Home Litigation with a Variable Cost of Trial
Article
Licensed
Unlicensed Requires Authentication

Litigation with a Variable Cost of Trial

  • Amy Farmer EMAIL logo and Paul Pecorino
Published/Copyright: May 21, 2015
Become an author with De Gruyter Brill

Abstract

We develop a model of pretrial bargaining under asymmetric information where both the plaintiff and the defendant’s cost of proceeding to trial is an increasing function of the judgment at trial. This contrasts with the standard assumption that costs at trial are a constant. As a result of this assumption, fee shifting can affect the incidence of trial in a model in which it would otherwise have no effect. Fee shifting will increase the incidence of trial if the plaintiff expects to shift the variable costs of trial to the defendant on net and will lower the incidence of trial if the defendant expects to shift these costs to the plaintiff. The model also implies that a reallocation of the variable costs of trial from the defendant to the plaintiff will lower the incidence of trial.

Appendix

Consider a generalized model where the cost of a trial varies positively with the judgment, but is not restricted to vary linearly. The more general cost functions become

[23]CD=θD0+wDg(J),
[24]CP=θP0+wPg(J),

where g′(J) > 0 and g″(J) ≤ 0 and wD, wP > 0. When g″(J) = 0, we have the linear case analyzed in Section 2. The w coefficients will be varied as part of our comparative statics exercise. Making use of eqs [23] and [24], we write the expected payoff at trial for a type J plaintiff as follows:

[25]EPTrial(J)=pJg(J)[(1pz0)wP+(1p)z0wD]((1pz0)θP0+(1p)z0θD0)

If g(J) =J and we replace the wi with θi1, then eq. [25] will reduce to eq. [3]. As before, the borderline type J* is solved from OD=EPTrial(J). All plaintiffs of type JJ* will accept the offer OD and all plaintiffs J > J* will reject the offer and proceed to trial.

The expected cost for the defendant at trial against a plaintiff of type J is

[26]EDTrial(J)=pJ+g(J)(pz0wP+[1(1p)z0]wD)+pz0θP0+[1(1p)z0]θD0

where substitutions for CD and CP have been made from eqs [23] and [24]. The defendant’s problem is to choose the offer OD in order to maximize the following:

[27](ODF(J*)+(1F(J*))[pz0θP0+(1z0(1p)θD0)]+J*J¯[pJ+g(J)(pz0wP+[1(1p)z0]wD)]f(J)dJ).

Note that J* is a function of the offer OD via eq. [25]. The first- and second-order conditions from the maximization of eq. [27] may be expressed as

[28]f(J*)(g(J*)[wP+wD]+θP0+θD0)=F(J*)(pwPg'(J*)+z0g'(J*)[pwP(1p)wD])
[29]f(J*)(pg'(J*)[2wP+wD]+z0g'(J*)[pwP(1p)wD])f'(J*)(g(J*)[wP+wD]+θP0+θD0)F(J*)g''(J*)(1pz0)wP+(1p)z0wD)Δ'>0

The equilibrium cutoff type J* is obtained from eq. [28], while eq. [29] may be used to sign the comparative statics. Compared with eq. [6], in eq. [28], g(J)wP+wD replaces J[θP1+θD1] on the left-hand side, while pwPg(J)+z0g(J)[pwP(1p)wD] replaces pθP1+z0[pθP1(1p)θD1] on the right-hand side. If we assume that g(J) is linear, eqs [28] and [29] will reduce to eqs [6] and [7].

Consider the effect of an increase in the use of fee shifting:

[30]dJdz0=F(J)g(J)[1p]wDpwPΔ

The sign of [30] depends upon the sign of [1p]wDpwP. If this term is positive, the defendant is shifting fees onto the plaintiff in expected value terms, and increased use of fee shifting lowers the incidence of trial. If [1p]wDpwP<0 then the plaintiff is shifting fees onto the defendant in expected value terms, and increased use of fee shifting results in a higher incidence of trial. Thus, the analog to Result 1 holds.

If we set z0= 0, we obtain the following comparative statics, which are the analogs to eqs [12a–d]:

[31]dJdθD0=dJdθP0=f(J)Δ>0
[32]dJdwD=f(J)g(J)Δ>0
[33]dJdwP=f(J)g(J)+F(J)g(J)Δ>0
[34]dJ*dwP|dwD=dwP=F(J*)g(J*)Δ>0

In eq. [34], it is shown that if wP is increased while wD is decreased by the same amount, the borderline type will increase and fewer cases will proceed to trial. This is the analog to Result 2.

Acknowledgment

We would like to thank two anonymous referees and participants at the 2013 American Law and Economics Association Meeting for providing helpful comment on the paper.

References

Baye, M.R., D. Kovenock, and C.G. de Vries. 2005. “Comparative Analysis of Litigation Systems: An Auction-Theoretic Approach,” 115 Economic Journal 583–601.10.1007/978-3-540-79247-5_24Search in Google Scholar

Bebchuk, L.A. 1984. “Litigation and Settlement Under Imperfect Information,” 15 RAND Journal of Economics 404–415.10.2307/2555448Search in Google Scholar

Bebchuk, L.A. 1988. “Suing Solely to Extract a Settlement Offer,” 17 Journal of Legal Studies 437–450.10.3386/w2161Search in Google Scholar

Braeutigam, R.B., B. Owen, and J. Panzar. 1984. “An Economic Analysis of Alternative Fee Shifting Systems,” 47 Law and Contemporary Problems 173–185.10.2307/1191439Search in Google Scholar

Carbonara, E., and F. Parisi. 2012. “Rent-Seeking and Litigation: The Hidden Virtues of the Loser-Pays Rule.” University of Minnesota Legal Studies Research Paper Series Research Paper No. 12–39.10.2139/ssrn.2144800Search in Google Scholar

Chen, K.P., and J.S. Wang. 2007. “Fee-Shifting Rules in Litigation with Contingency Fees,” 23 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 519–546.10.1093/jleo/ewm011Search in Google Scholar

Clermont, K., and S. Schwab. 2009. “Employment Discrimination Plaintiffs in Federal Court: From Bad to Worse,” 3 Harvard Law and Policy Review 1–33.10.2139/ssrn.1142345Search in Google Scholar

Daughety, A.F. and J.F. Reinganum. 2012. “Settlement,” in Chris W. Sanchirico, ed. Encyclopedia of Law and Economics. Vol. 8, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 386–471.Search in Google Scholar

Farmer, A., and P. Pecorino. 1999. “Legal Expenditure as a Rent-Seeking Game,” 100 Public Choice 271–288.10.1007/978-3-540-79247-5_22Search in Google Scholar

Farmer, A., and P. Pecorino. 2005. “Dispute Rates and Contingency Fees: An Analysis From the Signaling Model,” 71 Southern Economic Journal 566–581.10.2307/20062061Search in Google Scholar

Farmer, A., and P. Pecorino. 2007. “Negative Expected Value Suits in a Signaling Model,” 74 Southern Economic Journal 434–447.10.1002/j.2325-8012.2007.tb00847.xSearch in Google Scholar

Farmer, A., and P. Pecorino. 2013. “Discovery and Disclosure with Asymmetric Information and Endogenous Expenditure at Trial,” 42 Journal of Legal Studies 223–247.10.1086/667932Search in Google Scholar

Fu, Q. 2008. “Litigation, Settlement and Legal Presumptions,” Manuscript, National University of Singapore.Search in Google Scholar

Gong, J., and R.P. McAfee. 2000. “Pretrial Negotiation, Litigation, and Procedural Rules,” 38 Economic Inquiry 218–238.10.1111/j.1465-7295.2000.tb00015.xSearch in Google Scholar

Gradstein, M. 1995. “Intensity of Competition, Entry and Entry Deterrence in Rent Seeking Contests,” 7 Economics and Politics 79–91.10.1111/j.1468-0343.1995.tb00105.xSearch in Google Scholar

Gravelle, H., and M. Waterson. 1993. No Win, No Fee: Some Economics of Contingent Legal Fees,” 103 Economic Journal 1205–1220.10.2307/2234246Search in Google Scholar

Hause, J.C. 1989. “Indemnity, Settlement, and Litigation, or I’ll Be Suiting You,” 18 Journal of Legal Studies 157–179.10.1086/468144Search in Google Scholar

Hersch, J., and K. Viscusi. 2007. “Tort Liability Litigation Costs for Commercial Claims,” 9 American Law and Economics Review 303–369.10.1093/aler/ahm011Search in Google Scholar

Hirshleifer, J., and E. Osborne. 2001. “Truth, Effort and the Legal Battle,” 108 Public Choice 169–195.10.1023/A:1017520505573Search in Google Scholar

Kaplow, L. 1994. “The Value of Accuracy in Adjudication: An Economic Analysis,” 23 Journal of Legal Studies 307–401.10.1086/467927Search in Google Scholar

Kaplow, L. and S. Shavell. 1996. “Accuracy in the Assessment of Damages.” Journal of Law and Economics 39: 191–210.10.3386/w4287Search in Google Scholar

Katz, A. 1988. “Judicial Decisionmaking and Litigation Expenditure,” 8 International Review of Law and Economics 127–143.10.1016/0144-8188(88)90001-4Search in Google Scholar

Katz, Avery. 1990. “The Effect of Frivolous Lawsuits on the Settlement of Litigation,” 10 International Review of Law and Economics 3–27.10.1016/0144-8188(90)90002-BSearch in Google Scholar

Katz, A., and C.W. Sanchirico. 2010. “Fee Shifting in Litigation: Survey and Assessment,” Institute for Law and Economics Research Paper No. 10–30.10.2139/ssrn.1714089Search in Google Scholar

Kobayashi, B., and J. Lott. 1996 “In Defense of Criminal Defense Expenditures and Plea Bargaining,” 16 International Review of Law and Economics 397–416.10.1016/S0144-8188(96)00034-8Search in Google Scholar

Lee III, E.G., and T.E. Willging. 2010. “Litigation Costs in Civil Cases: Multivariate Analysis,” Report to the Judicial Advisory Committee on Civil Rights, Federal Judicial Center March 2010.10.2139/ssrn.1606846Search in Google Scholar

Lee, C., and R. LaFountain. 2011. “Medicaid Malpractice Litigation in State Courts,” 18 Court Statistics Project 1–7.Search in Google Scholar

Lemley, M.A. 2010. “Where to File Your Patent Case,” 38 AIPLA Quarterly Journal 401–436.10.2139/ssrn.1597919Search in Google Scholar

Leshem, S. 2009. “Contingent Fees, Signaling and Settlement Authority,” 5 Review of Law and Economics 435–460.10.2202/1555-5879.1274Search in Google Scholar

Nalebuff, B. 1987. “Credible Pretrial Negotiation,” 18 RAND Journal of Economics 198–210.10.2307/2555547Search in Google Scholar

Parisi, F. 2002. “Rent-Seeking Through Litigation: Adversarial and Inquisitorial Systems Compared,” 22 International Review of Law and Economics 193–216.10.1007/978-3-540-79247-5_23Search in Google Scholar

Plott, C.R. 1987. “Legal Fees: A Comparison of the American and English Rules,” 3 Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 185–192.Search in Google Scholar

Poitras, M., and R. Frasca. 2011. “A Unified Model of Settlement and Trial Expenditures: The Priest-Klein Model Extended,” 31 International Review of Law and Economics 188–195.10.1016/j.irle.2011.07.006Search in Google Scholar

Polinsky, A.M., and S. Shavell. 2014. “Costly Litigation and Optimal Damages,” 37 International Review of Law and Economics 86–89.10.3386/w18594Search in Google Scholar

Priest, G.L., and B. Klein. 1984. “The Selection of Disputes for Litigation,” 13 Journal of Legal Studies 1–55.10.1086/467732Search in Google Scholar

Reinganum, J.F., and L.L. Wilde. 1986. “Settlement, Litigation, and the Allocation of Litigation Costs,” 17 RAND Journal of Economics 557–566.10.2307/2555481Search in Google Scholar

Shavell, Steven. 1982. “Suit, Settlement, and Trial: A Theoretical Analysis Under Alternative Methods for the Allocation of Legal Costs,” 11 Journal of Legal Studies 55–82.10.3386/w0662Search in Google Scholar

Spier, K.E. 2007. “Litigation,” In A.M. Polinsky, and S. Shavell, eds. Handbook of Law and Economics Vol. 1. Amsterdam, the Netherlands: North Holland, 259–342.10.1016/S1574-0730(07)01004-3Search in Google Scholar

Tullock, G. 1980. “Efficient Rent Seeking,” In J.M. Buchanan, R.D. Tollison, and G. Tullock, eds. Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society. College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2015-5-21
Published in Print: 2016-7-1

©2016 by De Gruyter

Downloaded on 18.9.2025 from https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/rle-2015-0004/html
Scroll to top button