Home Content Provision in the Media Market with Single-Homing and Multi-Homing Consumers
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

Content Provision in the Media Market with Single-Homing and Multi-Homing Consumers

  • Armando J. Garcia Pires ORCID logo EMAIL logo
Published/Copyright: October 5, 2020

Abstract

In this paper, we analyze the effects on content provision in the news market of single-homing (i.e. when readers consume news from just one outlet) and multi-homing (i.e. when readers can choose to consume news from competing outlets). Media firms compete on content provision and on advertising revenues. Readers have an ideal variety of content and experience a disutility from consuming news that differs from their ideal variety. In addition, readers have a preference for single-homing and for multi-homing. In this set-up, we show that media firms only diversify content with single-homing, but not with multi-homing. The reason for this is that competition for readers and advertising is lower under multi-homing than under single-homing, since multi-homing readers consume from all media outlets. We derive the consequences of single-homing and multi-homing for profits, consumer surplus and social welfare. We also discuss the implications of our results for the current debate in the media market related with social media and echo chambers.

JEL Classification: D43; L13; L82; L86

Corresponding author: Armando J. Garcia Pires, Centre for Applied Research at NHH (SNF), Helleveien 30, 5045 Bergen, Norway, E-mail:

A. Appendix

Single-Homing: FOCs

FOCs for advertising:

(34)dΠidai=t(didj+1)(α2ai)+ηai(3ai2aj)αη(2aiaj)2t,i,j=1,2 withij.

FOCs for content:

(35)dΠiddi=t(didj+3)(t(didj+3)2αη)+18γη2di18η2,i,j=1,2 withij.

Single-Homing: SOCs

SOCs for advertising:

(36)d2Πidai2=αη+t(didj+1)η(3aiaj)t<0,i,j=1,2.

We can see that at the symmetric equilibrium the SOC simplifies to:

(37)d2Πidai2=αη+t2ηait<0,i=j=1,2.

The SOC is satisfied if α>2ηaitη, i = j = 1, 2. Since ai=tη, then the SOC is satisfied if α>tη.

SOCs for content:

(38)d2Πiddi2=t2(didj+3)η(tα9γη)9η2<0,i,j=1,2.

At the symmetric equilibrium, the SOC equals:

(39)d2Πiddi2=3t2η(tα9γη)9η2<0,i=j=1,2.

The SOC is satisfied if α<3t2+9γη2ηt. As a result the game is valid for tη<α<3t2+9γη2ηt. The SOCs in the single homing case then say that the advertising market cannot be too big or too small. The intuition is the following. Since firms derive all the revenues from advertising, if the advertising market is too small, firms cannot make positive profits, and as a result, all firms exit the market. If the advertising market is too big, and since under the single homing case firms diversify content, this means that it is possible that content diversification can either be bigger than the line and/or that the content provision segments of the two firms overlap. Since under single homing consumers only consume one variety, overlap of content is not possible in equilibrium.

Multi-Homing: FOCs

FOCs for advertising:

(40)dΠidai=((VMVS)+tdi)(α2ai)ηai(2α3ai)t,i,j=1,2.

FOCs for content:

(41)dΠiddi=γdi+α2(VMVS+tdi)((4α3η3+(VMVS)(13α2η2+2(VMVS)(4αη+(VMVS))))8(αη+(VMVS)+tdi)4+(tdi(13α2η2+2tdi(4αη+tdi)+2(VMVS)(8αη+3(VMVS)+3tdi)))8(αη+(VMVS)+tdi)4),i,j=1,2.

Multi-Homing: SOCs

SOCs for advertising:

(42)d2Πidai2=2αη+(VMVS+td13ηa1)t,i=1,2.

Substituting for ai=α(VMVS)2(αη+(VMVS)) and di = 0, we obtain:

(43)d2Πidai2=(VMVS)(2(VMVS)+αη)+2α2η2((VMVS)+αη)t<0,i=1,2.

Then the SOC is always satisfied since (VM − VS) > 0.

SOCs for content:

(44)d2Π1dd12=tα4η2(VMVS)((VMVS)7αη+2tdi)2α2η2tdi(7αηtdi)4(αη+(VMVS)+tdi)5γ<0,i=1,2.

Substituting for di = 0, we obtain:

(45)d2Π1dd12=tα4η2(VMVS)((VMVS)7αη)2α2η24(αη+(VMVS))5γ<0,i=1,2.

The SOCs for content is satisfied if γ>tα4η2(VMVS)((VMVS)7αη)2α2η24(αη+(VMVS))5. We can see that the numerator has two solutions in relation to (VM − VS): αη(7+57)2>0 and αη(757)2<0. Furthermore, the numerator is convex in (VM − VS). As such the numerator is always positive for (VMVS)>αη(7+57)2>0 and for (VMVS)<αη(757)2<0. When this occurs, we have that tα4η2(VMVS)((VMVS)7αη)2α2η24(αη+(VMVS))5<0 and the SOC is as a result satisfied, since γ > 0.

Note that if (VMVS)<αη(757)2<0, multi-homing does not arise in equilibrium (see Eq. (21)). In other words, we fall back in the single-homing case, and therefore there are no differences between the single-homing and the multi-homing case. Since we are interested in comparing what happens in a media market where readers single-home and where readers multi-home, we look at the case where (VMVS)>αη(7+57)2>0.

In the multi-homing case, the SOC then only demands that consumers have a higher preference for multi-homing than single-homing. If the SOC is not satisfied, we follow back in the single homing case.

Alternative Utilities: Consumers Care About the Size of the Line Segment of Content Provided by Media Firms

In the model in the paper consumers care about their ideal variety. We could what ask what would occur if they also care about the size of the line segment of content provided by media firms. There are potentially several ways to do this. In here, we consider two alternatives.

In the first, individual utility from consuming news is just multiplied by the size of the content provision segment provided by each firm, i.e. in the single-homing case VSdi; and in the multi-homing case VMdi, with i = 1,2.

In this case, under single-homing, the utility of a reader who only consumes from media firm 1 and is located outside the multi-content segment of media firm 1, is:

(46)US=VSd1t(xd1)ηa1,

and under multi-homing, the utility of a reader, located outside the multi-content segments of the two media firms and who consumes from both media firms is:

(47)UM=VMd1t((xd1)+(1xd2))η(a1+a2),

In the second case, we consider that consumers care about the difference in content provision provided by each firm, i.e. (d1 − d2) for a consumer in the left segment and (d2 − d1) for a consumer in the right segment.

In this case, under single-homing, the utility of a reader who only consumes from media firm 1 and is located outside the multi-content segment of media firm 1, is:

(48)US=VSt(xd1)ηa1+(d1d2),

And under multi-homing, the utility of a reader, located outside the multi-content segments of the two media firms and who consumes from both media firms is:

(49)UM=VMt((xd1)+(1xd2))η(a1+a2)+(d1d2),

It can be easily be seen that since media firms are symmetric, in both cases, we get the same indifferent consumer as in the main model. Therefore, our results in the main text are not changed.

Numerical Simulations (An Example)

If we set η = 0.3; γ = 1; and t = 1, we have from Eq. (32) that 150 < α < 452. 7. As a result, for 150=tη<α<225=3t2δ, media firms do not diversify content; and for 225=3t2δ<α<452.7, media firms diversify content. We then make simulations for parameter values under these two intervals. Setting for instance α = 400, which represents a large add market and that media firms diversify content under single-homing, from Eq. (33), we must have that VMVS>4(57+7)3. We then plot Eqs. (50)–(55) in the interval VMVS>4(57+7)3.

We proceed in the same way with different values of the parameters, to check for high and low η, for high and low γ; for high and low t, and for high and low α.

Note that since we plot Eqs. (50)–(55) in the VM − VS, we do not need to do simulations for high and low values of VM − VS, since this can be seen from the figures.

Difference in Profits, Consumer Surplus and Social Welfare: Single-Homing Versus Multi-Homing

Start with the scenario where α<3t2δ (small advertising market, media firms do not diversify content in both the single-homing and the multi-homing cases). The difference in profits between the single-homing case and the multi-homing case is:

(50)ΠSHΠMH=(αδt)tδ2(2(VMVS)+αδ)((VMVS)+2αδ)(VMVS)2α24((VMVS)+αδ)3t,ifα<3t2δ.

The difference in consumer surplus between the single-homing case and the multi-homing case is:

(51)CSSHCSMH=VS5t4(VMVS)2(2(VMVS)+αδ)22t(VM2VS)(αδ+(VMVS))22((VMVS)+αδ)2t+(αδ+2(VMVS))3(VMVS)312((VMVS)+αδ)3t2,ifα<3t2δ.

The difference in social welfare between the single-homing case and the multi-homing case is:

(52)WSHWMH=VS+(δ(4α5δ)4t)t4δ2(VMVS)2(2(VMVS)+αδ)22t(VM2VS)(αδ+(VMVS))22((VMVS)+αδ)2t(δα2(6tαδ(VMVS))(VMVS)(4(VMVS)((VMVS)+αδ)3tα2))12((VMVS)+αδ)3t2(2(VMVS)+αδ)1(VMVS)2,ifα<3t2δ.

Turn now to the case with α>3t2δ (large advertising market, media firms diversify content in the single-homing case, but not diversify content in the multi-homing case). The difference between profits in the single-homing and the multi-homing scenario equals:

(53)ΠSHΠMH=(4δ2α(9γδtα)3t(3t2+4δ(3γδtα)))t36δ4γ(2(VMVS)+αδ)((VMVS)+2αδ)(VMVS)2α24((VMVS)+αδ)3t,ifα>3t2δ.

The difference in consumer surplus between the single-homing and the multi-homing scenario is:

(54)CSSHCSMH=VS3t2(t(3t4αδ)+6γδ2)+δ2(4αt(tα3γδ)+45γ2δ2)36δ4γ2(VMVS)2(2(VMVS)+αδ)22t(VM2VS)(αδ+(VMVS))22((VMVS)+αδ)2t+(αδ+2(VMVS))3(VMVS)312((VMVS)+αδ)3t2,ifα>3t2δ.

With respect to social welfare, we have:

(55)WSHWMH=VS+3t2(t(4αδ3t)(γ+1)6δ2γ(2γ+1))+δ2(4αt(3δγ(3γ+1)αt(γ+1))45γ2δ2)36δ4γ2(VMVS)2(2(VMVS)+αδ)22t(VM2VS)(αδ+(VMVS))22((VMVS)+αδ)2t(δα2(6tαδ(VMVS))(VMVS)(4(VMVS)((VMVS)+αδ)3tα2))12((VMVS)+αδ)3t2(2(VMVS)+αδ)1(VMVS)2,if α>3t2δ.

Type of Content Provided by Media Firms

In this paper, our aim is to look at content competition with single-homing and multi-homing consumers. Our aim is to focus in different type of content provided in media markets. Below, we give some examples of content that can be considered in the context of our model.

Competition between local media outlets. Consider two local newspapers of two different cities (city 1 and city 2) but possible nearby cities (but not necessarily). Media outlet 1 is located on the left at point zero and media outlet 2 on the right at point one. Consumer located closer to point 0 like news about city 1, consumers located closer to point 1 like news about city 2 and consumers in between like a mix of news about city 1 and 2. What our model says is that under single-homing, local media outlet 1 will provide mostly news about city 1 but also a mix of news from both city 1 and 2 in order to attract consumers that like a mix of news from both cities and to not lose them to media outlet 2. Under multi-homing, media outlet 1 will just provide news about city 1. The reason is that consumers that like also of news of city 2 can just go to newspaper 2 and consume news from media outlet 2, and media outlet 1 will not lose them since they will continue to consume from media outlet 1.

Competition between national and local media outlets. Consider a national newspaper and a local newspaper. Media outlet 1 is the national outlet and is located on the left at point zero. Media outlet 2 is the local outlet and is located on the right at point one. Consumer located closer point 0 like national news, consumers located closer to point 1 like local news, and consumers in between like a mix of national and local news. What our model says is that under single-homing, the national media outlet will provide mostly national news but also a mix of local and national news in order to attract consumers that like a mix of local and national news and not lose them to media outlet 2. Under multi-homing, the national media outlet will just provide national news. The reason again is that consumers that like a mix of local and national news can just go to the local newspaper and consume local news, and the national media outlet will not lose them since they will continue to consume from national outlet. A similar reasoning can be applied to the local newspaper.

Competition between generalist media outlets and specialist media outlets (like sports media outlets). Media outlet 1 is the generalist outlet and is located on the left at point zero. Media outlet 2 is the specialist outlet and is located on the right at point one. Consumer located closer point 0 like generalist news, consumers located closer to point 1 like specialist news, and consumers in between like a mix of specialist and generalist news. What our model says is that under single-homing, the generalist media outlet will provide generalist news but also a mix of generalist and specialist news in order to attract consumers that like a mix of generalist and specialist news and not lose them to media outlet 2. Under multi-homing, the generalist media outlet will just provide generalist news. The reason again is that consumers that like a mix of generalist and specialist news can just go to the specialist newspaper and consume specialist news, and the generalist media outlet will not lose them since they will continue to consume from the generalist outlet. A similar reasoning can be applied to the specialist newspaper.[24]

Competition between generalist media outlets. Consider two generalist media outlets that compete for political news (left wing versus right wing). Media outlet 1 is the left outlet and is located on the left at point zero. Media outlet 2 is the right outlet and is located on the right at point one. Consumer located closer point zero like left news, consumers located closer to point one like right news, and consumers in between like a mix of left and right news. What our model says is that under single-homing, the left media outlet will provide left news but also a mix of left and left-to-the-center news in order to attract consumers that are closer to the center. Under multi-homing, the left media outlet will just provide left news. The reason again is that consumers that like a mix of left and right news can just go to the right newspaper and consume right wing news, and the left media outlet will not lose them since they will continue to consume from the left wing media outlet. A similar reasoning can be applied to the right newspaper.

Competition between specialist media outlets. Consider two specialist media outlets that covers for instance just sport news (for instance car races and football). Media outlet 1 is the football outlet and is located on the left at point zero. Media outlet 2 is the car races outlet and is located on the right at point one. Consumer located closer point zero like football news, consumers located closer to point one like car race news, and consumers in between like a mix of football and car races news. What our model says is that under single-homing, the football media outlet will provide football news but also a mix of football and car races news in order to attract consumers that like also car races. Under multi-homing, the left media outlet will just provide football news. The reason again is that consumers that like a mix of football and car races news can just go to the car races newspaper and consume car races news, and the football media outlet will not lose them since they will continue to consume from the football media outlet. A similar reasoning can be applied to the car race newspaper.

Acknowledgment

The author would like to thank the editor Lukasz Grzybowski, and two anonymous referees for extremely helpful comments and suggestions.

References

Alexandrov, A. 2008. “Fat Products.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 17: 67–95. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1530-9134.2008.00171.x.10.1111/j.1530-9134.2008.00171.xSearch in Google Scholar

Ambrus, A., E. Calvano, and M. Reisinger. 2016. “Either or Both Competition: A Two-Sided Theory of Advertising with Overlapping Viewerships.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 8: 189–222, https://doi.org/10.1257/mic.20150019.10.1257/mic.20150019Search in Google Scholar

Anand, B., R. Di Tella, and A. Galetovic. 2007. “Information or Opinion? Media Bias as Product Differentiation.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 16: 635–82, 10.1111/j.1530-9134.2007.00153.x.10.1111/j.1530-9134.2007.00153.xSearch in Google Scholar

Anderson, S., and S. Coate. 2005. “Market Provision of Broadcasting: A Welfare Analysis.” The Review of Economic Studies 72: 947–72, https://doi.org/10.1111/0034-6527.00357.10.1111/0034-6527.00357Search in Google Scholar

Anderson, S., Ø. Foros, and H. J. Kind. 2017. “Product Functionality, Competition, and Multi-Purchasing.” International Economic Review 58: 183–210. https://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12213.10.1111/iere.12213Search in Google Scholar

Anderson, S., and J. Gans. 2011. “Platform Siphoning: Ad-Avoidance and Media Content.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 3: 1–34, https://doi.org/10.1257/mic.3.4.1.10.1257/mic.3.4.1Search in Google Scholar

Armstrong, M. 2006. “Competition in Two‐Sided Markets.” The RAND Journal of Economics 37: 668–91, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1756-2171.2006.tb00037.x.10.1111/j.1756-2171.2006.tb00037.xSearch in Google Scholar

Athey, S., E. Calvano, and J. Gans. 2018. “The Impact of Consumer Multi-Homing on Advertising Markets and Media Competition.” Management Science 64: 1574–90, https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2016.2675.10.1287/mnsc.2016.2675Search in Google Scholar

Athey, S., and J. Gans. 2010. “The Impact of Targeting on Advertising Markets and Media Competition.” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 100: 608–13, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.2.608.10.1257/aer.100.2.608Search in Google Scholar

Belleflamme, P., and M. Peitz. 2010. Industrial Organization: Markets and Strategies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511757808Search in Google Scholar

Belleflamme, P., and M. Peitz. 2019. “Managing Competition on a Two‐Sided Platform.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 28: 5–22, https://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12311.10.1111/jems.12311Search in Google Scholar

Berry, S., and J. Waldfogel. 2001. “Do Mergers Increase Product Variety? Evidence from Radio Broadcasting.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 116: 1009–25, https://doi.org/10.1162/00335530152466296.10.1162/00335530152466296Search in Google Scholar

Caillaud, B., and B. Jullien. 2003. “Chicken and Egg: Competition Among Intermediation Service Providers.” The RAND Journal of Economics 34: 309–28, https://doi.org/10.2307/1593720.10.2307/1593720Search in Google Scholar

Carrillo, J., and G. Tan. 2006. Platform Competition: The Role of Multi-Homing and Complementors. Working Papers 06–30, NET Institute.Search in Google Scholar

Choi, J. 2010. “Tying in Two-Sided Markets with Multi-Homing.” The Journal of Industrial Economics 58: 607–26, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6451.2010.00426.x.10.1111/j.1467-6451.2010.00426.xSearch in Google Scholar

Coase, R. 1974. “The Economics of the First Amendment: The Market for Goods and the Market for Ideas.” The American Economic Review 64: 384–91.10.4324/9780203930885.ch2Search in Google Scholar

Coleman, R., M. McCombs, D. Shaw, and D. Weaver. 2009. “Agenda Setting.” In The Handbook of Journalism Studies, edited by K. Wahl-Jorgensen, and T. Hanitzsch. New York: Routledge.Search in Google Scholar

d’Aspremont, C., J. Gabszewicz, and J.-F. Thisse. 1979. “On Hotelling’s Stability in Competition.” Econometrica 47: 1145–50, https://doi.org/10.2307/1911955.10.2307/1911955Search in Google Scholar

Del Vicario, M., A. Bessi, F. Zollo, F. Petroni, A. Scala, G. Caldarelli, H. Stanley, and W. Quattrociocchi. 2016. “The Spreading of Misinformation Online.” PNAS, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 113: 554–9, https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1517441113.10.1073/pnas.1517441113Search in Google Scholar

Dewan, R., B. Jing, and A. Seidmann. 2003. “Product Customization and Price Competition on the Internet.” Management Science 49: 1055–70, https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.49.8.1055.16401.10.1287/mnsc.49.8.1055.16401Search in Google Scholar

Doganoglu, T., and J. Wright. 2006. “Multi-Homing and Compatibility.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 24: 45–67, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2005.07.004.10.1016/j.ijindorg.2005.07.004Search in Google Scholar

Doganoglu, T., and J. Wright. 2010. “Exclusive Dealing with Network Effects.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 28: 145–54, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2009.07.006.10.1016/j.ijindorg.2009.07.006Search in Google Scholar

Eisensee, T., and D. Strömberg. 2007. “News Floods, News Droughts, and U.S. Disaster Relief.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 122: 693–728, https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.122.2.693.10.1162/qjec.122.2.693Search in Google Scholar

Esteban, L., and J. Hernández. 2016. “Advertising Media Planning, Optimal Pricing, and Welfare.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 25: 880–910, https://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12173.10.1111/jems.12173Search in Google Scholar

Esteban, L., J. Hernández, and J. Moraga-González. 2006. “Customer Directed Advertising and Product Quality.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 15: 943–68, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1530-9134.2006.00123.x.10.1111/j.1530-9134.2006.00123.xSearch in Google Scholar

Esteves, R.-B., and J. Resende. 2016. “Competitive Targeted Advertising with Price Discrimination.” Marketing Science 35: 576–87, https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.2015.0967.10.1287/mksc.2015.0967Search in Google Scholar

Gabszewicz, J., D. Laussel, and N. Sonnac. 2001. “Press Advertising and the Ascent of the Pensée Unique.” European Economic Review 45: 641–51, https://doi.org/10.1016/s0014-2921(01)00139-8.10.1016/S0014-2921(01)00139-8Search in Google Scholar

Gabszewicz, J., D. Laussel, and N. Sonnac. 2002. “Press Advertising and the Political Differentiation of Newspapers.” Journal of Public Economic Theory 4: 317–34, https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9779.00100.10.1111/1467-9779.00100Search in Google Scholar

Gal-Or, E., and A. Dukes. 2003. “Minimum Differentiation in Commercial Media Markets.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 12: 291–325, https://doi.org/10.1162/105864003322309491.10.1162/105864003322309491Search in Google Scholar

Gans, H. 1999. “Deciding What’s News.” In News: A Reader, edited by H. Tumber. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Garcia Pires, A. 2013. “Media Plurality and the Intensity of Readers’ Political Preferences.” The Journal of Media Economics 26: 41–55, https://doi.org/10.1080/08997764.2012.755984.10.1080/08997764.2012.755984Search in Google Scholar

Garcia Pires, A. 2014. “Media Diversity, Advertising, and Adaptation of News to Readers’ Political Preferences.” Information Economics and Policy 28: 28–38, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.infoecopol.2014.06.001.10.1016/j.infoecopol.2014.06.001Search in Google Scholar

Gentzkow, M., J. Shapiro, and M. Sinkinson. 2014. “Competition and Ideological Diversity: Historical Evidence from US Newspapers.” The American Economic Review 104: 3073–114, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.10.3073.10.3386/w18234Search in Google Scholar

Gitlin, H. 1999. “The Whole World Is Watching.” In News: A Reader, edited by H. Tumber. Oxford: Oxford University Press.10.4135/9781483326870.n4Search in Google Scholar

Goldfarb, A., and C. Tucker. 2011. “Online Display Advertising: Targeting and Obtrusiveness.” Marketing Science 30: 389–404, https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1100.0583.10.1287/mksc.1100.0583Search in Google Scholar

Goyal, S. 2012. “Social Networks on the Web.” In The Oxford Handbook of the Digital Economy, edited by M. Peitz, and J. Waldfogel. Oxford: Oxford University Press.10.1093/oxfordhb/9780195397840.013.0016Search in Google Scholar

Hayek, F. 1945. “The Use of Knowledge in Society.” The American Economic Review 35: 519–30.Search in Google Scholar

Hotelling, H. 1929. “Stability in Competition.” Economic Journal 39: 41–57, https://doi.org/10.2307/2224214.10.1007/978-1-4613-8905-7_4Search in Google Scholar

Iyer, G., D. Soberman, and J. Villas-Boas. 2005. “The Targeting of Advertising.” Marketing Science 24: 461–76, https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1050.0117.10.1287/mksc.1050.0117Search in Google Scholar

Jamieson, K., and J. Cappella. 2008. Echo Chamber: Rush Limbaugh and the Conservative Media Establishment. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Kim, H., and K. Serfes. 2006. “A Location Model with Preference for Variety.” The Journal of Industrial Economics 54: 569–95, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6451.2006.00300.x.10.1111/j.1467-6451.2006.00300.xSearch in Google Scholar

Kind, H. J., T. Nilssen, and L. Sørgard. 2007. “Competition for Viewers and Advertisers in a TV Oligopoly.” The Journal of Media Economics 20: 211–33, https://doi.org/10.1080/08997760701290708.10.1080/08997760701290708Search in Google Scholar

Maruyama, M., and Y. Zennyo. 2013. “Compatibility and the Product Life Cycle in Two-Sided Markets.” Review of Network Economics 12: 131–55, https://doi.org/10.1515/rne-2013-0011.10.1515/rne-2013-0011Search in Google Scholar

Mill, J. S. 1859. On Liberty. London: Parker and Son.Search in Google Scholar

Mullainathan, S., and A. Shleifer. 2005. “The Market for News.” The American Economic Review 95: 1031–53, https://doi.org/10.1257/0002828054825619.10.4324/9780203930885.ch6Search in Google Scholar

Musacchio, J., G. Schwartz, and J. Walrand. 2009. “A Two-Sided Market Analysis of Provider Investment Incentives with an Application to the Net-Neutrality Issue.” Review of Network Economics 8: 1–18, https://doi.org/10.2202/1446-9022.1168.10.2202/1446-9022.1168Search in Google Scholar

O’Neill, D., and T. Harcup. 2009. “News Values and Selectivity.” In The Handbook of Journalism Studies, edited by K. Wahl-Jorgensen, and T. Hanitzsch. New York: Routledge.Search in Google Scholar

Peitz, M., and M. Reisinger. 2014. The Economics of Internet Media. Working Papers from University of Mannheim No 14–23, Department of Economics.Search in Google Scholar

Peitz, M., and T. Valletti. 2008. “Content and Advertising in the Media: Pay-TV versus Free-To-Air.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 26: 949–65, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2007.08.003.10.1016/j.ijindorg.2007.08.003Search in Google Scholar

Perego, J., and S. Yuksel. 2018. Media Competition and Social Disagreement. Mimeo Columbia Business School.Search in Google Scholar

Prat, A., and D. Strömberg. 2005. Commercial Television and Voter Information. CEPR Discussion Paper 4989.Search in Google Scholar

Prat, A., and D. Strömberg. 2011. The Political Economy of Mass Media. CEPR Discussion Paper 8246.Search in Google Scholar

Quattrociocchi, W., A. Scala, and C. Sunstein. 2016. Echo Chambers on Facebook. Harvard Law School. Discussion Paper No. 877.10.2139/ssrn.2795110Search in Google Scholar

Rainie, L, J. Anderson, and J. Albright. 2017. The Future of Free Speech, Trolls, Anonymity and Fake News Online. Washington: Pew Research Center.Search in Google Scholar

Reisinger, M., L. Ressner, and R. Schmidtke. 2009. “Two-Sided Markets with Pecuniary and Participation Externalities.” The Journal of Industrial Economics 57: 32–57, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6451.2009.00373.x.10.1111/j.1467-6451.2009.00373.xSearch in Google Scholar

Rochet, J.-C., and J. Tirole. 2003. “Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets.” Journal of the European Economic Association 1: 990–1029, https://doi.org/10.1162/154247603322493212.10.1162/154247603322493212Search in Google Scholar

Rothbauer, J., and G. Sieg. 2013. “Public Service Broadcasting of Sport, Shows, and News to Mitigate Rational Ignorance.” The Journal of Media Economics 26: 21–40, https://doi.org/10.1080/08997764.2012.755985.10.1080/08997764.2012.755985Search in Google Scholar

Schuett, F. 2010. “Network Neutrality: A Survey of the Economic Literature.” Review of Network Economics 9: 1–13, https://doi.org/10.2202/1446-9022.1224.10.2202/1446-9022.1224Search in Google Scholar

Sismeiro, C., and A. Mahmood. 2018. “Competitive vs. Complementary Effects in Online Social Networks and News Consumption: A Natural Experiment.” Management Science. forthcoming.10.1287/mnsc.2017.2896Search in Google Scholar

Snyder, J., and D. Strömberg. 2010. “Press Coverage and Political Accountability.” Journal of Political Economy 118: 355–408, https://doi.org/10.1086/652903.10.3386/w13878Search in Google Scholar

Strömberg, D. 2001. “Mass Media and Public Policy.” European Economic Review 45: 652–63, https://doi.org/10.1016/s0014-2921(01)00106-4.10.1016/S0014-2921(01)00106-4Search in Google Scholar

Strömberg, D. 2004a. “Mass Media Competition, Political Competition, and Public Policy.” The Review of Economic Studies 71: 265–84, https://doi.org/10.1111/0034-6527.00284.10.1111/0034-6527.00284Search in Google Scholar

Strömberg, D. 2004b. “Radio’s Impact on Public Spending.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 119: 189–221, https://doi.org/10.1162/003355304772839560.10.1162/003355304772839560Search in Google Scholar

Strömberg, D. 2007. “Natural Disasters, Economic Development, and Humanitarian Aid.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 21: 199–222, https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.21.3.199.10.1257/jep.21.3.199Search in Google Scholar

Strömberg, D. 2008. “How the Electoral College Influences Campaigns and Policy: The Probability of Being Florida.” The American Economic Review 98: 769–807, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.98.3.769.10.1257/aer.98.3.769Search in Google Scholar

Sun, K. 2018. “Bundling, Vertical Differentiation, and Platform Competition.” Review of Network Economics 17(1): 1–23, https://doi.org/10.1515/rne-2017-0046.10.1515/rne-2017-0046Search in Google Scholar

Sun, M., and F. Zhu. 2013. “Ad Revenue and Content Commercialization: Evidence from Blogs.” Management Science 59: 2314–31, https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1120.1704.10.1287/mnsc.1120.1704Search in Google Scholar

Sunstein, C. 2016. #Republic: Divided Democracy in the Age of Social Media. Princeton: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9781400884711Search in Google Scholar

The Pew Research Center. 2016a. State of the News Media 2016. Washington: Pew Research Center.Search in Google Scholar

The Pew Research Center. 2016b. The Modern News Consumer. Washington: Pew Research Center.Search in Google Scholar

The Pew Research Center. 2017. The Future of Truth and Misinformation Online. Washington: Pew Research Center.Search in Google Scholar

The Pew Research Center. 2018a. State of the News Media 2018. Washington: Pew Research Center.Search in Google Scholar

The Pew Research Center. 2018b. News Use across Social Media Platforms 2018. Washington: Pew Research Center.Search in Google Scholar

The Pew Research Center. 2018c. Partisans Remain Sharply Divided in Their Attitudes about the News Media. Washington: Pew Research Center.Search in Google Scholar

von Ehrlich, M., and T. Greiner. 2013. “The Role of Online Platforms for Media Markets – Two-Dimensional Spatial Competition in a Two-Sided Market.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 31: 723–37, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2013.05.003.10.1016/j.ijindorg.2013.05.003Search in Google Scholar

Wallsten, K. 2005. “Political Blogs: Is the Political Blogosphere an Echo Chamber?.” In American Political Science Association’s Annual Meeting. Washington, DC. Department of Political Science, University of California, Berkeley.Search in Google Scholar

Xiang, Y., and D. Soberman. 2014. “Consumer Favorites and the Design of News.” Management Science 60: 188–205, https://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2013.1742.10.1287/mnsc.2013.1742Search in Google Scholar

Yildirim, P., E. Gal-Or, and T. Geylani. 2013. “User-Generated Content and Bias in News Media.” Management Science 59: 2655–66, https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2013.1746.10.1287/mnsc.2013.1746Search in Google Scholar

Received: 2020-03-30
Accepted: 2020-09-15
Published Online: 2020-10-05
Published in Print: 2020-03-26

© 2020 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 7.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/rne-2020-0021/html
Scroll to top button