Startseite Measuring Historical Inequality in Germany
Artikel Open Access

Measuring Historical Inequality in Germany

  • Thilo Albers ORCID logo , Charlotte Bartels ORCID logo EMAIL logo und Felix Schaff
Veröffentlicht/Copyright: 16. September 2024

Abstract

This article surveys the measurement of historical wealth and income inequality in Germany. We discuss the underlying data sources, the challenges they pose, and the opportunities they create. We also identify two promising avenues for future research. First, we argue that the geographic granularity of German historical statistics provides researchers with the opportunity to investigate the causes of inequality. Second, several dimensions of historical inequality remain under-explored, for example, the equalizing role of welfare state institutions such as public pensions.

JEL Classification: D63; N13; N14

1 Introduction

It is no coincidence that Kuznets (1955) employed Prussian income tax data to provide evidence for what came to be known as the Kuznets curve. First, German tax data were frequently used in the international debate on the distribution of income and wealth because of their wide territorial and temporal coverage (see e.g. Procopovitch 1926; Sweezy 1939). Second, Prussian tax data were recorded in a particularly granular way, allowing the more polarized urban distributions to be contrasted with the rural data. The upward slope of the Kuznets curve originates in this difference. While the new wave of inequality research since the early 2000s (Atkinson and Piketty 2007; Piketty 2014) has moved beyond the static concepts underlying the Kuznets curve, historical data on inequality remain relevant. How have more recent debates led to the creation of knowledge about historical inequality in Germany? Do German data continue to inform the international debate as they did in Kuznets’ era? What are the challenges for estimating historical inequality levels and how have they been overcome? What are avenues for future research?

In this article, we confront these questions by reviewing the measurement of historical wealth and income inequality in Germany. In particular, we argue that the new wave of inequality research has inspired new estimates for income and wealth inequality for the period since 1850 that are consistent both across time and with established international standards for cross-country comparisons. In addition, the new interest in inequality has led to methodological innovations such as creating synthetic distributions that allow us to approximate the evolution of national inequality going back as far as the Black Death in the 14th century. Studies on Germany have also informed the international debate by adding a country particularly exposed to the shocks of the 20th century, furthering our knowledge of the drivers of wealth and income inequality.

The contribution of studies using German data goes beyond national series on the concentration of wealth and income. Both for the pre-industrial period and thereafter, new studies exploit the spatial variation recorded in the statistics covering German states, districts, cities, counties, and at times individuals. We posit that much potential for future research lies in continuing to exploit sub-national variation to identify the causes and consequences of inequality. Furthermore, social tables and earnings inequality data can complement recent work on top income and wealth shares by dealing with two of its limitations: the focus on the right tail of the distribution and the ignorance of socio-demographic dimensions such as gender and age.

The remainder of the article is structured as follows. Section 2 provides an overview of existing and past estimates, thereby characterizing the process of knowledge production concerning inequality. Section 3 discusses the measurement of pre-industrial inequality, while Section 4 turns to the top income and wealth share series that are based on modern federal income and wealth tax statistics. Section 5 briefly introduces research on earnings inequality and social tables, which complement traditional wealth and income inequality series.

2 Knowledge Production in Past and Present

To set the scene for our in-depth discussion of the existing evidence, it is useful to portray the evolution of inequality and, with it, to illustrate the knowledge production in the past. The two panels of Figure 1 provide a non-exhaustive overview of existing estimates for the share of aggregate wealth and income held by the top percentile. The solid lines provide the most recent and most reliable national-level estimates for the respective periods. Taken together, the evolution of wealth and income inequality suggests that modern economic growth increased inequality towards the end of the 19th century relative to the pre-industrial period, that the shocks between 1914 and 1950 reduced inequality, and that over the past 20 years there has been a moderate increase in income and wealth concentration.

Figure 1: 
Estimates of economic inequality in Germany, c. 1600–2018. The wealth estimate from Biedermann (1918) is for the top 1.1 %. The income estimate from Helfferich (1914) is for the top 1.6 % (1896) and 1.2 % (1912). Sweezy (1939) estimates the Pareto-α for income and wealth distributions. The displayed values are the implied top shares (see Jones 2015, for the relationship between top shares and the Pareto α). The wealth estimates by Alfani, Gierok, and Schaff (2022) also cover the period 1,400–1,600, for which the level of the top 1 % share and the flat trend are comparable to the period 1,600–1,800. (a) Wealth share of the top 1 %. (b) Income share of the top 1 %.
Figure 1:

Estimates of economic inequality in Germany, c. 1600–2018. The wealth estimate from Biedermann (1918) is for the top 1.1 %. The income estimate from Helfferich (1914) is for the top 1.6 % (1896) and 1.2 % (1912). Sweezy (1939) estimates the Pareto-α for income and wealth distributions. The displayed values are the implied top shares (see Jones 2015, for the relationship between top shares and the Pareto α). The wealth estimates by Alfani, Gierok, and Schaff (2022) also cover the period 1,400–1,600, for which the level of the top 1 % share and the flat trend are comparable to the period 1,600–1,800. (a) Wealth share of the top 1 %. (b) Income share of the top 1 %.

Since the estimates are ordered by publication date in the respective legends, Figure 1 also provides a short history of knowledge production. The earliest distributional estimates that come close to top shares date back to the eve of World War I (WWI). Members of the historical school such as Wagner and Sombart had developed a strong interest in inequality, but failed to adopt a consistent measure that allows us to pin down whether inequality was increasing or decreasing (Dumke 1987). This is particularly unfortunate, because Lorenz (1905, incidentally using, among others, Prussian data) had developed the eponymous curve (Dumke 1987). These problems notwithstanding, the publications by Helfferich (1914) and Biedermann (1918) implicitly contain top shares by tabulating both the wealth and income of certain groups along with the corresponding aggregates. Stemming from a banker and Prussian bureaucrat, respectively, they also reflect that income and wealth inequality were not only important to academic debates but also for the wider public.

In the interwar period, Procopovitch (1926) and Sweezy (1939) provided new estimates, now closer to the top share concept, but still different from today‘s measurement standards. Their studies reflect a sustained interest in distributional issues and the role of the government in affecting it. Immediately after the war, Krelle, Schunck, and Siebke (1968) compared the wealth distribution before and after World War II (WWII). At this point, too, the first studies without an explicit link to the then present were published (e.g. Müller and Geisenberger 1972, on income inequality in German states before WWI). Except for a PhD thesis of exceptionally high quality covering wealth inequality between 1935 and 1980 (Baron 1988), the production of national top share estimates came virtually to a halt in the mid-1970s (like elsewhere, see Römer 2023). Only with the latest wave of international inequality research since the early 2000s, has there been a renewed effort to reconstruct long-term time series for Germany’s personal income and wealth distributions (Albers, Bartels, and Schularick 2022; Alfani, Gierok, and Schaff 2022; Bartels 2019).

In sum, knowledge production appears to reflect the level and evolution of inequality itself: it is high when levels of inequality are either high or increasing and tends to be low when the inequality is low. To be clear, knowledge creation with respect to inequality has not been limited to the distributional data surveyed in this paper. Alternative approaches are particularly useful complements to the period before 1850, where availability of data required to calculate personal income distribution is limited (Albers and Bartels 2023).[1]

3 Wealth Inequality, 1300–1800

In the 1800s, many of the German state governments introduced state-wide taxes on their citizens’ property and income.[2] This facilitates the estimation of distributions at the state level and, by combining the data for multiple states, at the federal level. In contrast, taxes were levied mostly at the village or town level up until the early 19th century. This creates both challenges and opportunities. On the one hand, not all localities in a unit of interest might be covered and the taxation rules might differ across jurisdictions. This complicates the estimation of national- and state-level distributions. On the other hand, the data are usually even more granular than those for larger territories in the 19th and 20th centuries. This allows scholars to ask a different set of questions. Below, we first discuss the nature of the existing data and highlight three applications exploiting the granularity of pre-industrial wealth data.

Levying taxes at the town- and village-level rather than the state-level was the result of local authorities usually being more important than central authorities in matters of commerce, work, and life in general, at a time when modern nation states did not yet exist, and transport networks were poorly developed (Schmoller 1896). These local taxes – called for example Beede, Geschoss, Schatzung or Ordinari Steuer – were property taxes, conceptually similar to modern wealth taxes, levied at the household level. The tax base was broad, usually including immobile (e.g. land, houses) and mobile assets (e.g. animals, grain stocks, cash money, household goods), sometimes elements of income, but everywhere the main asset class was real estate. Unfortunately, the tax registers usually indicate total taxable wealth only, but do not distinguish between classes of assets. Taxes had to be paid by the entirety of civilian households,[3] such as craftsmen, peasants, and merchants, as well as very poor and very rich households (Alfani, Gierok, and Schaff 2022). The coverage of (almost) every household implies a convenient feature: we can model the ‘real’ distribution from the tax registers, without having to make assumptions about the likely functional shape of the distribution (e.g. log-normal), a challenge scholars of later eras often face. However, these data only make it possible to analyse inequality among households. It is not possible to estimate inequality among individuals in the pre-industrial period, because tax registers did not make inquiries about the number or wealth of individual household members.[4] Locating sources, collecting them from local archives, transcribing them, elaborating, and analysing the data is time-consuming and requires ‘historian’s skills’ as much as the economist’s toolbox. The resulting household-level wealth tax datasets have been used for the study of inequality at three aggregation levels:[5] the ‘national’-, the town- and village-level, and the individual-level. Several of these datasets are publicly available (see below).

A first use is the calculation of aggregate measures, to identify broad inequality trends (Alfani, Gierok, and Schaff 2022).[6] This has been achieved by modelling “national” wealth distributions (in steps of 50 years), based on data from a sample of towns and villages, and weighting these local data by some basic population statistics. Conceptually, this procedure is similar to the ‘Global Weighted Inequality’ approach of Milanovic (2005). The constructed wealth distributions have been used to calculate several inequality measures, such as the wealth percentiles of the entire distribution, but also Gini coefficients and measures of relative and absolute poverty. One major insight from this line of research is that Germany followed a secular trend of growth in inequality between the 14th and 19th centuries. For example, between 1,400 and 1,600 the Gini coefficient grew from 0.559 to 0.675 points. This trend was interrupted by two major catastrophes, the Black Death epidemic (1348) epidemic and the Thirty Years’s War (1618–48), both leading to a reduction of circa 0.1 Gini points. The second shock distinguished Germany from all other European areas for which comparable data are available. In 1800, inequality was again at a relatively high level of 0.617 Gini points. Another insight from this line of research is that several indicators of relative and absolute poverty (e.g. wealth percentiles of poor strata, poverty gap, share of propertyless households) mirrored trends in inequality. Poverty peaked around the year 1600, when almost a quarter of the German population was poor, and the poorest 20 percent of the population owned only about 0.4 percent of total property (Alfani, Gierok, and Schaff 2024). Moreover, inequality in relation to the overall prosperity (or poverty) of the economy, measured with the ‘inequality extraction ratio’ (Milanovic, Lindert, and Williamson 2011), grew more intensely in 16th-century Germany than in any other area of pre-industrial Europe (Alfani, Gierok, and Schaff 2024).

Interestingly, as can be seen in Figure 1, different measures of inequality, such as the top 1 % wealth share, can reveal substantially different patterns of inequality.[7] This raises the broader question of why inequality measured with top wealth shares was modest in pre-industrial compared to industrial times, although one may intuitively think of pre-industrial society as one where wealth was highly concentrated. It is unlikely that this seeming contradiction is a data issue. The main reason is presumably that the economic structure of the pre-industrial economy set a limit to accumulation: in pre-industrial times the most important production factor was land, which cannot be accumulated as easily as industrial capital.[8] Additionally, pre-industrial society was on average relatively poor, as measures such as per capita GDP indicate (see Pfister 2022). In a poor society, the amount of resources that can be concentrated at the top of the distribution is limited (Milanovic, Lindert, and Williamson 2011). Lastly, as mentioned, higher-level nobles were considered public authorities at the time; their riches were therefore exempt from taxation, just like states’ assets are today.

A second use of the local tax data is to calculate measures at the town- and village-level. This approach has been pursued for a long time by quantitative historians, beginning with the German Historical School (see Bátori and Weyrauch 1982; Sabean 1990; Schmoller 1895). For example, for the merchant city of Augsburg in 1,600, the estimated Gini coefficient is 0.85 (Alfani, Gierok, and Schaff 2022, 103). Another use of these community-level data is to exploit local variation in the analysis of the drivers of long-run inequality trends, to address the question of why wealth inequality was already high before industrialisation and modern economic growth began in Germany. So, the same local data have been used to construct town- and village-level panel data (25-year steps) of different inequality measures.[9] Previous scholarship has made important hypotheses about the causes of inequality, but empirically these were often based on data from few or even single communities (see Pfister 2020; Scheidel 2017; van Zanden 1995). Larger, more systematic, recent datasets have led to several new insights, about the inequality-promoting effect of pre-industrial warfare, closed political institutions, the Protestant Reformation, and differences in inheritance institutions (Ogilvie and Schaff 2024; Schaff 2023, 2024a, 2024b; Wegge 2021).

A third use of local wealth data is linking individual taxpayers over time, where exceptionally orderly, homogeneous and well-preserved tax sources make this possible for single communities. This has been done in one recent study investigating the individual-level drivers of wealth and inequality (see Schaff 2024b).[10] The study combines c. 27,000 observations of personal wealth with information about who was part of the city government and administration, in the oligarchically-governed south-German city-state of Nördlingen in the 17th century. The study finds that in this high-inequality context, government members were typically among the richest 20 % of the population before entering office, and about a fifth of all governors ‘inherited’ their privileged position from a close relative. But these well-off individuals enriched themselves even further after entering office, by up to 90 %, climbing up between three to four wealth percentiles.

In sum, recent research has advanced considerably our knowledge about wealth inequality in Germany between the Black Death and the 19th century. Inequality ebbed and flowed substantially according to several inequality measures (e.g. Gini coefficient, wealth shares of poor strata, inequality extraction ratio), but was rather flat in terms of top wealth shares (Figure 1). Several political economy forces, such as warfare, governmental and inheritance institutions, and differences in religious confession can explain a substantial part of the local variation in inequality, at a time when factors like modern economic growth or industrialization were much less important than in later periods. We further discuss these modern forces in the following sections.

4 Income and Wealth Concentration Since 1850

Over the course of the 19th century, German states successively introduced modern income and wealth tax systems, in which the level of taxation depended on the income or wealth of the household or individual. For example, the Prussian income tax law of 1891 recorded annual incomes of more than 10 % of Prussian households (or even 30 % in rich industrial districts like Düsseldorf) (Bartels et al. 2023). These new data sources make it possible to quantify the degree of wealth and income concentration at the national level more precisely than for previous periods. In consequence, the main focus of recent research has been to produce long-run series on top shares. Long-run series for top incomes in Germany, 1871–2014, have been produced by Bartels (2019) and long-run series for wealth and its distribution in Germany, 1895–2018, by Albers, Bartels, and Schularick (2022).[11]

Once the first states introduced income taxes, a lively theoretical discussion about what to count as income emerged (see, e.g. Fuisting 1907; Giloy 1978; Schanz 1896). The Prussian income tax law of 1891 closely followed the theory of source (Quellentheorie), counting only regular incomes from labour, capital or real estate as income and, thus, excluding capital gains from income taxation. Over time, the more encompassing definition of income became popular: the so-called Reinvermögenszugangstheorie counted any income that changed net wealth, i.e. changed consumption possibilities. This income definition theory was defended by Schanz (1896) in Prussia at the turn of the century and is known today as Haig-Simons income (Haig 1921; Simons 1938). The first Germany-wide income tax introduced in 1920 also included some forms of capital gains, which may represent sizable income flows, particularly for top income earners.

The newly founded statistical offices of the German states started to publish regularly grouped income and wealth tax statistics. Being based on state-wide taxes, these grouped statistics became the main data source to construct time series of income and wealth concentration within states like Prussia or Saxony. These statistics provide the number of taxpayers between two thresholds and their respective total income or wealth. As the population share of the number of taxpayers above a threshold mostly does not coincide with the top income group that we are interested in, such as the top 1 %, thresholds and averages are estimated using the Pareto interpolation method. This method, which we sketch in the following section, is now commonly used in the top income and wealth share literature following the seminal contributions of Piketty (2003) and Piketty and Saez (2003).

The main challenges for researchers estimating income and wealth concentration based on tax statistics are to understand and address the following questions: What types of income or wealth are included in the tax statistics, and which are excluded? For example, is it possible to remove capital gains to ensure intertemporal comparability? What types of tax units are included, and which are tax-exempt? Is the tax unit a household or an individual, and what is the measure of the total potential number of tax units? We will discuss some of the challenges below, with more detailed discussions of the data landscape.

4.1 Measuring Income and Wealth Concentration

Wealth concentration is measured analogously to income concentration. For the sake of readability, we will refer to income in the following, which could easily be replaced by wealth. To obtain income shares (or wealth shares) from grouped tax statistics, it is assumed that top incomes y (or top wealth) above the Pareto threshold k follow the Pareto distribution F(y) = 1 − (y/k)b/(b−1) ∀yk where the Pareto parameter b is obtained by dividing the average income above a certain income threshold documented in the tax statistics by the respective income threshold. Empirically, b varies slightly across the top fractiles, so that different Pareto parameters are obtained for different fractiles. Using the estimated b, we can compute the income threshold of the top x percent. The income share s x of the top x percent is then obtained by dividing the cumulative income above the income threshold t x by an external reference total income Y (see paragraph on Reference income below) as follows:

(1) s x = b x t x i x / Y

where i x is the top x% expressed in terms of total tax units.

For applied researchers, the generalized Pareto interpolation method developed by Blanchet, Fournier, and Piketty (2022) is of great value. It draws on average income or wealth and the respective threshold for a number of fractiles to estimate shares and the Gini coefficient. The authors provide an online version of the gpinter tool via https://wid.world/gpinter and a plugin for the software R that converts Excel input into the measures of interest.[12]

The main difference between measuring the concentration of flows (income) and stocks (wealth) is that assessing the value of stocks is notoriously difficult. Harmonizing the valuation of assets is one of the main challenges facing wealth inequality researchers as, for example, tax-assessed values might differ substantially from market values. As Albers, Bartels, and Schularick (2022) demonstrate, consistently applying market prices to both distributional data and wealth aggregates has important implications for levels and changes in long-run top 1 % wealth share series.

4.2 Historical Data on Income and its Distribution

4.2.1 Income Tax Statistics

As noted above, income tax statistics are used as the main data source to estimate income concentration. Incomes recorded in tax statistics included wages, business income, and capital income, but again, as noted, excluded most sorts of capital gains. German states successively introduced a modern income tax system: in 1869 in Hesse, in 1874 in Bremen, in 1874 in Saxony, in 1881 in Hamburg, in 1884 in Baden, in 1891 in Prussia, in 1905 in Württemberg, and in 1912 in Bavaria. At the same time, the statistical offices of these states began publishing tabulations showing the number of taxpayers per income bracket and aggregated taxable income per income bracket. In total, 27 income tax systems were introduced in the 39 German states, but only the aforementioned states regularly published tax statistics. Bartels (2019) and Bartels and Bönke (2015) list all publications of the German and state statistical offices including grouped income tax statistics.

4.2.2 Reference Income

(Denoted by y in Equation (1)) is the crucial additional input next to total reference population.[13] There are two approaches to derive the total reference income. The bottom-up approach adds the (estimated) income of the tax-exempt to the taxpayers’ income. Bartels (2019) adopts the bottom-up approach for the period 1871–1918. National accounts were not then available and income tax laws varied across German states. Hoffmann and Müller (1959) estimate a consistent series of non-filers’ income in German states. The top-down approach draws on national accounts data and applies a fixed share to arrive at private household income. National accounts provide a useful benchmark both regarding consistency over time and comparability across countries through the United Nations’ System of National Accounts (SNA), first charted in 1947, and the European System of Accounts (ESA), which is a modification of the SNA. Bach, Corneo, and Steiner (2009) estimate that gross market household income of both filers and non-filers is between 80.9 % and 84.4 % of the national accounts’ household income. Bartels (2019) adopts the top-down approach from 1925 onwards, using a ratio of 90 % throughout.

4.2.3 Regional Income Concentration Data

As discussed in Section 3 for the period 1,300 to 1,850, regional variation can help uncover the causes and consequences of income concentration. For example, the comparison of income concentration in German states in Albers and Bartels (2021, 2023 reveals systematically higher income concentration in independent cities like Bremen and Hamburg than in states with large rural areas. Further, more industrial states like Prussia or Saxony show higher levels of concentration than more agricultural states like Baden or Hesse. In some states and years and until today, grouped income tax statistics are also published by district (Regierungsbezirk), by county (Kreis), and by urban and rural regions, so that regional top shares can be estimated, also drawing on the ‘Global Weighted Inequality’ approach of Milanovic (2005). For example, Bartels et al. (2023) show that changes in capital accumulation led to a rise in the capital share and income inequality in Prussian regions, as predicted by orthodox Marxists.[14] But trade unions and strike activity limited income inequality and fostered political support for socialism, as argued by their critics, the so-called Revisionists. Bartels, Jäger, and Obergruber (2024) show that the equal division of inherited land among siblings in some regions during Germany’s industrialization led to higher average incomes, more entrepreneurship and higher income concentration today. Given the relevance of the income distribution in many fields (from political economy to growth theory), we see substantial potential for future research in studying local and regional inequality developments together with the respective outcomes of interest.

4.3 Historical Data on Wealth and its Distribution

As for measuring income inequality, the measurement of wealth inequality based on historical tax statistics and modern survey data poses a set of challenges. First, tax-assessed values do not necessarily reflect market values. To ensure the comparability of distributional estimates over time, we must apply adjustment factors that transform tax into market values. Second, the federal wealth tax was only introduced in the interwar period and was phased out in the 1990s. For the periods before and after, we need to employ alternative data sources, including historical wealth taxes at the regional level and modern survey data. Third, wealth taxes only capture the very top of the distribution, making it necessary to estimate total wealth. In the following, we discuss how the existing research overcomes these challenges and the quality of the source material. We also discuss avenues to further develop the historical measurement.

4.3.1 The Definition and Valuation of Wealth

Estimating wealth levels and distributions over time requires a consistent definition of what personal net wealth constitutes and at which prices it is assessed. Thanks to the renewed interest in comparative work on wealth inequality, there is an established effort to follow – as close as sources permit – the following definition: Net private wealth is defined as the total value of marketable assets excluding consumer durables at market prices less the nominal debt (see e.g. Piketty and Zucman 2014). How well are the two elements in italics reflected in the German sources and how do existing estimates adjust for potential inconsistencies?

The internationally popular definition for marketable wealth squares remarkably well with the historical source material for Germany. The underlying reason is that Prussia – Germany’s largest state at the time housing 62 % of the German population and 57 % of German net private wealth in 1913 (Albers, Bartels, and Schularick 2022, Appendix p. 20) – introduced a wealth tax largely consistent with the above definition as early as 1893 (Preussischer Staat 1893). It classified assets into four categories (agricultural, real estate, business, and financial) and explicitly excluded consumer durables and public pensions claims. Presumably, because Prussia was the largest and the first state to introduce a wealth tax, most state governments adopted the Prussian definitions when introducing their own wealth tax (Statistisches Reichsamt 1927). When the tax system was eventually federalised, the Prussian definitions were largely adopted and refined. For the post-wealth tax period since the 1990s, wealth survey data is more refined and consistent with the above definition of marketable assets (Albers, Bartels, and Schularick 2022).

A consistent valuation of private wealth at market prices requires adjustments of the raw wealth tax data. In the pre-WWI period, the assessment rules were new and quite complex (see the tax assessor handbook by Buck 1914). Based on contemporary sources, Albers, Bartels, and Schularick (2022) adjust all asset values by 10 % to account for the under-reporting of market values. For the interwar period until 1990, Albers, Bartels, and Schularick (2022) develop asset-specific adjustment indices that convert tax into market values.[15] Finally, Albers, Bartels, and Schularick (2022) correct for the undervaluation of non-listed businesses – an important part of the German industrial capital stock – and real estate in the official balance sheets for the period since 1993 (using the methods by Davis and Heathcote 2007; Ogden, Thomas, and Warusawitharana 2016, respectively).

In sum, German tax sources accord well with the definition of wealth in terms of the included items. However, major adjustments are needed when calculating the market value rather than the tax value of assets. Albers, Bartels, and Schularick (2022) provide corresponding adjustment indices that can be applied when using German historical post-WWI wealth data.[16]

4.3.2 Distributional Data

Estimating the historical concentration of wealth requires data on its distribution among the rich. There are four potential source types that require different methodological approaches: estate taxes, wealth taxes and wealth levies, the combination of survey data and rich lists, and capitalised capital returns from the income tax statistics. While the German inheritance tax statistics are not very suitable to infer the distribution among the living from the wealth distribution of the dead,[17] the other three source types are sufficient to provide distributional estimates for the period 1895–2021.

For the pre-WWI period, no regular federal wealth tax was levied. However, the federal government did levy a one-off tax in 1913 to fund the expansion of the German army. The corresponding statistics (Statistisches Reichsamt 1919) cover close to 11 % of German households as they pertain to both those actually paying the tax and those assessed but exempted. Since Prussia was the largest state and its wealth tax similarly comprehensive (see e.g. the statistics for 1895 and 1911 published in Königliches Statistisches Bureau 1895, 1912), Albers, Bartels, and Schularick (2022) use changes in the Prussian distribution to extrapolate backwards the 1913 benchmark estimate. Future work can make use of the many state-level taxes that exist for this time (see Statistisches Reichsamt 1927, for an overview). While they are unlikely to change the picture qualitatively, they could solidify the existing evidence.

For the period 1924–1990, researchers can rely on comprehensive wealth tax tabulations of the federal wealth tax. In the 1920s, the official statistics cover 10–12 % of the population, while the corresponding values for the 1931 and 1935 edition of the wealth tax lie between 2.5 % and 2.8 %. For the post-war period, the share of assessed households varies between 1.5 % and 3 % (see the Albers, Bartels, and Schularick 2022 Online Appendix for the corresponding calculations and the bibliographical details of the primary sources). Beyond those tabulations used in the literature, we consider it likely that detailed tabulated data for the Reichsnotopfer, a one-off emergency levy after WWI, and for the 1940 wealth tax exist in the archives.[18] These could improve our understanding of the distributional consequences of WWI and the Nazi regime, respectively.

For unified Germany, no wealth tax data exist. Instead, researchers can draw on an increasing number of surveys (EVS since 1978, SOEP since 2002, HFCS since 2010) to measure the wealth distribution across the entire population in Germany. A large benefit of this type of distributional data is that it covers wider parts of the population, allowing to calculate different measures of wealth concentration than the wealth held by the top percentile or decile. A major disadvantage is that surveys miss the very rich. There are a variety of approaches to address this shortcoming (see e.g. Bartels and Metzing 2019; Bartels and Waldenström 2022; Schröder et al. 2020). Albers, Bartels, and Schularick (2022) combine data from the Manager Magazin, survey data, and leverage their aggregate wealth estimates to correct the top shares. While all such approaches and their combination are imperfect, not correcting for the effect of the missing rich in survey data is not a viable alternative. For example, the top 1 % wealth share increases by about 7 percentage points when adequately taking into account the undercoverage of the rich and their asset classes (mostly business wealth) in survey data.

In sum, the absence of a federal wealth tax before WWI and after reunification requires leveraging regional wealth taxes and combining survey data with rich lists, respectively. Tabulated regional wealth taxes as well as potentially existing detailed sources on the 1940 wealth tax and the emergency levy after WWI Reichsnotopfer are promising avenues to refine our knowledge about the national wealth distribution.

4.3.3 Data on Aggregate Wealth

Since wealth taxes typically cover only a small group at the tail of the wealth distribution, we need to estimate the total wealth in the economy to calculate top shares and other measures of inequality. Similarly to the literature on income inequality, past and current research addresses this challenge either by a ‘bottom-up’ or ‘top-down’ strategy. Following the former, the per household wealth of those not assessed for the wealth tax is estimated, multiplied by the respective number of households, and then added to the total assessed for the wealth tax. Following the latter, researchers reconstruct historical household balance sheets in the vein of Goldsmith (1985) and more recently Piketty and Zucman (2014). Both approaches are used to estimate historical wealth inequality in Germany.

For the period before WWI, there exist a considerable number of contemporary estimates,[19] among which the ‘bottom-up’ estimates by Wagner (1904), Helfferich (1914), and Biedermann (1918) are the most reliable. More recently, Piketty and Zucman (2014) provide a ‘top-down’ estimate starting in 1870 using data on the capital stock and land value from Hoffmann (1965). Their estimate shows the potential predicament of historical balance sheets; they depend on the quality of the underlying data. It is unclear how Hoffmann arrived at values for agricultural assets so incompatible with contemporary ‘bottom-up’ estimates (Albers, Bartels, and Schularick 2022, Appendix, p. 18). We therefore recommend using the Albers, Bartels, and Schularick 2022 series (starting in 1895), which is based on a ‘bottom-up’ estimate but allocates the wealth to the different asset classes (agricultural, real estate, business, and financial). In our view, future research could aim to provide an alternative ‘top-down’ estimate for the pre-WWI period. Newly available data on land incomes (Pfister 2019b) allow us to apply the capitalization method for this asset class. Others have improved Hoffmann’s estimates for the industrial capital stock (Burhop and Wolff 2005).

For the period 1924–1989, Albers, Bartels, and Schularick (2022) reconstruct historical household balance sheets. For the interwar period, these are largely based on the so-called ‘unit value statistics’ (Einheitswertstatistik) (Statistisches Reichsamt 1930, 1931, 1939). Tax assessors created these ‘unit values’ to reduce the need for multiple assessments when levying different taxes. The ambition was to cover all real estate, agricultural assets, and business assets in the country. The data, especially for the later years, are of exceptionally high quality and the publications include discussions about potential problems. The total value of the households’ financial assets can be reconstructed from combining wealth tax data with data on savings and insurances (cf Albers, Bartels, and Schularick 2022). For the post-war period, Albers, Bartels, and Schularick (2022) rely on, refine, and extend the work by Baron (1988) up to 1989. Baron’s estimates are also used by Piketty and Zucman (2014) and are of high quality. They comprise a traditional reconstruction of historical household balance sheets in that the single parts of aggregate wealth (agricultural assets, real estate, business, and financial assets) are estimated based on separate sources and then aggregated to total gross wealth. Finally, liabilities are deducted to arrive at net private wealth.

For unified Germany, the Central Bank (Bundesbank) and federal statistical office (Statistisches Bundesamt) collaborate on publishing household balance sheets (see e.g. Deutsche Bundesbank 2019). As discussed above, Albers, Bartels, and Schularick (2022) suggest a substantial upward correction of business and real estate wealth. With respect to unlisted business wealth, the Bundesbank is currently revising their official measure (Bundesbank 2022) in response to Albers, Bartels, and Schularick (2020).

4.3.4 Pension Claims and Sub-national Wealth Data

From a data perspective, there are two promising avenues to further develop our understanding of the evolution of wealth inequality. First, to assess the role of the state in moderating wealth inequality, it would be useful to include pension wealth in the historical series. Whether or not to do so is contentious in the literature. On the one hand, the future claim is not tradable and has to be estimated based on strong assumptions (Saez and Zucman 2016). On the other, public pension are known to be important outside of the Anglo-Saxon world, especially for the bottom half of the wealth distribution.[20] From this perspective, integrating public pension claims into long-run wealth inequality series would arguably increase the comparability between countries with and without public pension systems. Second, to better identify – in the strict econometric sense – the drivers of wealth inequality, future research can exploit the granularity of historical German wealth tax statistics. Depending on the period, these allow us to produce measures such as the top 1 % at the state, district, and even county level. Like the studies discussed in the income inequality section above, these can be correlated with other variables of interest at the same geographical resolution. Albers, Kersting, and Stieglitz (2023); Bartels et al. (2023); Bartels, Jäger, and Obergruber (2024) provide examples studying the relationship between growth, especially during the industrialization period, and income and wealth inequality.

5 Two Complementary Distributional Measures

We now discuss two complementary ways to measure historical inequality. Social tables combine social groups or classes of a given society with their estimated average incomes. Earnings inequality across the working population can be estimated from grouped earnings statistics, which have existed, broadly speaking, since the introduction of modern income statistics. Both approaches share a disadvantage and two advantages relative to concentration measures based on personal income distribution. On the one hand, they capture inequality imperfectly. They focus on earnings, i.e. income from labor, exclude capital incomes and, thereby, understate incomes at the top of the income distribution where households’ incomes disproportionately stem from capital rather than labour. On the other hand, both methods cover dimensions that the previously presented data do not, including inequality between gender, occupation or age. Moreover, both methods cover a much broader part of the population compared to historical tax statistics, which often cover less than 10 % of the population.

5.1 Income Inequality using Social Tables 1900–1950

Constructing social tables is probably the oldest method used to measure inequality.[21] In contrast to the previously described tax data that often only cover the richest population segments, social tables collect data on the number of people belonging to different social groups or classes and their estimated average incomes. Gómez León and De Jong (2019) follow this traditional approach and construct such social tables (ex post) for Germany and Britain. For Germany, they use information on the active population structure provided in the occupational censuses (Berufzählungen) of 1907, 1925, 1933, 1939, and 1950. The authors then compile average annual earnings linked to each profession from different sources, mostly relying on Hohls (1995). Social tables might underestimate inequality when the number of groups is small or when the members belonging to one group are assumed to share the same average income. To mitigate this bias (a small number of groups or little heterogeneity within groups), the authors aim to maximize the level of disaggregation within each occupational group, for example, by further differentiating between male and female as well as salaried personnel and wage-earners.

The heterogeneity included in social tables allows us to shed light on inequality drivers. For example, Gómez León and De Jong (2019) graphically contrast skill ratio, gender ratio, and business owner ratio in agriculture and industry with the evolution of the Gini coefficient. Future work could apply methods like reweighting or decomposition to weigh the different inequality drivers against each other.

5.2 Earnings Inequality Since ca. 1880

Three historical data sources offer information that can be used to recover the earnings distribution: (1) Workplace and Occupation Census (Berufszählung); (2) Wage and Salary Structure Survey (Gehalts- und Lohnstrukturerhebung); and (3) payroll tax statistics (Lohnsteuerstatistik).[22] Bönke, Harnack-Eber, and Penz (2024) use these grouped earnings statistics (1)–(3) and obtain a continuous marginal earnings distribution applying the generalized Pareto method (Blanchet, Fournier, and Piketty 2022). (1) The Workplace and Occupation Census was collected between 1875 and 1970 and records the number of individuals by gender, age, marital status, and occupation for the entire German population (Kleber and Willms 1982).[23] Bönke, Harnack-Eber, and Penz (2024) map mean and variance of annual pre-tax earnings from Hohls (1991) to the number of individuals by occupation recorded in the Workplace and Occupation Census. (2) The Wage and Salary Structure Survey was conducted by the federal statistical office and includes data on wages, salaries, and working hours categorized by industry, gender, and company size between 1951 and 1972. The survey represents approximately 15 % of all employees and is considered representative (Hohls 1991).[24] Bönke, Harnack-Eber, and Penz (2024) add the number of unemployed from the Workplace and Occupation Census for the years in which both data sources overlap. (3) Payroll tax statistics containing binned information on the number of taxpayers, their gross earnings, and the total tax paid became available after the payroll tax (Lohnsteuer) introduction in 1920 (Metzger and Weingarten 1989). In most years, binned tax statistics are also broken down by socio-economic characteristics such as gender, age, and occupation.

6 Conclusions

Data on the distribution of income and wealth in Germany has been at the forefront of the scientific debate about the development and the causes of inequality at least since Kuznets (1955). They have been both an input to the debate and a product of it as new methods and standards have been developed by the international research community. Thanks to these efforts, we can now characterize inequality levels in Germany from the Black Death up to today.

And yet, despite recent advances, the large potential of historical German inequality data has only been exploited to a limited extent. For the pre-industrial period, the origins of income and wealth differences between the sexes, between rural and urban places, and the role of feudalism are understudied aspects of inequality. Leveraging geographical and temporal variation means we can, in principle, analyse these in a causal manner. Likewise, the regional data for the late 19th and 20th century allow us to establish the causal effects of growth and political outcomes on inequality. In addition, descriptive work could combine state-level taxes for the 19th century, locate sources relating to the Reichsnotopfer or the 1940 wealth tax, and assess the role of welfare state institutions such as the public pension system. Finally, future work on social tables and earnings distributions could apply re-weighting and decomposition methods to further investigate the role of age, occupations or gender.


Corresponding author: Charlotte Bartels, DIW Berlin, Berlin, Germany; CEPR, London, UK; CESifo, Munich, Germany; and IZA, Bonn, Germany, E-mail: 

  1. Research ethics: Not applicable.

  2. Author contributions: The authors have accepted responsibility for the entire content of this manuscript and approved its submission.

  3. Competing interests: The authors state no competing interests.

  4. Research funding: None declared.

  5. Data availability: Not applicable.

References

Albers, T., and C. Bartels. 2021. “Phasen und Triebkräfte der Ungleichheit in Deutschland von 1840 bis 1914.” In Deutschland 1871: Die Nationalstaatsgründung und der Weg in die moderne Wirtschaft, edited by J.-O. Hesse, U. Pfister, M. Spoerer, and N. Wolf, 291–312. Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.Suche in Google Scholar

Albers, T., and C. Bartels. 2023. “Inequality and its Drivers in Germany, 1840–1914.” In Economic History of the First German Unification, edited by U. Pfister, and N. Wolf. London: Routledge.10.4324/9781003283430-17Suche in Google Scholar

Albers, T., C. Bartels, and M. Schularick. 2020. “The Distribution of Wealth in Germany, 1895–2018.” ECONtribute Policy Brief 001.Suche in Google Scholar

Albers, T., C. Bartels, and M. Schularick. 2022. “Wealth and its Distribution in Germany, 1895–2018.” CEPR Discussion Paper 17269.10.31235/osf.io/y6zpqSuche in Google Scholar

Albers, T. N., F. Kersting, and T. Stieglitz. 2023. “Industrialization, Returns, Inequality.” CRC Discussion Paper 462.Suche in Google Scholar

Alfani, G. 2023. As Gods Among Men. A History of the Rich in the West. Princeton: Princeton University Press.10.1353/book.118715Suche in Google Scholar

Alfani, G., V. Gierok, and F. Schaff. 2022. “Economic Inequality in Preindustrial Germany, Ca. 1300 – 1850.” The Journal of Economic History 82 (1): 87–125. https://doi.org/10.1017/s0022050721000607.Suche in Google Scholar

Alfani, G., V. Gierok, and F. Schaff. 2024. “Poverty in Germany from the Black Death until the Beginning of Industrialization.” Explorations in Economic History.Suche in Google Scholar

Atkinson, A. B., and T. Piketty, eds. 2007. Top Incomes over the Twentieth Century: A Contrast between Continental European and English-speaking Countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press.10.1093/oso/9780199286881.001.0001Suche in Google Scholar

Bach, S., G. Corneo, and V. Steiner. 2009. “From Bottom to Top: The Entire Income Distribution in Germany, 1992–2003.” Review of Income and Wealth 55 (2): 303–30. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-4991.2009.00317.x.Suche in Google Scholar

Banken, R. 2019. “Durch Weltwirtschaftskrise und Rüstungsboom. Die Entwicklung der großen Vermögen 1928-1940 in Deutschland.” In Reichtum in Deutschland. Akteure, Räume und Lebenswelten im 20. Jahrhundert, edited by E. M. Gajek, A. Kurr, and L. Seegers, 289–312. Göttingen: Wallstein.10.5771/9783835343276-287Suche in Google Scholar

Baron, D. 1988. Die personelle Vermögensverteilung in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland und ihre Bestimmungsgründe. Frankfurt: Peter Lang.Suche in Google Scholar

Bartels, C. 2019. “Top Incomes in Germany, 1871-2014.” The Journal of Economic History 79 (3): 669–707. https://doi.org/10.1017/s0022050719000378.Suche in Google Scholar

Bartels, C., and T. Bönke. 2015. “Die statistische Erfassung hoher Einkommen, Vermögen und Erbschaften in Deutschland.” In Thomas Piketty und die Verteilungsfrage: Analysen, Bewertungen und wirtschaftspolitische Implikationen für Deutschland: Analysen, Bewertungen und Wirtschaftspolitische Implikationen fur Deutschland, edited by G. Horn, K. Schmid, T. van Treeck, and P. Bofinger, 159–92. Leipzig: SE Publishing.Suche in Google Scholar

Bartels, C., and M. Metzing. 2019. “An Integrated Approach for a Top-Corrected Income Distribution.” The Journal of Economic Inequality 17 (2): 125–43. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10888-018-9394-x.Suche in Google Scholar

Bartels, C., and D. Waldenström. 2022. “Inequality and Top Incomes.” In Handbook of Labor, Human Resources and Population Economics, edited by K. Zimmermann. Springer.10.1007/978-3-319-57365-6_169-2Suche in Google Scholar

Bartels, C., T. Bönke, R. Glaubitz, M. M. Grabka, and C. Schröder. 2023. “Accounting for Pension Wealth, the Missing Rich and Under-coverage: A Comprehensive Wealth Distribution for Germany.” Economics Letters 231: 111299. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2023.111299.Suche in Google Scholar

Bartels, C., F. Kersting, and N. Wolf. 2023. “Testing Marx: Capital Accumulation, Income Inequality, and Socialism in Late Nineteenth-Century Germany.” The Review of Economics and Statistics: 1–44. https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_01305.Suche in Google Scholar

Bartels, C., S. Jäger, and N. Obergruber. 2024 In press. “Long-Term Effects of Equal Sharing: Evidence from Inheritance Rules for Land.” The Economic Journal, https://doi.org/10.1093/ej/ueae040.Suche in Google Scholar

Bátori, I., and E. Weyrauch. 1982. Die bürgerliche Elite der Stadt Kitzingen: Studien zur Sozial- und Wirtschaftsgeschichte einer landesherrlichen Stadt im 16. Jahrhundert. Stuttgart: Klett-Cotta.Suche in Google Scholar

Biedermann, E. 1918. “Die Einkommens- und Vermögensverhältnisse der preussischen Bevölkerung im Zeitraum 1895–1914 und ihre Übertragunsmöglichkeit auf das deutsche Reich.” In Zeitschrift des Königlich Preussischen Statistischen Landesamts, Vol. 58, 60–86.Suche in Google Scholar

Blanchet, T., J. Fournier, and T. Piketty. 2022. “Generalized Pareto Curves: Theory and Applications.” Review of Income and Wealth 68: 263–88. https://doi.org/10.1111/roiw.12510.Suche in Google Scholar

Bönke, T., A. Harnack-Eber, and H. Penz. 2024. “Earnings Growth, Inequality and Absolute Mobility in Germany, 1882-2019.” SSRN Working Paper No. 4822704.10.2139/ssrn.4822704Suche in Google Scholar

Bönke, T., G. Corneo, and H. Lüthen. 2015. “Lifetime Earnings Inequality in Germany.” Journal of Labor Economics 33 (1): 171–208. https://doi.org/10.1086/677559.Suche in Google Scholar

Bracht, J., and U. Pfister. 2020. Landpacht, Marktgesellschaft und Agrarentwicklung: FünfAdelsgüter zwischen Rhein und Weser, 16–19. Jahrhundert. Stuttgart: Franz Steiner Verlag.10.25162/9783515124454Suche in Google Scholar

Buck, L. 1914. Die Ermittlung des steuerpflichtigen Einkommens und Vermögens, zum Handgebrauch von Publikum und Behörden. Berlin: C. Heymann.Suche in Google Scholar

Bundesbank. 2022. “Eine verteilungsbasierte Vermögensbilanz der privaten Haushalte in Deutschland–Ergebnisse und Anwendungen.” In Monatsbericht der Deutschen Bundesbank Juli, 15–40.Suche in Google Scholar

Burhop, C., and G. B. Wolff. 2005. “A Compromise Estimate of German Net National Product, 1851–1913, and its Implications for Growth and Business Cycles.” The Journal of Economic History 65 (3): 613–57. https://doi.org/10.1017/s0022050705000239.Suche in Google Scholar

Davis, M., and J. Heathcote. 2007. “The Price and Quantity of Residential Land in the United States.” Journal of Monetary Economics 54 (8): 2595–620. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2007.06.023.Suche in Google Scholar

Dell, F. 2008. “L’Allemagne inégale: inégalités de revenus et de patrimoine en Allemagne, dynamique d’accumulation du capital et taxation de Bismarck à Schröder 1870-2005.” PhD thesis. Paris: EHESS.Suche in Google Scholar

Deutsche Bundesbank. 2019. “Vermögen und Finanzen privater Haushalte in Deutschland: Ergebnisse der Vermögensbefragung 2017,” Vol. 13. Monthly Report April 13.Suche in Google Scholar

Dirlmeier, U. 1978. Untersuchungen zu Einkommensverhältnissen und Lebenshaltungskosten in oberdeutschen Städten des Spätmittelalters. Heidelberg: Universitätsverlag.Suche in Google Scholar

Dumke, R. H. 1987. “Economic Inequality and Industrialization in Germany: 1850-1913.” PhD thesis.Suche in Google Scholar

Federal Statistical Office. 1954. “Ergebnisse der Gehalts- und Lohnstrukturerhebung 1951/52.” In Statistik der Bundesrepublik Deutschland, Vol. 90.Suche in Google Scholar

Federal Statistical Office. 1960. “Ergebnisse der Gehalts- und Lohnstrukturerhebung 1957.” In Statistik der Bundesrepublik Deutschland, Vol. 246.Suche in Google Scholar

Federal Statistical Office. 1965. “Ergebnisse der Gehalts- und Lohnstrukturerhebung 1962.” In Statistik der Bundesrepublik Deutschland, Vol. 17.Suche in Google Scholar

Fuisting, B. 1907. Die Preußischen direkten Steuern, Bd. 1. Berlin: C. Heymann.Suche in Google Scholar

Giloy, J. 1978. Vieldeutige Einkommensbegriffe. Zur geeigneten Bezugsgröße staatlicher Transferleistungen. Herne, Berlin: Verlag Neue Wirtschafts-Briefe.Suche in Google Scholar

Goldsmith, R. W. 1985. Comparative National Balance Sheets: A Study of Twenty Countries, 1688-1979. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Suche in Google Scholar

Gómez León, M., and H. J. De Jong. 2019. “Inequality in Turbulent Times: Income Distribution in Germany and Britain, 1900–50.” The Economic History Review 72 (3): 1073–98. https://doi.org/10.1111/ehr.12770.Suche in Google Scholar

Haig, R. M. 1921. “The Concept of Income- Economic and Legal Aspects.” In The Federal Income Tax, edited by R. M. Haig, 1–28. New York: Columbia University Press.Suche in Google Scholar

Helfferich, D. V. 1914. Volkswohlstand 1888–1913. Berlin: Stilke.Suche in Google Scholar

Himmelreicher, R. K., and M. Stegmann. 2008. “New Possibilities for Socio-Economic Research through Longitudinal Data from the Research Data Centre of the German Federal Pension Insurance (FDZ-RV).” In Schmollers Jahrbuch : Zeitschrift für Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften, Vol. 128, 647–60.10.3790/schm.128.4.647Suche in Google Scholar

Hoffmann, W. 1965. Das Wachstum der deutschen Wirtschaft seit der Mitte des 19. Jahrhunderts. Enzyklopädie der Rechts- und Staatswissenschaft. Berlin: Springer.10.1007/978-3-642-86088-1Suche in Google Scholar

Hoffmann, W., and J. Müller. 1959. Das deutsche Volkseinkommen 1851-1957. Tübingen: Mohr.Suche in Google Scholar

Hohls, R. 1991. “Arbeit und Verdienst – Entwicklung und Struktur der Arbeitseinkommen im Deutschen Reich und in der Bundesrepublik (1885-1985).” PhD thesis. Freie Univeristät Berlin.Suche in Google Scholar

Hohls, R. 1995. “The Sectoral Structure of Earnings in germany, 1885–1985.” In Labour’s Reward: Real Wages and Economic Change in 19th- and 20th-Century Europe, edited by P. Scholliers, and V. Zamagni, 37–60. Hants: Edward Elgar Publishing.Suche in Google Scholar

Jones, C. I. 2015. “Pareto and Piketty: The Macroeconomics of Top Income and Wealth Inequality.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 29 (1): 29–46. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.29.1.29.Suche in Google Scholar

Kleber, W., and A. Willms. 1982. “Historische Berufszählungen 1882-1970.” In Datenhandbuch. VASMA-Projekt, Universität Mannheim (Datenproduzent). GESIS – Leibniz-Institut für Sozialwissenschaften, German Microdata Lab (Datendistributor).Suche in Google Scholar

Königliches Statistisches Bureau. 1895. Statistik der preussischen Einkommen- und Ergänzungssteuer-Veranlagung für das Jahr 1896/96. Berlin: Verlag des Königlichen Statistischen Bureaus.Suche in Google Scholar

Königliches Statistisches Bureau. 1912. Statistisches Jahrbuch für den Preussischen Staat 1911. Berlin: Verlag des Königlichen Statistischen Landesamts.Suche in Google Scholar

Krelle, W., J. Schunck, and J. Siebke. 1968. Überbetriebliche Ertragsbeteiligung der Arbeitnehmer, Vol. 2. Tübingen: Mohr.Suche in Google Scholar

Kuznets, S. 1955. “Economic Growth and Income Inequality.” The American Economic Review 45 (1): 1–28.Suche in Google Scholar

Lindert, P. 2000. “Three Centuries of Inequality in Britain and America.” In Handbook of Income Distribution, Vol. 1, edited by A. Atkinson, and F. Bourguignon, 167–216. Amsterdam: Elsevier.10.1016/S1574-0056(00)80006-8Suche in Google Scholar

Lorenz, M. O. 1905. “Methods of Measuring the Concentration of Wealth.” Publications of the American Statistical Association 9 (70): 209–19. https://doi.org/10.1080/15225437.1905.10503443.Suche in Google Scholar

May, R. E. 1909. “Volksvermögen.” Preussische Jahrbücher 136 (4): 95–148.Suche in Google Scholar

Metzger, U., and J. Weingarten. 1989. Einkommensteuer und Einkommensteuerverwaltung in Deutschland – Ein historischer und verwaltungswissenschaftlicher Überblick. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.10.1007/978-3-663-09889-8Suche in Google Scholar

Milanovic, B. 2005. Worlds Apart: Measuring International and Global Inequality. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Suche in Google Scholar

Milanovic, B., P. Lindert, and J. Williamson. 2011. “Pre-Industrial Inequality.” The Economic Journal 121: 255–72. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2010.02403.x.Suche in Google Scholar

Müller, Heinz, and S. Geisenberger. 1972. Die Einkommensstruktur in verschiedenen deutschen Ländern 1874-1913. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.Suche in Google Scholar

Ogden, R. E., D. R. Thomas, and M. Warusawitharana. 2016. Corporate Equities by Issuer in the Financial Accounts of the United States. FEDS Notes. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. March 29, 2016.10.17016/2380-7172.1731Suche in Google Scholar

Ogilvie, S., and F. Schaff. 2024. Inheritance and Inequality in a Pre-modern Economy. Oxford, Fiesole: Unpublished manuscript All Souls College Oxford and European University Institute.Suche in Google Scholar

O’Rourke, K. H., and J. G. Williamson. 2001. Globalization and History: The Evolution of a Nineteenth-Century Atlantic Economy. Cambridge: MIT Press.Suche in Google Scholar

Pfister, U. 2019a. “The Inequality of Pay in Pre-modern Germany, Late 15th Century to 1889.” Jahrbuch für Wirtschaftsgeschichte 60: 209–43. https://doi.org/10.1515/jbwg-2019-0009.Suche in Google Scholar

Pfister, U. 2019b. “The Crafts-Harley View of German Industrialization: An Independent Estimate of the Income Side of Net National Product, 1851-1913.” European Review of Economic History 24 (3): 502–21. https://doi.org/10.1093/ereh/hez009.Suche in Google Scholar

Pfister, U. 2020. “Economic Inequality in Germany, 1500-1800.” In Disuguaglianza economica nelle società preindustriali: Cause ed effetti/Economic inequality in Pre-industrial Societies: Causes and Effect, 301–24. Florence: Firenze University Press.10.36253/978-88-5518-053-5.20Suche in Google Scholar

Pfister, U. 2022. “Economic Growth in Germany, 1500–1850.” The Journal of Economic History 82 (4): 1071–107. https://doi.org/10.1017/s002205072200033x.Suche in Google Scholar

Piketty, T. 2003. “Income Inequality in France, 1901-1998.” Journal of Political Economy 111 (5): 1004–42. https://doi.org/10.1086/376955.Suche in Google Scholar

Piketty, T. 2014. Capital in the 21st Century. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Suche in Google Scholar

Piketty, T., and E. Saez. 2003. “Income Inequality in the United States, 1913-1998.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (1): 1–39. https://doi.org/10.1162/00335530360535135.Suche in Google Scholar

Piketty, T., and G. Zucman. 2014. “Capital Is Back: Wealth-Income Ratios in Rich Countries, 1700-2010.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (3): 1255–310. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qju018.Suche in Google Scholar

Piketty, T., and G. Zucman. 2015. “Wealth and Inheritance in the Long Run.” In Handbook of Income Distribution, Volume 2 of Handbook of Income Distribution, edited by A. B. Atkinson, and F. Bourguignon, 1303–68. Amsterdam: Elsevier.10.1016/B978-0-444-59429-7.00016-9Suche in Google Scholar

Preussischer Staat. 1893. “Preussisches Ergänzungssteuergesetz. Vom 14. Juli 1893.” FinanzArchiv/Public Finance Analysis 10 (2): 304–17.Suche in Google Scholar

Procopovitch, S. N. 1926. “The Distribution of National Income.” Economic Journal 36 (141): 69–82. https://doi.org/10.2307/2223489.Suche in Google Scholar

Römer, F. 2023. Inequality Knowledge. The Making of the Numbers about the Gap between Rich and Poor in Contemporary Britain. Berlin: De Gruyter Oldenbourg.10.1515/9783111317052Suche in Google Scholar

Sabean, D. 1990. Property, Production, and Family in Neckarhausen, 1700–1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511572579Suche in Google Scholar

Saez, E., and G. Zucman. 2016. “Wealth Inequality in the United States since 1913: Evidence from Capitalized Income Tax Data.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 131 (2): 519–78. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjw004.Suche in Google Scholar

Schaff, F. 2023. “Warfare and Economic Inequality: Evidence from Preindustrial Germany (C. 1400-1800).” Explorations in Economic History 89 (2): 101495. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eeh.2022.101495.Suche in Google Scholar

Schaff, F. 2024a. “The Unequal Spirit of the Protestant Reformation: Particularism and Wealth Distribution in Early Modern Germany.” Journal of Economic Growth, In press.10.1007/s10887-024-09245-zSuche in Google Scholar

Schaff, F. 2024b. “Urban Political Structure and Inequality: Political Economy Lessons from Early Modern German Cities.” The Journal of Economic History 84 (2): 517–53. https://doi.org/10.1017/s0022050724000135.Suche in Google Scholar

Schanz, G. 1896. “Der Einkommensbegriff und die Einkommensteuergesetze.” FinanzArchiv 13 (1): 1–87.Suche in Google Scholar

Scheidel, W. 2017. The Great Leveler. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Suche in Google Scholar

Schinke, C. 2012. “Inheritance in Germany 1911 to 2009: A Mortality Multiplier Approach.” SOEPpapers DP 462.10.2139/ssrn.2131208Suche in Google Scholar

Schmoller, G. 1895. “Die Einkommensverteilung in alter und neuer Zeit.” In Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft, Vol. 19, 1067–94.Suche in Google Scholar

Schmoller, G. 1896. The Mercantile System and its Historical Significance Illustrated Chiefly from Prussian History. New York: Macmillan.Suche in Google Scholar

Schröder, C., C. Bartels, M. Grabka, J. König, M. Kroh, and R. Siegers. 2020. “A Novel Sampling Strategy for Surveying High-Worth Individuals – an Application Using the Socio-Economic Panel.” Review of Income and Wealth 66 (4): 825–49. https://doi.org/10.1111/roiw.12452.Suche in Google Scholar

Simons, H. 1938. Personal Income Taxation: The Definition of Income as a Problem of Fiscal Policy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Suche in Google Scholar

Spoerer, M. 2004. Steuerlast, Steuerinzidenz und Steuerwettbewerb: Verteilungswirkungen der Besteuerung in Preußen und Württemberg (1815–1913), Vol. 6. Berlin: Akademie Verlag.10.1515/9783050084152Suche in Google Scholar

Statistisches Reichsamt. 1919. “Wehrbeitragstatistik.” In Vierteljahreshefte zur Statistik des Deutschen Reichs – Zweites Ergänzungsheft (28).Suche in Google Scholar

Statistisches Reichsamt. 1927. “Die deutsche Vermögensbesteuerung vor und nach dem Kriege.” In Statistik des deutschen Reiches, Vol. 337. Berlin: Hobbing.Suche in Google Scholar

Statistisches Reichsamt. 1930. “Statistik der Einheitswerte für den ersten Hauptfeststellungszeitraum 1925–1927.” In Statistik des Deutschen Reiches, Vol. 365.Suche in Google Scholar

Statistisches Reichsamt. 1931. “Statistik der Einheitswerte für den zweiten Hauptfeststellungszeitraum 1928–1930.” In Statistik des Deutschen Reiches, Vol. 392.Suche in Google Scholar

Statistisches Reichsamt. 1939. “Die Hauptfeststellung der Einheitswerte nach dem Stand vom 1. Januar 1935.” In Statistik des Deutschen Reiches, Vol. 526.Suche in Google Scholar

Steinmann-Bucher, A. 1916. Deutschlands Volksvermögen im Krieg. Stuttgart: Ferdinand Enke.Suche in Google Scholar

Stockmann, R. 1984. “Eine organisationsstrukturelle Analyse zur Entwicklung der geschlechtsspezifischen Beschäftigungsstruktur.” VASMA-Arbeitspapier Nr. 41.Suche in Google Scholar

Sweezy, M. Y. 1939. “Distribution of Wealth and Income under the Nazis.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 21 (4): 178–84. https://doi.org/10.2307/1926604.Suche in Google Scholar

Ullmann, H.-P. 2005. Der deutsche Steuerstaat: Geschichte der öffentlichen Finanzen vom 18. Jahrhundert bis heute. München: C.H.Beck.Suche in Google Scholar

van Zanden, J. 1995. “Tracing the Beginning of the Kuznets Curve: Western Europe during the Early Modern Period.” The Economic History Review 48 (4): 643–64. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0289.1995.tb01437.x.Suche in Google Scholar

Wagner, A. 1904. “Weitere statistische Untersuchungen über die Verteilung des Volkseinkommens in Preussen.” In Zeitschrift des Königlich Preussischen Statistischen Bureaus, Vol. 44.Suche in Google Scholar

Wegge, S. 2021. “Inheritance Institutions and Landholding Inequality in Nineteenth-Century Germany: Village-Level Evidence from Hesse-Cassel.” The Journal of Economic History 81 (3): 909–42. https://doi.org/10.1017/s0022050721000358.Suche in Google Scholar

Received: 2024-06-14
Accepted: 2024-08-08
Published Online: 2024-09-16
Published in Print: 2024-12-17

© 2024 the author(s), published by De Gruyter, Berlin/Boston

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.

Heruntergeladen am 14.9.2025 von https://www.degruyterbrill.com/document/doi/10.1515/ger-2024-0060/html
Button zum nach oben scrollen