ H m = K H m = { ( x , u m ( x ) , 0 ) : H m ( x , u m ( x ) , 0 ) = 0 }

and that each point in K H m is a fixed point of Φ t H m . So, any convex combination of atomic measures supported in K H m is a Mather measure for H m . We use M m to denote the set of all convex combinations of atomic measures supported in K H m .

Define the set-valued map

Ψ : P ( M ) P ( M ) , m Ψ ( m ) ,

where

Ψ ( m ) { π x η m : η m M m } .

In view of the arguments in Section 1, it is important to show that there exists a fixed point m ¯ of Ψ .

Note that the metric space ( P ( M ) , d 1 ) is convex and compact due to Prokhorov’s theorem (see, for instance, [3]). Since Ψ has nonempty convex values, the only hypothesis of Kakutani’s theorem we need to check is that Ψ has a closed graph: for any pair of sequences { m j } j N P ( M ) , { μ j } j N P ( M ) such that

m j w m , μ j w μ , as j + and μ j Ψ ( m j ) for all j N ,

we aim to prove that μ Ψ ( m ) .

Since μ j Ψ ( m j ) , there are measures η m j M m j such that μ j = π η m j . From (3.10), we have that

u m j , u m D 3 , j N .

By Proposition 7, we obtain that

supp ( η m j ) M × [ D 3 , D 3 ] × { 0 } K 0 , j N .

Thus, the sequence { η m j } j N is tight. By Prokhorov’s theorem again, passing to a subsequence if necessary, we may suppose that

η m j w η , as j + and μ = π η ,

where η P 1 ( T M ) . It suffices to show that η M m . We first show that η is a Φ t H m -invariant measure. Since η m j are Φ t H m j -invariant measures, then we deduce that, for any given t R ,

(3.11) K 0 f ( Φ t H m j ( x , u , p ) ) d η m j = K 0 f ( x , u , p ) d η m j , f C ( K 0 ) , j N .

Note that H is of class C 3 , F satisfies (F1), (F2), and (F3). Since K 0 is compact, then by the continuous dependence of the solutions on the initial condition and a parameter, we obtain that

lim j f ( Φ t H m j ( x , u , p ) ) = f ( Φ t H m ( x , u , p ) )

uniformly on K 0 . Thus, by (3.11), we deduce that

K 0 f ( Φ t H m ( x , u , p ) ) d η = K 0 f ( x , u , p ) d η , f C ( K 0 ) ,

which shows that η is Φ t H m -invariant. Next, we show that supp ( η ) K H m = { ( x , u m ( x ) , 0 ) : H m ( x , u m ( x ) , 0 ) = 0 } . Since η m j w η as j , for any ( x 0 , u 0 , p 0 ) supp ( η ) , there is a sequence of points ( x j , u j , p j ) supp ( η m j ) with ( x j , u j , p j ) ( x 0 , u 0 , p 0 ) as j . By Proposition 7 and η m j M m j , we deduce that u j = u m j ( x j ) , p j = 0 , and that

H ( x j , u m j ( x j ) , 0 ) F ( x j , m j ) = 0

for all j N . By Proposition 10, the equi-Lipschitz property of { u m j } and (F3), we obtain that

H ( x 0 , u m ( x 0 ) , 0 ) F ( x 0 , m ) = 0 ,

which shows that supp ( η ) K H m . Thus, η M m . So far, we have proved that Ψ has a closed graph. By Kakutani’s theorem, there exists m ¯ P ( M ) such that m ¯ Ψ ( m ¯ ) , i.e., there is η m ¯ M m ¯ such that m ¯ = π x η m ¯ .

Denote by u ¯ the unique viscosity solution of u + H m ¯ ( x , D u ) = 0 . From the arguments in Section 2, u ¯ is differentiable m ¯ -a.e since m ¯ is supported on a subset of the projected Mather set H m ¯ .

For any x supp ( m ¯ ) , let γ t ( x ) = π x Φ t H m ¯ ( x , u ¯ ( x ) , D u ¯ ( x ) ) . Then, we have that

d d t γ t ( x ) = H m ¯ p ( γ t ( x ) , u ¯ ( γ t ( x ) ) , D u ¯ ( γ t ( x ) ) ) .

Since the map π x : supp ( η m ¯ ) supp ( m ¯ ) is one to one and its inverse is given by x ( x , u ¯ ( x ) , D u ¯ ( x ) ) on supp ( m ¯ ) , then γ t : supp ( m ¯ ) supp ( m ¯ ) is a bijection for each t R . Note that, for each t R and any function f C 1 ( M ) , we obtain that

supp ( m ¯ ) f ( γ t ( x ) ) d m ¯ = supp ( m ¯ ) f γ t ( x ) d π x η m ¯ = supp ( η m ¯ ) f γ t ( π x ( x , u , p ) ) d η m ¯ = supp ( η m ¯ ) f ( π x Φ t H m ¯ ( x , u , p ) ) d η m ¯ = supp ( η m ¯ ) f ( π x ( x , u , p ) ) d η m ¯ = supp ( m ¯ ) f ( x ) d m ¯ .

Here, the first equality holds since m ¯ is a fixed point of Ψ , the second one holds by the property of the push-forward, the third holds since γ t is a bijection, the fourth one comes from the Φ t H m ¯ -invariance property of η m ¯ , and the last one is again due to the property of the push-forward. So, for any function f C 1 ( M ) and any t R , one can deduce that

0 = d d t M f ( γ t ( x ) ) d m ¯ ( x ) = M D f ( γ t ( x ) ) , H m ¯ p ( γ t ( x ) , u ¯ ( γ t ( x ) ) , D u ¯ ( γ t ( x ) ) ) x d m ¯ ( x ) = M D f ( x ) , H m ¯ p ( x , u ¯ ( x ) , D u ¯ ( x ) ) x d m ¯ ( x ) .

Hence, m ¯ satisfies the continuity equation, which completes the proof.□

Acknowledgments

The authors sincerely thank the referees for their careful reading of the manuscript and invaluable comments, which were very useful in improving this paper. Kaizhi Wang is supported by NSFC Grant Nos. 12171315 and 11931016 and Innovation Program of Shanghai Municipal Education Commission No. 2021-01-07-00-02-E00087.

  1. Conflict of interest: The authors state no conflict of interest.

Appendix

Proof

Proof of (3.9) Recall that

h t m ( x , y ) inf γ 0 t ( L ( γ ( s ) , a m , γ ˙ ( s ) ) + F ( γ ( s ) , m ) ) d s , x , y M ,

where the infimum is taken among the absolutely continuous curves γ : [ 0 , t ] M with γ ( 0 ) = x and γ ( t ) = y .

Lemma 3 guarantees that for each given t 0 > 0 , there is a constant E t 0 R such that for any x , y M , there is a C curve γ x , y : [ 0 , t 0 ] M with γ x , y ( 0 ) = x , γ x , y ( t 0 ) = y and

0 t 0 ( L ( γ x , y ( s ) , a m , γ ˙ x , y ( s ) ) + F ( γ x , y ( s ) , m ) ) d s E t 0 , m P ( M ) ,

where E t 0 is given by

E t 0 t 0 E ˜ t 0 , E ˜ t 0 sup L ( x , u , v ) + F : ( x , u , v ) T M × R , u D 1 , v x diam ( M ) t 0 .

Recall that w m ( x ) w m ( x ) w m ( 0 ) , where w m is as in Lemma 2. Since w m is a viscosity solution (or equivalently, a backward weak KAM solution) of (3.7), then there is a curve γ y : ( , 0 ] M with γ y ( 0 ) = y , and

w m ( y ) w m ( γ y ( s ) ) = s 0 ( L ( γ y ( τ ) , a m , γ ˙ y ( τ ) ) + F ( γ y ( τ ) , m ) ) d τ , s 0 .

For any t t 0 , define a curve γ : [ 0 , t ] M by γ ( s ) = γ x , γ y ( t 0 t ) ( s ) , for s [ 0 , t 0 ] , and γ ( s ) = γ y ( s t ) , for s [ t 0 , t ] . This curve connects x and y . Hence, we have

0 t ( L ( γ ( s ) , a m , γ ˙ ( s ) ) + F ( γ ( s ) , m ) ) d s = 0 t 0 ( L ( γ ( s ) , a m , γ ˙ ( s ) ) + F ( γ ( s ) , m ) ) d s + t 0 t ( L ( γ ( s ) , a m , γ ˙ ( s ) ) + F ( γ ( s ) , m ) ) d s E t 0 + w m ( y ) w m ( γ y ( t 0 t ) ) E t 0 + 2 w m E t 0 + 2 w m ( x ) w m ( 0 ) E t 0 + 2 D 2 Diam ( M ) ,

where the last inequality comes from Lemma 2.□

Lemma 4

u m is equi-Lipschitz continuous on M .

Proof

For each x , y M , let γ : [ 0 , d ( x , y ) ] M be a geodesic of length d ( x , y ) , parameterized by arclength and connecting x to y , where d ( , ) denotes the distance function defined by the Riemannian metric g on M . Let

A 1 sup { L ( x , u , v ) + F : x M , u D 3 , v x = 1 } ,

where D 3 is as in (3.10). Since γ ˙ ( s ) γ ( s ) = 1 for each s [ 0 , d ( x , y ) ] , we have L ( γ ( s ) , u m ( γ ( s ) ) , γ ˙ ( s ) ) + F ( γ ( s ) , m ) A 1 . Since u m is a backward weak KAM solution, then

u m ( γ ( d ( x , y ) ) ) u m ( γ ( 0 ) ) 0 d ( x , y ) ( L ( γ ( s ) , u m ( γ ( s ) ) , γ ˙ ( s ) ) + F ( γ ( s ) , m ) ) d s 0 d ( x , y ) A 1 d s = A 1 d ( x , y ) .

We finish the proof by exchanging the roles of x and y .□

References

[1] M. Bardi and I. Capuzzo Dolcetta, Optimal Control and Viscosity Solutions of Hamilton-Jacobi Equations, Birkhäuser, Boston, 1997. 10.1007/978-0-8176-4755-1Search in Google Scholar

[2] P. Bernard, Young measures, superposition and transport, Indiana Univ. Math. J. 57 (2008), 247–275. 10.1512/iumj.2008.57.3163Search in Google Scholar

[3] P. Billingsley, Convergence of Probability Measures, John Wiley & Sons, Inc., New York, 1999. 10.1002/9780470316962Search in Google Scholar

[4] P. Cannarsa, W. Cheng, C. Mendico, and K. Wang, Long-time behavior of first-order mean field games on Euclidean space, Dyn. Games Appl. 10 (2020), 361–390. 10.1007/s13235-019-00321-3Search in Google Scholar

[5] P. Cannarsa, W. Cheng, C. Mendico, and K. Wang, Weak KAM aspects of Hamilton-Jacobi equations with state constraints and applications to long-time behavior of constrained first-order mean field games, J. Dynam. Differ. Equ. 2021. 10.1007/s10884-021-10071-9Search in Google Scholar

[6] P. Cannarsa and C. Sinestrari, Semiconcave Functions, Hamilton-Jacobi Equations, and Optimal Control, Birkhäuser, Boston, 2004. 10.1007/b138356Search in Google Scholar

[7] P. Cardaliaguet, Long time average of first order mean field games and weak KAM theory, Dyn. Games Appl. 3 (2013), 473–488. 10.1007/s13235-013-0091-xSearch in Google Scholar

[8] P. Cardaliaguet and P. Graber, Mean field games systems of first order, ESAIM Control Optim. Calc. Var. 21 (2015), 690–722. 10.1051/cocv/2014044Search in Google Scholar

[9] P. Cardaliaguet, Weak solutions for first order mean field games with local coupling, in: Analysis and Geometry in Control Theory and its Applications, Springer INdAM Ser., vol. 11, Springer, Cham, 2015, pp. 111–158. 10.1007/978-3-319-06917-3_5Search in Google Scholar

[10] P. Cardaliaguet, A. Mészáros, and F. Santambrogio, First order mean field games with density constraints: pressure equals price, SIAM J. Control Optim. 54 (2016), 2672–2709. 10.1137/15M1029849Search in Google Scholar

[11] M. Crandall and P.-L. Lions, Viscosity solutions of Hamilton-Jacobi equations, Trans. Amer. Math. Soc. 277 (1983), 1–42. 10.1016/S0304-0208(08)71044-2Search in Google Scholar

[12] L. Evans, Some new PDE methods for weak KAM theory, Calc. Var. Partial Differ. Equ. 17 (2003), 159–177. 10.1007/s00526-002-0164-ySearch in Google Scholar

[13] A. Fathi, Weak KAM Theorem and Lagrangian Dynamics, http://www.math.u-bordeaux.fr/ pthieull/Recherche/KamFaible/Publications/Fathi2008_01.pdf. Search in Google Scholar

[14] D. Gomes and J. Saude, Mean field games models-a brief survey, Dyn. Games Appl. 4 (2014), 110–154. 10.1007/s13235-013-0099-2Search in Google Scholar

[15] D. Gomes, E. Pimentel, and V. Voskanyan, Regularity theory for mean-field game systems, Springer Briefs in Mathematics. Springer, Cham, 2016. 10.1007/978-3-319-38934-9Search in Google Scholar

[16] D. Gomes, L. Nurbekyan, and E. Pimentel, Economic models and mean-field games theory, Publicações Matemáticas do IMPA. [IMPA Mathematical Publications] 30circ Colóquio Brasileiro de Matemática. [30th Brazilian Mathematics Colloquium] Instituto Nacional de Matemática Pura e Aplicada (IMPA), Rio de Janeiro, 2015. Search in Google Scholar

[17] D. Gomes, H. Mitake, and K. Terai, The selection problem for some first-order stationary mean-field games, Netw. Heterog. Media 15 (2020), 681–710. 10.3934/nhm.2020019Search in Google Scholar

[18] M. Huang, R. P. Malhamé, and P. E. Caines, Large population stochastic dynamic games: closed-loop McKean-Vlasov systems and the Nash certainty equivalence principle, Commun. Inf. Syst. 6 (2006), 221–251. 10.4310/CIS.2006.v6.n3.a5Search in Google Scholar

[19] M. Huang, P. E. Caines, and R. P. Malhamé, Large-population cost-coupled LQG problems with nonuniform agents: Individual-mass behavior and decentralized epsilon-Nash equilibria, IEEE Trans. Automat. Control 52 (2007), 1560–1571. 10.1109/TAC.2007.904450Search in Google Scholar

[20] R. Iturriaga and K. Wang, A semi-discrete approximation for first-order stationary mean field games, preprint, 2021, http://arxiv.org/abs/2111.11972. Search in Google Scholar

[21] J.-M. Lasry and P.-L. Lions, Jeux à champ moyen. I. Le cas stationnaire. (French) [Mean field games. I. The stationary case], C. R. Math. Acad. Sci. Paris 343 (2006), 619–625. 10.1016/j.crma.2006.09.019Search in Google Scholar

[22] J.-M. Lasry and P.-L. Lions, Jeux à champ moyen. II. Horizon fini et controle optimal. (French) [Mean field games. II. Finite horizon and optimal control], C. R. Math. Acad. Sci. Paris 343 (2006), 679–684. 10.1016/j.crma.2006.09.018Search in Google Scholar

[23] J.-M. Lasry and P.-L. Lions, Mean field games, Jpn. J. Math. 2 (2007), 229–260. 10.1007/s11537-007-0657-8Search in Google Scholar

[24] R. Mañé, Lagrangian flows: the dynamics of globally minimizing orbits, Bol. Soc. Brasil. Mat. (N.S.) 28 (1997), 141–153. 10.1007/BF01233389Search in Google Scholar

[25] S. Marò and A. Sorrentino, Aubry-Mather theory for conformally symplectic systems, Commun. Math. Phys. 354 (2017), 775–808. 10.1007/s00220-017-2900-3Search in Google Scholar

[26] J. Mather, Action minimizing invariant measures for positive definite Lagrangian systems, Math. Z. 207 (1991), 169–207. 10.1007/BF02571383Search in Google Scholar

[27] H. Mitake and K. Soga, Weak KAM theory for discounted Hamilton-Jacobi equations and its application, Calc. Var. 57 (2018), Paper No. 78, 32 p. 10.1007/s00526-018-1359-1Search in Google Scholar

[28] K. Wang and J. Yan, A new kind of Lax-Oleinik type operator with parameters for time-periodic positive definite Lagrangian systems, Commun. Math. Phys. 309 (2012), 663–691. 10.1007/s00220-011-1375-xSearch in Google Scholar

[29] K. Wang and J. Yan, The rate of convergence of new Lax-Oleinik type operators for time-periodic positive definite Lagrangian systems, Nonlinearity 25 (2012), 2039–2057. 10.1088/0951-7715/25/7/2039Search in Google Scholar

[30] K. Wang and Y. Li, Some results on weak KAM theory for time-periodic Tonelli Lagrangian systems, Adv. Nonlinear Stud. 13 (2013), 853–866. 10.1515/ans-2013-0406Search in Google Scholar

[31] K. Wang, L. Wang, and J. Yan, Variational principle for contact Hamiltonian systems and its applications, J. Math. Pures Appl. 123 (2019), 167–200. 10.1016/j.matpur.2018.08.011Search in Google Scholar

[32] K. Wang, L. Wang, and J. Yan, Aubry-Mather theory for contact Hamiltonian systems, Commun. Math. Phys. 366 (2019), 981–1023. 10.1007/s00220-019-03362-2Search in Google Scholar

Received: 2021-11-09
Revised: 2022-04-20
Accepted: 2022-05-13
Published Online: 2022-07-22

© 2022 Xiaotian Hu and Kaizhi Wang, published by De Gruyter

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.

Articles in the same Issue

  1. Research Articles
  2. Editorial
  3. A sharp global estimate and an overdetermined problem for Monge-Ampère type equations
  4. Non-degeneracy of bubble solutions for higher order prescribed curvature problem
  5. On fractional logarithmic Schrödinger equations
  6. Large solutions of a class of degenerate equations associated with infinity Laplacian
  7. Chemotaxis-Stokes interaction with very weak diffusion enhancement: Blow-up exclusion via detection of absorption-induced entropy structures involving multiplicative couplings
  8. Asymptotic mean-value formulas for solutions of general second-order elliptic equations
  9. Weighted critical exponents of Sobolev-type embeddings for radial functions
  10. Existence and asymptotic behavior of solitary waves for a weakly coupled Schrödinger system
  11. On the Lq-reflector problem in ℝn with non-Euclidean norm
  12. Existence of normalized solutions for the coupled elliptic system with quadratic nonlinearity
  13. Normalized solutions for a class of scalar field equations involving mixed fractional Laplacians
  14. Multiplicity and concentration of semi-classical solutions to nonlinear Dirac-Klein-Gordon systems
  15. Multiple solutions to multi-critical Schrödinger equations
  16. Existence of solutions to contact mean-field games of first order
  17. The regularity of weak solutions for certain n-dimensional strongly coupled parabolic systems
  18. Uniform stabilization for a strongly coupled semilinear/linear system
  19. Existence of nontrivial solutions for critical Kirchhoff-Poisson systems in the Heisenberg group
  20. Existence of ground state solutions for critical fractional Choquard equations involving periodic magnetic field
  21. Least energy sign-changing solutions for Schrödinger-Poisson systems with potential well
  22. Lp Hardy's identities and inequalities for Dunkl operators
  23. Global well-posedness analysis for the nonlinear extensible beam equations in a class of modified Woinowsky-Krieger models
  24. Gradient estimate of the solutions to Hessian equations with oblique boundary value
  25. Sobolev-Gaffney type inequalities for differential forms on sub-Riemannian contact manifolds with bounded geometry
  26. A Liouville theorem for the Hénon-Lane-Emden system in four and five dimensions
  27. Regularity of degenerate k-Hessian equations on closed Hermitian manifolds
  28. Principal eigenvalue problem for infinity Laplacian in metric spaces
  29. Concentrations for nonlinear Schrödinger equations with magnetic potentials and constant electric potentials
  30. A general method to study the convergence of nonlinear operators in Orlicz spaces
  31. Existence of ground state solutions for critical quasilinear Schrödinger equations with steep potential well
  32. Global existence of the two-dimensional axisymmetric Euler equations for the Chaplygin gas with large angular velocities
  33. Existence of two solutions for singular Φ-Laplacian problems
  34. Existence and multiplicity results for first-order Stieltjes differential equations
  35. Concentration-compactness principle associated with Adams' inequality in Lorentz-Sobolev space
Downloaded on 11.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/ans-2022-0012/html
Scroll to top button