Abstract
Using a novel dataset we examine the pricing behavior of Indian exporters, in particular looking at the relationship between export prices and the quality of imported inputs that firms use, conditioning on firm capability (productivity). Exporting firms that directly import are different in important ways from exporters that do not import directly. Among directly importing exporters, higher quality (higher price) imports are associated with higher quality (higher price) exports. In this respect, Indian exporters behave similarly to other developing country exporters, offering suggestive evidence of the importance for export success of access to high-quality imports.
Acknowledgments
We are deeply grateful for able research assistance from Matthew Reardon. We also thank Stephanie Fortune-Taylor, Hannah Hall, George Nurisso, Daniel Rodriguez, and Rainy Zhang. We gratefully acknowledge helpful comments, especially from Chris Handy, and also from participants in sessions at the fall 2016 Mid-West International Economics Group meetings, at the fall 2016 Southern Economics Association meetings, and at the U.S. International Trade Commission, Office of Economics, Research Division seminar series, where versions of this paper were presented. An earlier version of this paper appeared as USITC Office of Economics Working Paper 2017-01-B, January 2017, and Anderson and Smith gratefully acknowledge the support of the USITC's Office of Economics Research Division, where they served as Visiting Scholars in fall 2016. This paper represents the views of its authors only and is not meant to represent in any way the views of the U.S. International Trade Commission or any of its individual Commissioners.
Appendix
A Data construction and “HS 8-plus” level of product detail
Our main analysis relies on a merged dataset built by a firm-by-firm match of TIPS and Prowess data, excluding wholesalers for the sake of focusing on the trading behavior of production firms. TIPS data required considerable preparation for the merge, over and above simply aggregating its daily data to a fiscal year basis. A final merge with CEPII data brought destination market characteristics into the data set. The entire data construction process is described in detail in the appendix to Anderson et al. (2016).
As noted in the text we use an “HS 8-plus” product definition in the paper. Nearly all of the HS 8 tariff lines in TIPS have product definitions recorded by Indian Customs, and moreover those definitions vary within 8-digit lines. For example, a single HS 8 line might contain multiple types of textiles, and another might include multiple types of cooking spices, all with product definitions that define more precisely than the HS 8 code what was actually exported. Our challenge was to create usable information from these notes recorded by individual customs agents, often with different word orders or different spellings, across thousands of tariff lines over four years. We used two fuzzy-logic computer algorithms to identify common product definitions within each HS 8 line (Levenshtein distance and bigram comparisons), and added this information to the HS 8 codes to create the product definitions in our dataset.
Inside of an HS 8 or HS 8-plus code the quantity units can vary widely. The dependent variable in our empirical work is the export product price, defined as an export unit value and calculated as the relevant total value of exports divided by quantity. So, for instance, a firm's average price for selling a particular product to the United States in any given year would be the value of sales divided by, say, the metric tons sold. But in many of the single firm-product-destination categories, export values are reported in several different units, such as “buckles,” kilos, pounds, and boxes, the sum of which yields the total value of exports for that firm-product-destination observation. It is not possible to make meaningful unit value comparisons, or aggregations, across different units in these instances.
We therefore drop all observations that are measured in units that are not official units recognized by Indian Customs (see http://www.cybex.in/International-Trade-Resources/Unit_Quantity_Code.aspx). Further, we aggregate and “harmonize” the remaining values where there are well-established conversion factors for the units. Therefore in many instances we convert pounds to kilos, and tons to metric tons, and so on, prior to calculating unit values. However, there remain thousands of lines of data where the conversion factors are unknown, or for which the reporting of separate lines based on different quantity measures strongly suggests that there are in fact underlying differences between the goods reported in those lines (even when they are in the same 8-digit HS category). Accordingly, for the analysis reported here we keep only the top three units in each HS line, by value, and drop the others, a trim which costs approximately 2.5% of all observations.
The sigma indices of the quality of imported inputs are constructed from TIPS import data (aggregated and harmonized as described above). We calculate an annual z-score for the price a firm pays for each imported input (relative to the universe of prices paid for that good by all importing firms in TIPS), and then calculate an annual import value-weighted mean z-score across the firm's import bundle each year. The higher the sigma, the higher the relative price (and, by implication, the quality) of the firm's imported inputs. The sigma for capital goods imports uses the HS-based definition of capital goods developed in Bakht, Yunus, and Salimullah (2002).
The final data set contains 25,962 individual firm-product-destination-year observations over fiscal 2000–2003 for exporters including matched information on the prices these firms paid for imports (if any), drawn from 1,098 unique firms. Although by name alone we are able to match more firms than this, many observations are lost because they are not manufacturing firms (e. g., wholesalers), have incomplete information (e. g., missing input information in Prowess), or do not survive our procedures to clean the data.
We calculate TFP using the Stata implementation of the Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) technique, following Topalova and Khandelwal (2011) approach (pp. 998–999) to put each firm's productivity into index form (which itself depends on Aw, Chen, and Roberts 2001), which allows productivity comparisons within and between industries. We measure firm output with value-added (Topalova and Khandelwal 2011, use sales). Capital is measured as the size of each firm's gross fixed assets, and labor is proxied by the wage and salary bill (the number of employees is not included in Prowess). Note that this is the measure of labor used both in the TFP calculation and directly (in log form, “ln_labor”) on the right hand side of our regressions reported in Table 5 and Table 6 as our proxy for firm size; we also calculate the capital/labor ratio used in the regressions (“ln_klabor”) from these capital and labor variables.
We estimate TFP at the 4-digit National Industrial Classification (NIC) code level where possible, and at the 3-digit level when necessary due to a small number of firms at the 4-digit level (less than 20). We use Prowess data on firms’ spending on raw materials and electric power as the proxy for productivity shocks. All variables are expressed in real terms: output is deflated by two-digit industry-level wholesale prices indices from Ahsan (2013); capital expenditures are deflated by a capital goods wholesale price index we construct from several sub-industry wholesale price indices (including machine tools, electric machinery, and other capital goods); materials and power are likewise deflated with separate materials and power wholesale price indices we construct; and finally the wage and salary bill is deflated by the Economist Intelligence Unit's Indian labor cost index.
We calculate remoteness as in Harrigan, Ma, and Shlychkov (2015): the GDP-weighted distance of an export partner from all other export partners. So, for example, when we observe a transaction with the Philippines we sum the GDP-weighted distances between the Philippines and India's other export partners. Therefore
B Controlling for Destination Market and Firm Characteristics
As in Harrigan, Ma, and Shlychkov (2015), we consider the possibility of selection bias because firm prices are only observed if firms choose to export to particular destinations, and we implement their three-stage estimator, itself an extension of Wooldridge (1995). The first stage is a Probit of entry (of a firm in a particular destination in a particular year) on all exogenous export-market characteristics (Xd), firm characteristics (Xf), and a year-specific intercept
where Yfpd indicates firm f's revenues from exports of product p to destination d. Equation (1) is estimated over an expanded sample of all possible firm-destination-year combinations; that is, it is applied to a “rectangularized” data set with zeros added. The inverse Mills ratio
Quasi-residuals, formed as the actual residuals plus the estimated term for the inverse Mills ratio,
This approach is more flexible than the two-step Tobit approach proposed by Wooldridge (1995) in that the estimated effects on entry, the δ’s in eq. (1), are allowed to differ from the effects on export intensity, the ζ’s in equation (2).[22]
References
Ahsan, R. 2013. “Input Tariffs, Speed of Contract Enforcement, and the Productivity of Firms in India.” Journal of International Economics, 90 (1): 181–192.10.1016/j.jinteco.2012.11.006Search in Google Scholar
Anderson, M.A., M.H. Davies, J. Signoret, and S.L.S. Smith. 2016. “Firm Heterogeneity and Export Pricing in India.” U.S. International Trade Commission Office of Economics Working Paper No. 2016-09-A. https://www.usitc.gov/publications/332/ec_wp_2016-09-b.pdf10.1002/soej.12316Search in Google Scholar
Antoniades, A 2012. Heterogeneous Firms, Quality, and Trade. Washington, D.C.: Georgetown UniversitySearch in Google Scholar
Antoniades, A. 2015. “Heterogeneous Firms, Quality, and Trade.” Journal of International Economics, 95 (2): 263–273.10.1016/j.jinteco.2014.10.002Search in Google Scholar
Aw, B., X. Chen, and M. Roberts. 2001. “Firm Level Evidence on Productivity Differentials and Turnover in Taiwanese Manufacturing.” Journal of Development Economics, 66 (1): 61–86.10.3386/w6235Search in Google Scholar
Bakht, Z., M. Yunus, and M. Salimullah. 2002. “Machinery Industry in Bangladesh.” IDEAS Machinery Industry Study Report No. 4, Japan External Trade Organization (March).Search in Google Scholar
Bas, M., and V. Strauss-Kahn. 2015. “Input-Trade Liberalization, Export Prices and Quality Upgrading.” Journal of International Economics 95 (2): 250–62.10.1016/j.jinteco.2014.12.005Search in Google Scholar
Bastos, P., D. Dias, and O. Timoshenko. 2016. “Learning, Prices, and Firm Dynamics.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 7667 (May).10.1596/1813-9450-7667Search in Google Scholar
Bastos, P., and J. Silva. 2010. “The Quality of a Firm's Exports: Where You Export to Matters.” Journal of International Economics, 82 (2): 99–111.10.1016/j.jinteco.2010.07.001Search in Google Scholar
Bastos, P., J. Silva, and E. Verhoogen. 2018. “Export Destinations and Input Prices.” American Economic Review, 108 (2): 353–392. doi:https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20140647Search in Google Scholar
Bernard, A., B. Jensen, S. Redding, and P. Schott. 2007. “Firms in International Trade.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21 (3): 105–130.10.1257/jep.21.3.105Search in Google Scholar
Costinot, A., and I. Werning. 2017. “The Lerner Symmetry Theorem: Generalizations and Qualifications.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 23427 (May).10.3386/w23427Search in Google Scholar
Goldberg, P., A. Khandelwal, N. Pavcnik, and P. Topalova. 2010. “Trade Liberalization and New Imported Inputs.” American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 99 (2): 494–500.10.1257/aer.99.2.494Search in Google Scholar
Görg, H., L. Halpern, and B. Muraközy. 2017. “Why Do within Firm-Product Export Prices Differ across Markets? Evidence from Hungary.” The World Economy, 40 (6): 1233–1246.10.1111/twec.12442Search in Google Scholar
Hallak, J., and J. Sivadasan. 2013. “Product and Process Productivity: Implications for Quality Choice and Conditional Export Premia.” Journal of International Economics, 91: 53–67.10.1016/j.jinteco.2013.05.001Search in Google Scholar
Harrigan, J., X. Ma, and V. Shlychkov. 2015. “Export Prices of U.S. Firms.” Journal of International Economics, 97: 100–111.10.1016/j.jinteco.2015.04.007Search in Google Scholar
Head, K., T. Mayer, and J. Ries. 2010. “The Erosion of Colonial Trade Linkages after Independence.” Journal of International Economics, 81 (1): 1–14.10.1016/j.jinteco.2010.01.002Search in Google Scholar
Khandelwal, A. 2010. “The Long and Short (Of) Quality Ladders.” Review of Economic Studies, 77: 1450–1476.10.1111/j.1467-937X.2010.00602.xSearch in Google Scholar
Kugler, M., and E. Verhoogen. 2012. “Prices, Plant Size, and Product Quality.” Review of Economic Studies, 79: 307–339.10.1093/restud/rdr021Search in Google Scholar
Lerner, Abba P. 1936. “The Symmetry between Import and Export Taxes.” Economica, 3 (11): 306–313.10.2307/2549223Search in Google Scholar
Levinsohn, J., and A. Petrin. 2003. “Estimating Production Functions Using Inputs to Control for Unobservables.” Review of Economic Studies, 70: 317–341.10.1111/1467-937X.00246Search in Google Scholar
Lindé, J., and A. Pescatori. 2017. “The Macroeconomic Effects of Trade Tariffs: Revisiting the Lerner Symmetry Result.” IMF Working Paper WP/17/151 (July).10.5089/9781484306116.001Search in Google Scholar
Manova, K., and Z. Zhang. 2012. “Export Prices across Firms and Destinations.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127: 379–436.10.1093/qje/qjr051Search in Google Scholar
Martin, J. 2012. “Markups, Quality and Transport Costs.” European Economic Review, 56: 777–791.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2012.02.004Search in Google Scholar
Melitz, M. 2003. “The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity.” Econometrica : Journal of the Econometric Society, 71 (6): 1695–1725.10.1111/1468-0262.00467Search in Google Scholar
Sutton, J. 1998. Technology and Market Structure: Theory and History. Cambridge: MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar
Tokarick, S. 2006. “Does Import Protection Discourage Exports?” IMF Working Paper WP/06/20 (January).10.5089/9781451862805.001Search in Google Scholar
Topalova, P., and A. Khandelwal. 2011. “Trade Liberalization and Firm Productivity: The Case of India.” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 93 (3): 995–1009.10.1162/REST_a_00095Search in Google Scholar
Wooldridge, J. 1995. “Selection Corrections for Panel Data Models under Conditional Mean Independence Assumptions.” Journal of Econometrics, 68 (1): 115–132.10.1016/0304-4076(94)01645-GSearch in Google Scholar
© 2018 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston
Articles in the same Issue
- Firm Heterogeneity, Imported Input Quality, and Export Pricing in India
- Fishing Downstream Revisited: A Multi-country Analysis of Antidumping Patterns
- The Labor Share Squeeze in Latin America: A Dynamic Heterogeneous Approach
- Lead Jurisdiction Concepts: Prospects and Limits for Rationalizing International Competition Policy Enforcement
- A Prima Facie Evidence on the Impact of Export Diversification on Relative Trade Preferential Margin
Articles in the same Issue
- Firm Heterogeneity, Imported Input Quality, and Export Pricing in India
- Fishing Downstream Revisited: A Multi-country Analysis of Antidumping Patterns
- The Labor Share Squeeze in Latin America: A Dynamic Heterogeneous Approach
- Lead Jurisdiction Concepts: Prospects and Limits for Rationalizing International Competition Policy Enforcement
- A Prima Facie Evidence on the Impact of Export Diversification on Relative Trade Preferential Margin