Abstract
From the early 2000s onwards, the rise in net lending of the nonfinancial corporate sector has contributed substantially to the increase in the German current account surplus. The main driving factor behind the development in the nonfinancial corporate sector’s net lending was a rise in savings (retained earnings) while business investment was comparatively stable. To shed light on the determinants of corporate savings, this study presents results from an analysis using firm-level data from the recently developed Bundesbank database Janis. The descriptive analysis suggests that the increase in corporate savings was a widespread development across the corporate sector in Germany. In line with aggregate results, also the median firm saw an increase in profitability while dividends were subdued. Empirical results show that firms with initially higher leverage ratios increased their saving ratios more after the year 2001, providing arguments for a role of a desire to deleverage in explaining increased corporate savings. No (unanimous) evidence is found that increases in uncertainty and market power of firms affect corporate savings positively.
Acknowledgment
I would like to thank the editor, Peter Winker, the guest editor and three anonymous referees for their helpful comments and suggestions. I am also grateful to my colleagues Philipp Meinen and Arne Nagengast for their advice and support.
A Appendix
A.1 Variables
This section provides details on the definition of variables used in this study and how they are constructed using the items in the dataset Janis. Variables are defined following the definition of items from extrapolated results from financial statements of German enterprises, published by the Bundesbank (see Special Statistical Publication 5).
Equity (adjusted) is defined as
where other equity terms (item P21200) include equity-equivalent partner loans or partner loans with a subordinate claim, equity-equivalent profit participation capital, equity-equivalent contributions by silent partners, and reserves (book equity including other equity terms is P21000 + 0.5*P22000 + P23000). Adjustments include deficit not covered by equity (A17000), outstanding contributions to subscribed capital (A11000), treasury shares (A14320), deferred tax assets (A16000), business start-up and expansion expenses (A12000), discount (A15010), self created industrial and similar rights and assets (A13150), and other adjustments (A18000). The equity ratio is calculated as
Assets (adjusted) are given by book assets (A10000) minus adjustments (see above):
Gross value added is given by gross profits (G36000):
where total output (G33000) includes sales (G30000), increase or decrease in finished and unfinished goods inventories and work in progress (G31000), and other own work capitalized (G31000). Cost of materials (G35000) includes cost of raw materials, consumables and supplies (G35100), and of purchased merchandise and services (G35200).
Net savings are defined as
where
The increase in capital of corporations is given by
Labor costs are given by personnel expenses (G37000) which include wages and salaries as well as social security, post employment and other employee benefit costs.
Depreciation (total) includes depreciation of fixed assets (amortization and write-downs of intangible fixed assets, depreciation and write-downs of tangible fixed assets and amortization of capitalized business start-up and expansion expenses), write-downs of current assets to the extent that they exceed the write-downs that are usual for the corporation (G38000), and also write-downs of long-term financial assets and securities classified as current assets (G50000).
Interest costs are given by interest and similar expenses (G52000).
Investment income is defined as
Other costs (net of other income) are defined as
Total taxes include taxes on income (G60000) and earnings and other taxes such as operating taxes and purchase tax (G61000).
The effective tax rate (ETR) is given by
where earnings before taxes (EBT) are calculated as
The dividend payout ratio is defined as
Since the designated dividend (P21C10) is not a mandatory field and only reported by a fraction of companies. However, it is not possible to distinguish between actual zero values and missing values.
Firm size is measured by the natural logarithm of assets (adjusted) deflated by the Consumer Price Index (CPI).
As profitability measure, returns on earnings (ROA) are used, which are calculated as
where earnings before interest and taxes are given by operating result (G45000).
Dividend payer is a dummy variable which equals one if a company pays out cash in the given period and zero otherwise. To construct this variable, a payout proxy is calculated as
where retained earnings are given by the capital increase from profits.[42]
Intangibles are defined as book intangible assets (A13100) minus goodwill (A13120) and internally generated industrial rights and similar rights and assets (A13150). The intangible share is calculated as
where fixed assets include tangible assets and intangible assets (A13200).
Cash flow is calculated as
Industry sigma (cashflow risk) is the standard deviation of industry cash flow to assets (adjusted). Standard deviation of cash flow to assets is computed for every firm-year using data over the previous five years. Cash flow standard deviations are then averaged each year over all firms within an industry.
The interest rate of firms paid is calculated as
where the interest-bearing debt is defined as total liabilities (P25000) minus payments received on account (P25300) and liabilities arising from goods and services (P25400).
The (real) wage rate is defined as
where real labor costs are labor costs deflated by the CPI. Since the number of employees (EMPL) is not a mandatory field, the wage rate is only observed for a fraction of companies.
Sales growth is defined as the log-difference of sales deflated by the Consumer Price Index (CPI).
Total debt (P25000 + A14140 + A14214) includes liabilities, provisions, deferred income, and the proportionate special tax-allowable reserve.
Bank debt is given by liabilities to credit institutions (P25200).
Cash is defined as cash, Bundesbank balances, balances at credit institutions and cheques (A14400) plus current asset securities excluding own shares (A14300-A14320).
Capital expenditures or gross investments (Capex) are defined as
Depreciation of fixed assets is depreciation on intangible assets and tangible assets as well as on capitalized start-up and business expansion expenses (G38100).
Acquisitions (of other long-term equity investments) are defined as
where other long-term equity investments are given by other long-term equity investments plus shares in affiliated companies and goodwill (A13340 + A13310 + A13120). Acquisitions are normalized by assets (adjusted).
Economic policy uncertainty is measured by the Economic Policy Uncertainty Index (PU) from Baker et al. (2016).
A.2 Variables for Computing Firm-Level Markups
For computing markups, the input factors capital, labor, and materials (intermediate goods) are used. The firm-specific wage rate is chosen as the input price to identify the gross output production function.
The real capital stock is generated following Eslava et al. (2004) and given by:
where K
it
is firm i’s capital stock,
The cost of materials comprises cost of raw materials, consumables and supplies, and of purchased merchandise and services.
The number of employees defines the labor input. This variable is only observed for a fraction of firms, since it is not a mandatory field. Therefore, the sample used to calculate markups is limited to firms who report the number of employees.
The wage rate as input price for labor is calculated as described in Section A.1.
Materials, wages, and gross value added are deflated using an industry-specific intermediate goods price index, the CPI, and an industry-specific price index, respectively. The depreciation rate is calculated each year using aggregate data on depreciation and capital stock from National Accounts.
A.3 Descriptives

Median net income of German non-financial corporations (in % of GVA).
Source: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, own calculations.

Wage and interest rate payments of German non-financial corporations.
Source: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, own calculations.

Median dividend payout and equity ratio of German non-financial corporations.
Source: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, own calculations.

Mean and median intangibles as a share of total fixed assets of German nonfinancial corporations.
Source: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, own calculations.
A.4 Determinants of Corporate Savings: Deleveraging
A.4.1 Main Results: Different Window Sizes
DID regressions: debt (three year window).
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Binary | Continuous | Controls | Placebo | EB | |
DID | −0.044*** (0.008) | −0.161*** (0.032) | −0.044*** (0.008) | −0.041*** (0.009) | −0.004 (0.018) |
Placebo | −0.009 (0.008) | ||||
N | 46,086 | 46,086 | 46,086 | 46,086 | 46,086 |
-
Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm-level. Standard errors are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical difference from zero at the 10, 5, and the 1% level, respectively. Sources: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, Ustan (1987–2017), retrieved December 11, 2019, own calculations.
DID regressions: debt (five year window).
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Binary | Continuous | Controls | Placebo | EB | |
DID | −0.015** (0.006) | −0.061** (0.031) | −0.016** (0.006) | −0.018** (0.008) | −0.001 (0.010) |
Placebo | 0.004 (0.006) | ||||
N | 48,140 | 48,140 | 48,140 | 48,140 | 48,140 |
-
Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm-level. Standard errors are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical difference from zero at the 10, 5, and the 1% level, respectively. Sources: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, Ustan (1987–2017), retrieved December 11, 2019, own calculations.
DID regressions: bank debt (three year window).
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Binary | Continuous | Controls | Placebo | EB | |
DID | 0.019** (0.008) | 0.056*** (0.018) | 0.017** (0.008) | 0.022** (0.009) | 0.001 (0.008) |
Placebo | −0.010 (0.008) | ||||
N | 46,086 | 46,086 | 46,086 | 46,086 | 46,086 |
-
Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm-level. Standard errors are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical difference from zero at the 10, 5, and the 1% level, respectively. Sources: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, Ustan (1987–2017), retrieved December 11, 2019, own calculations.
DID regressions: bank debt (five year window).
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Binary | Continuous | Controls | Placebo | EB | |
DID | 0.010 (0.006) | 0.036** (0.014) | 0.009 (0.006) | 0.009 (0.008) | 0.002 (0.006) |
Placebo | 0.000 (0.006) | ||||
N | 48,140 | 48,140 | 48,140 | 48,140 | 48,140 |
-
Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm-level. Standard errors are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical difference from zero at the 10, 5, and the 1% level, respectively. Sources: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, Ustan (1987–2017), retrieved December 11, 2019, own calculations.

Determinants of corporate savings: Generalized difference-in-differences.
Source: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, own calculations.

Determinants of corporate savings: Generalized difference-in-differences.
Source: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, own calculations.
A.4.2 Additional Results
To study more closely the impact of the corporate tax reform 2001 and the role of intangibles, additional estimations were performed. According to Givoly (1992), firms with a high marginal effective corporate tax rate will change their capital structure more than firms with a low marginal effective corporate tax rate in response to the same change in the statutory corporate tax rate. Hence, one would expect that firms with high marginal tax rates increased their saving ratios more than firms with low marginal tax rates in response to the tax rate reductions by the reform (see also Jüppner and Nagengast 2018). In the employed dataset, there is no data on firm-specific marginal tax rates. To evaluate the tax channel, one may follow Givoly (1992) by using tax payments over earnings before taxes as a proxy for the marginal tax rate of firms. Using this approach, however, no significant and robust evidence is obtained that firms with high income tax rates increased their saving ratio after 2001 more strongly than firms with low income tax rates (see Table A.5). Since, the employed proxy for marginal tax rates is rather crude, the effects can only be measured with a considerable degree of uncertainty in this approach. Results could therefore also indicate that the effective tax rate is not a suitable proxy in this case. A similar problem may arise when looking at the share of intangible assets in total fixed assets. Also in this case, there is no significant evidence that firms with higher intangible shares increased their saving ratios more compared to firms with lower intangible shares (see Table A.6). As pointed out by Crouzet and Eberly (2019), using the book value of intangibles may be problematic. To properly analyze the effects of intangible assets on corporate savings, a deeper analysis using a different measure for intangible capital may be needed.[43]
Determinants of corporate savings: income tax (four year window).
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Binary | Continuous | Controls | Placebo | EB | |
DID | 0.007 (0.007) | 0.008 (0.017) | 0.011 (0.007) | 0.007 (0.008) | 0.006 (0.007) |
Placebo | 0.000 (0.007) | ||||
N | 44,544 | 44,544 | 44,544 | 44,544 | 44,544 |
-
Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm-level. Standard errors are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical difference from zero at the 10, 5, and the 1% level, respectively. Sources: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, Ustan (1987–2017), retrieved December 11, 2019, own calculations.
Determinants of corporate savings: intangibles (four year window).
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Binary | Continuous | Controls | Placebo | EB | |
DID | −0.001 (0.006) | 0.016 (0.041) | 0.002 (0.006) | −0.002 (0.007) | 0.001 (0.006) |
Placebo | 0.002 (0.006) | ||||
N | 42,808 | 42,808 | 42,808 | 42,808 | 42,808 |
-
Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm-level. Standard errors are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical difference from zero at the 10, 5, and the 1% level, respectively. Sources: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, Ustan (1987–2017), retrieved December 11, 2019, own calculations.
A.4.3 Robustness Checks
When studying deleveraging processes, one needs to distinguish between the motive/desire for deleveraging and the actual increase in equity ratios as a use of net saving. The previous analysis showed that firms with higher leverage prior to 2001 subsequently increased saving ratios more. Instead of a desire to deleverage, it is also plausible that firms with higher leverage ratios benefited more from the decline in interest rates and associated reductions in debt servicing costs, which boosted their profits and net savings. At the firm-level, Figure 2 shows a sizable decrease in interest costs for the median firm and panel results from Section 6.2 show that interest rates are significantly negatively correlated with net savings.[44] However, this is already indirectly taken into account in the estimation using Eq. (3) by including profitability as additional control variable. Deleveraging results are still significant in this case and they also remain significant (for all window sizes) when interest costs over interest-bearing debt (as interest rate proxy) are included as a separate control variable (see Table A.7).
DiD regressions: debt (controlling for interest costs).
(1) | (2) | (3) | |
---|---|---|---|
Three-year window | Four-year window | Five-year window | |
DID | 0.043*** (0.008) | 0.028*** (0.007) | 0.017*** (0.006) |
Firm size | −0.119*** (0.013) | −0.080*** (0.010) | −0.068*** (0.009) |
Profitability | −0.134*** (0.038) | −0.069** (0.031) | −0.046* (0.026) |
Interest rate | −0.061 (0.113) | −0.163** (0.067) | −0.186*** (0.068) |
N | 45,720 | 45,200 | 47,740 |
-
Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm-level. Standard errors are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical difference from zero at the 10, 5, and the 1% level, respectively. Sources: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, Ustan (1987–2017), retrieved December 11, 2019, own calculations.
To further account for decreasing interest costs as source of higher savings, a triple DID approach can be considered. This approach tests whether the DID deleveraging effect is different for firms with high interest rates (defined as interest costs relative to interest-bearing debt) compared to firms with low interest rates. In addition to the initial leverage ratio, the initial interest rate is used as a second treatment variable:
where d1 is the first treatment variable (leverage ratio) and d2 is the second treatment variable (interest rate). The treatment variables are again defined on the median. The coefficient of interest is κ 6, i.e. the coefficient on the interaction term between the two treatment variables and the post-2001 dummy. Results from Table A.8 suggest that the deleveraging effect on saving ratios of firms with high interest rates was not significantly different compared to the deleveraging effect for firms with low interest rates (i.e. the triple DID coefficient is insignificant). Results hold when using different window sizes for the panel regression (not shown here but available upon request). Overall, findings suggest that the general deleveraging process is also driven by a desire to deleverage and not only the result of increased profits.
Triple DID regressions: debt and interest costs (four year window).
Deleveraging motive | |
---|---|
Post × Treated_Interest | −0.013 (0.012) |
Post × Treated_Debt | 0.024*** (0.008) |
T-DiD | 0.010 (0.013) |
N | 45,184 |
-
Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm-level. Standard errors are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical difference from zero at the 10, 5, and the 1% level, respectively. Sources: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, Ustan (1987–2017), retrieved December 11, 2019, own calculations.
Since this study analyzes in detail the deleveraging motive for increased corporate savings, a thorough investigation of the actual use of savings is beyond the scope of this paper. However, to provide more evidence on the deleveraging hypothesis, one can use a simple regression to show that savings were indeed used to increase equity ratios. Computing mean saving and equity (leverage) ratios for the post-2001 and pre-2001 periods, the change in equity ratios (post- vs. pre-2001) can be regressed on the post-2001 saving ratio, controlling for the pre-2001 leverage ratio. Results show that controlling for initial leverage, subsequent increases in savings lead to a significantly higher speed at which firms deleverage (see Table A.9). To provide further support for actual deleveraging, one can test whether firms with initially high leverage ratios decreased their leverage ratios more. When performing a simple DID estimation as in Eq. (1) but using the equity ratio as dependent variable, results show that firms with initially high leverage ratios in the pre-2001 period increased their equity ratios more (see Table A.10). Actually, such an analysis has already been done by Deutsche Bundesbank (2019b) considering changes of the equity ratio around the year 1998 but showing the same pattern. In fact, due to mean reversion of leverage ratios, which is widely documented in the literature (see e.g. Lemmon et al. 2008), one can generally observe that firms with initially lower equity ratios subsequently increase their equity ratios more.[45] However, looking at additional Placebo regressions for years before 2001, the magnitude of the effect is largest in 2001 (see Table A.10).
Speed of delivering.
Three-year window | Four-year window | Five-year window | |
---|---|---|---|
Pre-2001 mean equity ratio | −0.081*** (0.009) | −0.115*** (0.012) | −0.137*** (0.014) |
Post-2001 mean saving ratio | 0.072*** (0.008) | 0.121*** (0.016) | 0.119*** (0.020) |
N | 7681 | 5700 | 4814 |
-
Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical difference from zero at the 10, 5, and the 1% level, respectively. Sources: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, Ustan (1987–2017), retrieved December 11, 2019, own calculations.
DiD regressions: equity ratio as dependent variable (four year window).
(1) | (2) | (3) | |
---|---|---|---|
1991 | 1996 | 2001 | |
DID | 0.026*** (0.002) | 0.016*** (0.002) | 0.032*** (0.003) |
N | 103,328 | 71,688 | 55,472 |
-
Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm-level. Standard errors are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical difference from zero at the 10, 5, and the 1% level, respectively. Sources: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, Ustan (1987–2017), retrieved December 11, 2019, own calculations.
Dao and Maggi (2018) find that the trend towards higher corporate saving is concentrated among large publicly listed firms. In a final robustness test, another triple DID estimation is performed investigating whether the deleveraging motive was more relevant for increased savings of large publicly listed firms. In this case, the second treatment variable is a dummy variable showing whether a firm is large and publicly listed:
where, d1 is the first treatment variable (leverage ratio) and d2 is the second treatment variable (referring to firm size and legal form). The first treatment variables areagain defined on the median. The second treatment variable equals one if a firm is large and publicly listed and zero otherwise. The coefficient of interest is κ 7, i.e. the coefficient on the interaction term between the two treatment variables and the post-2001 dummy. Results from Table A.11 suggest that the deleveraging effect on saving ratios of large public firms was not significantly larger compared to the deleveraging effect for other firms (i.e. the triple DiD coefficient is insignificant but also negative). Results hold when using different window sizes for the panel regression (not shown here but also available upon request). This result is in line with the observation that compared to large firms, small and medium sized firms in Germany had significantly lower equity ratios during the 1990s and have increased their equity base more strongly since then (see e.g. Deutsche Bundesbank 2018a, 2019b). One would therefore expect that the deleveraging motive is not stronger for large publicly listed firms.
Triple DiD regressions: debt and firm type (four year window).
Deleveraging motive | |
---|---|
Post × large public firm | 0.006 (0.013) |
Post × Treated_Debt | 0.027*** (0.007) |
T-DiD | −0.022 (0.030) |
N | 45,600 |
-
Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm-level. Standard errors are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical difference from zero at the 10, 5, and the 1% level, respectively. Sources: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, Ustan (1987–2017), retrieved December 11, 2019, own calculations.
A.5 Determinants of Corporate Savings: Firm-Level Markups
This section presents the empirical strategy for estimating firm-level markups.
A.5.1 Empirical Methodology
A.5.1.1 Deriving Markups
Firm-level markups are estimated following the methodology of Loecker and Warzynski (2012), which builds on the work of Hall (1988). This approach only assumes cost-minimizing firms and the presence of at least one variable input that is free of adjustment costs (see also Meinen 2016a,b). Cost minimization and optimal input demand imply that the output elasticity of any variable input is equal to its input cost share:
where X
it
is the choice of input X by firm i in year t,
Assuming imperfect competition, i.e. revenue shares are typically lower than output elasticities, a firm’s markup can be recovered from
where
A.5.1.2 Estimating Output Elasticities and Markups
The estimation procedure consists of two steps and follows Ackerberg et al. (2015). As is standard in the literature, a translog production function is used to estimate the output elasticities. The gross output translog production function is given by:
where all variables in Eq. (A.7) are presented in lower-case letters which indicate logs. y
it
denotes real value added of firm i in year t, l
it
, k
it
, and m
it
are firm-level inputs of labor, capital, and materials, respectively.
In the first stage, the following equation is estimated:
where estimates of expected output (
and
The second stage provides estimates for all production function coefficients by relying on the law of motion for productivity which is modeled as a first-order Markov process:
where
To finally compute markups, the input share is adjusted for potential measurement error and unanticipated shocks to production, as suggested by Loecker and Warzynski (2012). Specifically, the input share is computed as:
where
For the estimation, firms with less than 10 employees are excluded. After estimation, observations with implausible values for the output elasticity of materials are excluded, i.e. for
A.5.1.3 Summary statistics
Markups: summary statistics.
Count | Mean | SD | p1 | p5 | p10 | p25 | p50 | p75 | p90 | p95 | p99 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Markup | 149,977 | 1.23 | 0.28 | 0.86 | 0.92 | 0.96 | 1.04 | 1.17 | 1.35 | 1.57 | 1.79 | 2.32 |
-
Source: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, own calculations.
A.6 Determinants of Corporate Savings: Precautionary Motives and Other Channels
Determinants of corporate savings: weighted panel regressions.
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Intangibles | Taxes | Uncertainty | Policy uncertainty | Input prices | All | Sales growth | |
Size | −0.057*** (0.003) | −0.057*** (0.003) | −0.060*** (0.003) | −0.055*** (0.003) | −0.070*** (0.005) | −0.092*** (0.006) | −0.092*** (0.006) |
Equity ratio | −0.097*** (0.008) | −0.097*** (0.008) | −0.105*** (0.009) | −0.090*** (0.008) | −0.134*** (0.014) | −0.185*** (0.018) | −0.163*** (0.017) |
Profitability | 0.062*** (0.009) | 0.062*** (0.009) | 0.059*** (0.009) | 0.062*** (0.009) | 0.089*** (0.015) | 0.098*** (0.018) | 0.088*** (0.018) |
Dividend payer | −0.104*** (0.002) | −0.104*** (0.002) | −0.111*** (0.002) | −0.104*** (0.002) | −0.080*** (0.003) | −0.086*** (0.003) | −0.078*** (0.003) |
Intangible share | −0.040*** (0.014) | −0.041*** (0.014) | −0.047*** (0.016) | −0.040*** (0.014) | −0.064** (0.025) | −0.089*** (0.033) | −0.043 (0.027) |
Effective tax rate | 0.002 (0.004) | −0.002 (0.005) | 0.001 (0.004) | 0.005 (0.006) | −0.001 (0.009) | 0.010 (0.007) | |
Industry cash flow volatility | −0.168 (0.193) | −0.911** (0.364) | −0.789** (0.326) | ||||
Policy uncertainty | 0.000*** (0.000) | ||||||
Interest rate | −0.083*** (0.022) | −0.088*** (0.023) | −0.067*** (0.020) | ||||
Wage | −0.000 (0.000) | −0.000 (0.000) | −0.000 (0.000) | ||||
Sales growth | 0.024** (0.010) | ||||||
N | 713,810 | 706,722 | 609,072 | 706,722 | 246,167 | 171,295 | 157,062 |
-
Regressions are weighted by the log of firm-specific average real gross value added. Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm-level. Standard errors are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical difference from zero at the 10, 5, and the 1% level, respectively. Source: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, own calculations.
Determinants of corporate savings: weighted cross-sectional regressions.
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Intangibles | Taxes | Input prices | Sales growth | Uncertainty | |
Size | 0.007*** (0.001) | 0.008*** (0.001) | 0.004*** (0.001) | 0.003*** (0.001) | −0.000 (0.001) |
Equity ratio | 0.134*** (0.009) | 0.132*** (0.009) | 0.128*** (0.009) | 0.133*** (0.009) | 0.116*** (0.010) |
Profitability | 0.115*** (0.017) | 0.098*** (0.017) | 0.098*** (0.017) | 0.072*** (0.018) | 0.019 (0.017) |
Dividend payer | −0.006* (0.003) | −0.011*** (0.003) | −0.011*** (0.003) | −0.009*** (0.003) | −0.001 (0.004) |
Intangible share | 0.038* (0.021) | 0.039* (0.021) | 0.012 (0.020) | −0.002 (0.020) | −0.010 (0.020) |
Effective tax rate | 0.054*** (0.007) | 0.050*** (0.007) | 0.045*** (0.007) | 0.030*** (0.009) | |
Interest rate | −0.045* (0.027) | −0.025 (0.027) | −0.025 (0.030) | ||
Wage | 0.001*** (0.000) | 0.001*** (0.000) | 0.001*** (0.000) | ||
Sales growth | 0.180*** (0.025) | 0.256*** (0.032) | |||
Firm-specific cash flow volatility | −0.259*** (0.030) | ||||
N | 25,321 | 25,321 | 25,321 | 25,321 | 18,152 |
-
In specifications (1)–(4), firms with less than three years of observations are excluded. In specification (5), firms with at least five years of observations enter the sample. Regressions are weighted by the log of firm-specific average real gross value added. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical difference from zero at the 10, 5, and the 1% level, respectively. Source: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, own calculations.
A.7 Determinants of Corporate Cash Holdings
In order to investigate which firm characteristics are positively and negatively associated with corporate cash holdings, the following dynamic panel model is estimated:
where

Median liquid assets in % of assets of German nonfinancial corporations.
Source: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, own calculations.
Determinants of corporate cash holdings: dynamic panel regressions.
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
System GMM | System GMM | LD | LD | DPF | DPF | |
Cash ratio | 0.484*** (0.006) | 0.498*** (0.006) | 0.549*** (0.004) | 0.558*** (0.005) | 0.590*** (0.002) | 0.592*** (0.002) |
Intangibles | −0.002 (0.004) | 0.008* (0.004) | 0.003 (0.003) | 0.003 (0.003) | −0.000 (0.002) | −0.000 (0.002) |
Industry sigma | 0.396*** (0.033) | 0.017 (0.022) | −0.177*** (0.040) | −0.154*** (0.029) | 0.013 (0.033) | −0.169*** (0.024) |
Size | −0.012*** (0.001) | −0.015*** (0.001) | −0.006*** (0.001) | −0.004*** (0.001) | −0.009*** (0.000) | −0.008*** (0.000) |
Cash flow | 0.011*** (0.002) | 0.009*** (0.002) | 0.002 (0.002) | 0.002 (0.002) | −0.008*** (0.001) | −0.009*** (0.001) |
Capex | −0.019*** (0.003) | −0.023*** (0.003) | −0.044*** (0.003) | −0.045*** (0.003) | −0.012*** (0.002) | −0.013*** (0.002) |
Acquisitions | −0.012* (0.007) | −0.011 (0.007) | −0.043*** (0.009) | −0.043*** (0.009) | −0.014** (0.006) | −0.016** (0.006) |
Dividend payer | −0.001* (0.000) | −0.001* (0.000) | −0.000 (0.000) | −0.001 (0.000) | 0.001*** (0.000) | 0.001*** (0.000) |
PU | 0.000*** (0.000) | 0.000*** (0.000) | 0.000*** (0.000) | |||
Firm FE | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES | YES |
Year FE | YES | NO | YES | NO | YES | YES |
N | 454,669 | 454,669 | 148,200 | 148,200 | 454,669 | 454,669 |
-
Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm-level, except for specifications (5) and (6). Standard errors are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate statistical difference from zero at the 10, 5, and the 1% level, respectively. Source: Data and Service Centre (RDSC) of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Janis (1997–2017), retrieved November 07, 2019, own calculations.
References
Abadie, A., Diamond, A., and Hainmueller, J. (2010). Synthetic control methods for comparative case studies: estimating the effect of California’s tobacco control program. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 105: 493–505, https://doi.org/10.1198/jasa.2009.ap08746.Search in Google Scholar
Abadie, A. and Gardeazabal, J. (2003). The economic costs of conflict: a case study of the Basque country. Am. Econ. Rev. 93: 113–132, https://doi.org/10.1257/000282803321455188.Search in Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Autor, D.H., and Lyle, D. (2004). Women, war, and wages: the effect of female labor supply on the wage structure at midcentury. J. Polit. Econ. 112: 497–551, https://doi.org/10.1086/383100.Search in Google Scholar
Ackerberg, D.A., Caves, K., and Frazer, G. (2015). Identification properties of recent production function estimators. Econometrica 83: 2411–2451, https://doi.org/10.3982/ecta13408.Search in Google Scholar
André, C., Guichard, S., Kennedy, M., and Turner, D. (2007). Corporate net lending: a review of recent trends. OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 583, Paris.Search in Google Scholar
Armenter, R. and Hnatkovska, V. (2017). Taxes and capital structure: understanding firms’ savings. J. Monetary Econ. 87: 13–33, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2017.03.001.Search in Google Scholar
Baker, S.R., Bloom, N., and Davis, S.J. (2016). Measuring economic policy uncertainty. Q. J. Econ. 131: 1593–1636, https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjw024.Search in Google Scholar
Bates, T.W., Kahle, K.M., and Stulz, R.M. (2009). Why do U.S. firms hold so much more cash than they used to? J. Finance 64: 1985–2021, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01492.x.Search in Google Scholar
Becker, T., Biewen, E., Schultz, S., and Weisbecker, M. (2019a). Corporate balance sheets (Ustan) 1987–2017. Data report 2019-08 – metadata version 3. Deutsche Bundesbank Research Data and Service Centre, Frankfurt.Search in Google Scholar
Becker, T., Biewen, E., Schultz, S., and Weisbecker, M. (2019b). Individual financial statements of non-financial firms (JANIS) 1997–2017. Data report 2019-10 – metadata version 2. Deutsche Bundesbank Research Data and Service Centre, Frankfurt.Search in Google Scholar
Behringer, J., and van Treeck, T. (2019). The corporate sector and the current account. IMK Working Paper 196-2019. IMK at the Hans Boeckler Foundation. Macroeconomic Policy Institute, Düsseldorf.Search in Google Scholar
Bertrand, M., Duflo, E., and Mullainathan, S. (2004). How much should we trust differences-in-differences estimates? Q. J. Econ. 119: 249–275, https://doi.org/10.1162/003355304772839588.Search in Google Scholar
Blundell, R. and Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. J. Econom. 87: 115–143, https://doi.org/10.1016/s0304-4076(98)00009-8.Search in Google Scholar
Booth, L.D. (1981). Market structure uncertainty and the cost of equity capital. J. Bank. Finance 5: 467–482, https://doi.org/10.1016/s0378-4266(81)80002-7.Search in Google Scholar
Chen, P., Karabarbounis, L., and Neiman, B. (2017). The global rise of corporate saving. J. Monetary Econ. 89: 1–19, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2017.03.004.Search in Google Scholar
Collard-Wexler, A., and Loecker, J.D. (2016). Production function estimation with measurement error in inputs. NBER Working Papers 22437. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, Cambridge, Massachusetts.10.3386/w22437Search in Google Scholar
Crouzet, N., and Eberly, J.C. (2019). Understanding weak capital investment: the role of market concentration and intangibles. In: NBER Working Papers, 25869. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, Cambridge, Massachusetts.10.3386/w25869Search in Google Scholar
Dao, M.C. (2020). Wealth inequality and private savings: the case of Germany. IMF Working Papers 20/107. International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.10.5089/9781513546063.001Search in Google Scholar
Dao, M.C. and Maggi, C. (2018). The rise in corporate saving and cash holding in advanced economies: aggregate and firm level trends. IMF Working Papers 18/262. International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.10.2139/ssrn.3333720Search in Google Scholar
DeAngelo, H. and Masulis, R.W. (1980). Optimal capital structure under corporate and personal taxation. J. Financ. Econ. 8: 3–29, https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405x(80)90019-7.Search in Google Scholar
Desai, M.A. and Dharmapala, D. (2009). Corporate tax avoidance and firm value. Rev. Econ. Stat. 91: 537–546, https://doi.org/10.1162/rest.91.3.537.Search in Google Scholar
Desai, M.A., Foley, C.F., and Hines, J.R. (2004). A multinational perspective on capital structure choice and internal capital markets. J. Finance 59: 2451–2487, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2004.00706.x.Search in Google Scholar
Deutsche Bundesbank. (2013). Capital base of non-financial enterprises in Germany sustainably strengthened. In: Monthly report – December 2013. Deutsche Bundesbank, pp. 44–46.Search in Google Scholar
Deutsche Bundesbank. (2018a). German enterprises’ profitability and financing in 2017. In: Monthly report – December 2018. Deutsche Bundesbank, Frankfurt, pp. 33–46.Search in Google Scholar
Deutsche Bundesbank. (2018b). The savings of non-financial corporations in Germany. In: Monthly report – March 2018. Deutsche Bundesbank, Frankfurt, pp. 61–73.Search in Google Scholar
Deutsche Bundesbank. (2018c). Trends in the financing structures of German non-financial corporations as reflected in the corporate financial statements statistics. In: Monthly report – July 2018. Deutsche Bundesbank, Frankfurt, pp. 57–67.Search in Google Scholar
Deutsche Bundesbank. (2019a). On the corporate payout ratio in Germany. In: Monthly report – March 2019. Deutsche Bundesbank, Frankfurt, pp. 24–27.Search in Google Scholar
Deutsche Bundesbank. (2019b). The evolution of German enterprises’ equity ratio. In: Monthly report – December 2019. Deutsche Bundesbank, Frankfurt, pp. 44–46.Search in Google Scholar
Edmans, A., Li, L., and Zhang, C. (2014). Employee satisfaction, labor market flexibility, and stock returns around the world. NBER Working Papers 20300. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc., Washington, D.C.10.3386/w20300Search in Google Scholar
Elsas, R. and Florysiak, D. (2015). Dynamic capital structure adjustment and the impact of fractional dependent variables. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 50: 1105–1133, https://doi.org/10.1017/s0022109015000496.Search in Google Scholar
Eslava, M., Haltiwanger, J., Kugler, A., and Kugler, M. (2004). The effects of structural reforms on productivity and profitability enhancing reallocation: evidence from Colombia. J. Dev. Econ. 75: 333–371, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2004.06.002.Search in Google Scholar
Faccio, M. and Xu, J. (2015). Taxes and capital structure. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 50: 277–300, https://doi.org/10.1017/s0022109015000174.Search in Google Scholar
Falato, A., Kadyrzhanova, D., and Sim, J.W. (2013). Rising intangible capital, shrinking debt capacity, and the US corporate savings glut. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2013-67. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, U.S.10.2139/ssrn.2350863Search in Google Scholar
Flannery, M.J. and Rangan, K.P. (2006). Partial adjustment toward target capital structures. J. Financ. Econ. 79: 469–506, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2005.03.004.Search in Google Scholar
Fresard, L. (2010). Financial strength and product market behavior: the real effects of corporate cash holdings. J. Finance 65: 1097–1122, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2010.01562.x.Search in Google Scholar
Fritz Foley, C., Hartzell, J.C., Titman, S., and Twite, G. (2007). Why do firms hold so much cash? A tax-based explanation. J. Financ. Econ. 86: 579–607, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2006.11.006.Search in Google Scholar
Fuest, C., Hugger, F., and Wildgruber, S. (2020). Why is corporate tax revenue stable while tax rates fall? Evidence from firm-level data. In: CESifo Working Paper Series 8605. CESifo, Munich.10.2139/ssrn.3707945Search in Google Scholar
Gandhi, A., Navarro, S., and Rivers, D. (2020). On the identification of gross output production functions. J. Polit. Econ. 128: 2973–3016.10.1086/707736Search in Google Scholar
German Council of Economic Experts. (2014). More confidence in market processes. Annual Report 2014/2015, Wiesbaden.Search in Google Scholar
Givoly, D.E.A. (1992). Taxes and capital structure: evidence from firms’ response to the tax reform act of 1986. Rev. Financ. Stud. 5: 331–355, https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/5.2.331.Search in Google Scholar
Graham, J.R. (1999). Do personal taxes affect corporate financing decisions? J. Publ. Econ. 73: 147–185, https://doi.org/10.1016/s0047-2727(99)00006-7.Search in Google Scholar
Graham, J.R. and Tucker, A.L. (2006). Tax shelters and corporate debt policy. J. Financ. Econ. 81: 563–594, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2005.09.002.Search in Google Scholar
Gruber, J.W. and Kamin, S.B. (2016). The corporate saving glut and falloff of investment spending in OECD economies. IMF Econ. Rev. 64: 777–799, https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-016-0018-9.Search in Google Scholar
Gutiérrez, G., and Philippon, T. (2017). Declining competition and investment in the U.S. NBER Working Papers 23583. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, Washington, D.C.10.3386/w23583Search in Google Scholar
Hahn, J., Hausman, J., and Kuersteiner, G. (2007). Long difference instrumental variables estimation for dynamic panel models with fixed effects. J. Econom. 140: 574–617, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2006.07.005.Search in Google Scholar
Hainmueller, J. (2012). Entropy balancing for causal effects: a multivariate reweighting method to produce balanced samples in observational studies. Polit. Anal. 20: 25–46, https://doi.org/10.1093/pan/mpr025.Search in Google Scholar
Hall, R.E. (1988). The relation between price and marginal cost in U.S. industry. J. Polit. Econ. 96: 921–947, https://doi.org/10.1086/261570.Search in Google Scholar
IMF (2006). Awash with cash: why are corporate savings so high? World economic outlook. International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.Search in Google Scholar
IMF (2017). IMF country report, Germany: selected issues no. 14/217. International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.Search in Google Scholar
Jüppner, M., and Nagengast, A. (2018). The decline in the aggregate payout ratio of the non-financial corporate sector in Germany: evidence from two firm-level data sets. Internal note. Deutsche Bundesbank, Frankfurt.Search in Google Scholar
Jüppner, M., and Nagengast, A. (2019). On the rise in equity rations of German non-financial firms. Internal note. Deutsche Bundesbank, Frankfurt.Search in Google Scholar
Kaserer, C., Rapp, M.S., and Trinchera, O. (2012). Payout policy, taxes, and corporate insiders: evidence from the German Tax Reduction Act 2001. Z. für Betriebswirtschaft 82: 85–114, https://doi.org/10.1007/s11573-012-0596-6.Search in Google Scholar
Klug, T., Mayer, E., and Schuler, T. (2018). The corporate saving glut and the current account in Germany. In: ifo Working Paper Series 280. ifo. Institute – Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of, Munich, Munich.Search in Google Scholar
Lemmon, M.L., Roberts, M.R., and Zender, J.F. (2008). Back to the beginning: persistence and the cross-section of corporate capital structure. J. Finance 63: 1575–1608, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2008.01369.x.Search in Google Scholar
Loecker, J.D. and Warzynski, F. (2012). Markups and firm-level export status. Am. Econ. Rev. 102: 2437–2471, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.102.6.2437.Search in Google Scholar
Loeys, J., Mackie, D., Meggyesi, P., and Panigirtzoglou, N. (2005). Corporates are Driving the Global Saving Glut. JP Morgan Research, London.Search in Google Scholar
Macnamara, P. (2019). Taxes and financial frictions: implications for corporate capital structure. J. Econ. Dynam. Contr. 101: 82–100, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2019.02.004.Search in Google Scholar
Meinen, P. (2016a). Markup responses to Chinese imports. Discussion Papers 02/2016. Deutsche Bundesbank, Frankfurt.10.2139/ssrn.2797075Search in Google Scholar
Meinen, P. (2016b). Markup responses to Chinese imports. Econ. Lett. 141: 122–124, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2016.02.004.Search in Google Scholar
Miller, M.H. (1977). Debt and taxes. J. Finance 32: 261–275, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1977.tb03267.x.Search in Google Scholar
Modigliani, F. and Miller, M.H. (1963). Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a correction. Am. Econ. Rev. 53: 433–443.Search in Google Scholar
OECD. (2007). OECD economic outlook, volume 2007 issue 2. OECD Publishing, Paris.Search in Google Scholar
OECD. (2010). OECD economic surveys: Germany 2010. OECD Publishing, Paris.10.1787/eco_surveys-deu-2010-enSearch in Google Scholar
Poterba, J.M. (1987). Tax policy and corporate saving. Brookings Pap. Econ. Activ. 18: 455–516, https://doi.org/10.2307/2534488.Search in Google Scholar
Projektgruppe Gemeinschaftsdiagnose. (2017). Gemeinschaftsdiagnose Herbst 2017: Aufschwung weiter kräftig – Anspannungen nehmen zu. Berlin.Search in Google Scholar
Riddick, L.A. and Whited, T.M. (2009). The corporate propensity to save. J. Finance 64: 1729–1766, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01478.x.Search in Google Scholar
Rinne, U. and Schneider, H. (2017). The labor market in Germany, 2000–2016. IZA World Labor 2017: 379, https://doi.org/10.15185/izawol.379.Search in Google Scholar
Saibene, G. (2019). The corporate saving glut. J. Macroecon. 62: art no.103076, doi:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2018.11.004.Search in Google Scholar
Schratzenstaller, M. (2001). Die Unternehmenssteuerreform 2001. Wirtschaftsdienst 79: 611–618.Search in Google Scholar
Sullivan, T.G. (1978). The cost of capital and the market power of firms. Rev. Econ. Stat. 60: 209–217, https://doi.org/10.2307/1924974.Search in Google Scholar
Valta, P. (2012). Competition and the cost of debt. J. Financ. Econ. 105: 661–682, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2012.04.004.Search in Google Scholar
Article Note
This article is part of the special issue “Market Power and Concentration and Developments: Evidence and Implications for Germany and Europe” published in the Journal of Economics and Statistics. Access to further articles of this special issue can be obtained at www.degruyter.com/journals/jbnst.
© 2021 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Editorial
- Market Power and Concentration Developments: Evidence and Implications for Germany and Europe
- Special Issue Articles
- The Fall and Rise of Market Power in Europe
- Industry Concentration and Profitability in Europe: The Case of Norway
- Digitalization, Industry Concentration, and Productivity in Germany
- Markups and Concentration in the Context of Digitization: Evidence from German Manufacturing Industries
- Markups for Consumers
- Determinants of Corporate Savings in Germany
- Data Observer
- The Top 100 Companies Panel Database
- Business Concentration Data for Germany
- Miscellaneous
- Annual Reviewer Acknowledgement
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Editorial
- Market Power and Concentration Developments: Evidence and Implications for Germany and Europe
- Special Issue Articles
- The Fall and Rise of Market Power in Europe
- Industry Concentration and Profitability in Europe: The Case of Norway
- Digitalization, Industry Concentration, and Productivity in Germany
- Markups and Concentration in the Context of Digitization: Evidence from German Manufacturing Industries
- Markups for Consumers
- Determinants of Corporate Savings in Germany
- Data Observer
- The Top 100 Companies Panel Database
- Business Concentration Data for Germany
- Miscellaneous
- Annual Reviewer Acknowledgement