Abstract
We develop a model of pretrial bargaining under asymmetric information where both the plaintiff and the defendant’s cost of proceeding to trial is an increasing function of the judgment at trial. This contrasts with the standard assumption that costs at trial are a constant. As a result of this assumption, fee shifting can affect the incidence of trial in a model in which it would otherwise have no effect. Fee shifting will increase the incidence of trial if the plaintiff expects to shift the variable costs of trial to the defendant on net and will lower the incidence of trial if the defendant expects to shift these costs to the plaintiff. The model also implies that a reallocation of the variable costs of trial from the defendant to the plaintiff will lower the incidence of trial.
Appendix
Consider a generalized model where the cost of a trial varies positively with the judgment, but is not restricted to vary linearly. The more general cost functions become
where g′(J) > 0 and g″(J) ≤ 0 and wD, wP > 0. When g″(J) = 0, we have the linear case analyzed in Section 2. The w coefficients will be varied as part of our comparative statics exercise. Making use of eqs [23] and [24], we write the expected payoff at trial for a type J plaintiff as follows:
If g(J) =J and we replace the wi with
The expected cost for the defendant at trial against a plaintiff of type J is
where substitutions for CD and CP have been made from eqs [23] and [24]. The defendant’s problem is to choose the offer OD in order to maximize the following:
Note that J* is a function of the offer OD via eq. [25]. The first- and second-order conditions from the maximization of eq. [27] may be expressed as
The equilibrium cutoff type J* is obtained from eq. [28], while eq. [29] may be used to sign the comparative statics. Compared with eq. [6], in eq. [28],
Consider the effect of an increase in the use of fee shifting:
The sign of [30] depends upon the sign of
If we set z0= 0, we obtain the following comparative statics, which are the analogs to eqs [12a–d]:
In eq. [34], it is shown that if wP is increased while wD is decreased by the same amount, the borderline type will increase and fewer cases will proceed to trial. This is the analog to Result 2.
Acknowledgment
We would like to thank two anonymous referees and participants at the 2013 American Law and Economics Association Meeting for providing helpful comment on the paper.
References
Baye, M.R., D. Kovenock, and C.G. de Vries. 2005. “Comparative Analysis of Litigation Systems: An Auction-Theoretic Approach,” 115 Economic Journal 583–601.10.1007/978-3-540-79247-5_24Search in Google Scholar
Bebchuk, L.A. 1984. “Litigation and Settlement Under Imperfect Information,” 15 RAND Journal of Economics 404–415.10.2307/2555448Search in Google Scholar
Bebchuk, L.A. 1988. “Suing Solely to Extract a Settlement Offer,” 17 Journal of Legal Studies 437–450.10.3386/w2161Search in Google Scholar
Braeutigam, R.B., B. Owen, and J. Panzar. 1984. “An Economic Analysis of Alternative Fee Shifting Systems,” 47 Law and Contemporary Problems 173–185.10.2307/1191439Search in Google Scholar
Carbonara, E., and F. Parisi. 2012. “Rent-Seeking and Litigation: The Hidden Virtues of the Loser-Pays Rule.” University of Minnesota Legal Studies Research Paper Series Research Paper No. 12–39.10.2139/ssrn.2144800Search in Google Scholar
Chen, K.P., and J.S. Wang. 2007. “Fee-Shifting Rules in Litigation with Contingency Fees,” 23 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 519–546.10.1093/jleo/ewm011Search in Google Scholar
Clermont, K., and S. Schwab. 2009. “Employment Discrimination Plaintiffs in Federal Court: From Bad to Worse,” 3 Harvard Law and Policy Review 1–33.10.2139/ssrn.1142345Search in Google Scholar
Daughety, A.F. and J.F. Reinganum. 2012. “Settlement,” in Chris W. Sanchirico, ed. Encyclopedia of Law and Economics. Vol. 8, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 386–471.Search in Google Scholar
Farmer, A., and P. Pecorino. 1999. “Legal Expenditure as a Rent-Seeking Game,” 100 Public Choice 271–288.10.1007/978-3-540-79247-5_22Search in Google Scholar
Farmer, A., and P. Pecorino. 2005. “Dispute Rates and Contingency Fees: An Analysis From the Signaling Model,” 71 Southern Economic Journal 566–581.10.2307/20062061Search in Google Scholar
Farmer, A., and P. Pecorino. 2007. “Negative Expected Value Suits in a Signaling Model,” 74 Southern Economic Journal 434–447.10.1002/j.2325-8012.2007.tb00847.xSearch in Google Scholar
Farmer, A., and P. Pecorino. 2013. “Discovery and Disclosure with Asymmetric Information and Endogenous Expenditure at Trial,” 42 Journal of Legal Studies 223–247.10.1086/667932Search in Google Scholar
Fu, Q. 2008. “Litigation, Settlement and Legal Presumptions,” Manuscript, National University of Singapore.Search in Google Scholar
Gong, J., and R.P. McAfee. 2000. “Pretrial Negotiation, Litigation, and Procedural Rules,” 38 Economic Inquiry 218–238.10.1111/j.1465-7295.2000.tb00015.xSearch in Google Scholar
Gradstein, M. 1995. “Intensity of Competition, Entry and Entry Deterrence in Rent Seeking Contests,” 7 Economics and Politics 79–91.10.1111/j.1468-0343.1995.tb00105.xSearch in Google Scholar
Gravelle, H., and M. Waterson. 1993. No Win, No Fee: Some Economics of Contingent Legal Fees,” 103 Economic Journal 1205–1220.10.2307/2234246Search in Google Scholar
Hause, J.C. 1989. “Indemnity, Settlement, and Litigation, or I’ll Be Suiting You,” 18 Journal of Legal Studies 157–179.10.1086/468144Search in Google Scholar
Hersch, J., and K. Viscusi. 2007. “Tort Liability Litigation Costs for Commercial Claims,” 9 American Law and Economics Review 303–369.10.1093/aler/ahm011Search in Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, J., and E. Osborne. 2001. “Truth, Effort and the Legal Battle,” 108 Public Choice 169–195.10.1023/A:1017520505573Search in Google Scholar
Kaplow, L. 1994. “The Value of Accuracy in Adjudication: An Economic Analysis,” 23 Journal of Legal Studies 307–401.10.1086/467927Search in Google Scholar
Kaplow, L. and S. Shavell. 1996. “Accuracy in the Assessment of Damages.” Journal of Law and Economics 39: 191–210.10.3386/w4287Search in Google Scholar
Katz, A. 1988. “Judicial Decisionmaking and Litigation Expenditure,” 8 International Review of Law and Economics 127–143.10.1016/0144-8188(88)90001-4Search in Google Scholar
Katz, Avery. 1990. “The Effect of Frivolous Lawsuits on the Settlement of Litigation,” 10 International Review of Law and Economics 3–27.10.1016/0144-8188(90)90002-BSearch in Google Scholar
Katz, A., and C.W. Sanchirico. 2010. “Fee Shifting in Litigation: Survey and Assessment,” Institute for Law and Economics Research Paper No. 10–30.10.2139/ssrn.1714089Search in Google Scholar
Kobayashi, B., and J. Lott. 1996 “In Defense of Criminal Defense Expenditures and Plea Bargaining,” 16 International Review of Law and Economics 397–416.10.1016/S0144-8188(96)00034-8Search in Google Scholar
Lee III, E.G., and T.E. Willging. 2010. “Litigation Costs in Civil Cases: Multivariate Analysis,” Report to the Judicial Advisory Committee on Civil Rights, Federal Judicial Center March 2010.10.2139/ssrn.1606846Search in Google Scholar
Lee, C., and R. LaFountain. 2011. “Medicaid Malpractice Litigation in State Courts,” 18 Court Statistics Project 1–7.Search in Google Scholar
Lemley, M.A. 2010. “Where to File Your Patent Case,” 38 AIPLA Quarterly Journal 401–436.10.2139/ssrn.1597919Search in Google Scholar
Leshem, S. 2009. “Contingent Fees, Signaling and Settlement Authority,” 5 Review of Law and Economics 435–460.10.2202/1555-5879.1274Search in Google Scholar
Nalebuff, B. 1987. “Credible Pretrial Negotiation,” 18 RAND Journal of Economics 198–210.10.2307/2555547Search in Google Scholar
Parisi, F. 2002. “Rent-Seeking Through Litigation: Adversarial and Inquisitorial Systems Compared,” 22 International Review of Law and Economics 193–216.10.1007/978-3-540-79247-5_23Search in Google Scholar
Plott, C.R. 1987. “Legal Fees: A Comparison of the American and English Rules,” 3 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 185–192.Search in Google Scholar
Poitras, M., and R. Frasca. 2011. “A Unified Model of Settlement and Trial Expenditures: The Priest-Klein Model Extended,” 31 International Review of Law and Economics 188–195.10.1016/j.irle.2011.07.006Search in Google Scholar
Polinsky, A.M., and S. Shavell. 2014. “Costly Litigation and Optimal Damages,” 37 International Review of Law and Economics 86–89.10.3386/w18594Search in Google Scholar
Priest, G.L., and B. Klein. 1984. “The Selection of Disputes for Litigation,” 13 Journal of Legal Studies 1–55.10.1086/467732Search in Google Scholar
Reinganum, J.F., and L.L. Wilde. 1986. “Settlement, Litigation, and the Allocation of Litigation Costs,” 17 RAND Journal of Economics 557–566.10.2307/2555481Search in Google Scholar
Shavell, Steven. 1982. “Suit, Settlement, and Trial: A Theoretical Analysis Under Alternative Methods for the Allocation of Legal Costs,” 11 Journal of Legal Studies 55–82.10.3386/w0662Search in Google Scholar
Spier, K.E. 2007. “Litigation,” In A.M. Polinsky, and S. Shavell, eds. Handbook of Law and Economics Vol. 1. Amsterdam, the Netherlands: North Holland, 259–342.10.1016/S1574-0730(07)01004-3Search in Google Scholar
Tullock, G. 1980. “Efficient Rent Seeking,” In J.M. Buchanan, R.D. Tollison, and G. Tullock, eds. Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society. College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press.Search in Google Scholar
©2016 by De Gruyter
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Litigation with a Variable Cost of Trial
- Ex ante versus Ex post Governance: A Behavioral Perspective
- Risk Aversion, the Hand Rule, and Comparison between Strict Liability and the Negligence Rule
- Takings and Tax Revenue: Fiscal Impacts of Eminent Domain
- When Should Governments Reveal Criminal Histories?
- Ideology and Strategy among Politicians: The Case of Judicial Independence
- Tax Return as a Political Statement
- What Makes Law to Change Behavior? An Experimental Study
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Litigation with a Variable Cost of Trial
- Ex ante versus Ex post Governance: A Behavioral Perspective
- Risk Aversion, the Hand Rule, and Comparison between Strict Liability and the Negligence Rule
- Takings and Tax Revenue: Fiscal Impacts of Eminent Domain
- When Should Governments Reveal Criminal Histories?
- Ideology and Strategy among Politicians: The Case of Judicial Independence
- Tax Return as a Political Statement
- What Makes Law to Change Behavior? An Experimental Study