Abstract
No election rules are perfect, but they can be better. The Electoral College is increasingly failing to represent voter preferences in determining election winners. A path to reform begins with identifying election goals and establishing voting rules that best achieve these goals.
1 Introduction
On November 6, 2024, Donald Trump won the Presidency of the United States with 312 Electoral votes. A potential crisis in voter confidence was averted because Mr. Trump also won the popular vote by just over 2.2 million votes. This “dual” win has temporarily assuaged a growing distrust of the democratic process in America. Still, his popular vote win was a narrow 49.8 percent to 48.3 percent. While some view Mr. Trump winning the Electoral College and popular vote as a mandate, the narrow margin in the popular vote shows just how close the United States was to a result that could have escalated the crisis in democratic confidence.
For the first two centuries of the United States, only three instances occurred where the popular vote winner did not win the presidency – John Quincy Adams in 1824, Rutherford B. Hayes in 1876, and Grover Cleveland in 1888. However, this has happened twice in the last twenty-four years – George W. Bush in 2000 and Trump in 2016. Whatever your political views, it is undeniable that this phenomenon undermines the winner’s legitimacy. Our position is that had this happened again in 2024, the current crisis would have escalated. Such a result is possible in the future and creates ill will towards the US democratic process.
To avoid such a crisis in democracy, we propose that now is the time for election reform. We propose using market design to look beyond the Electoral College and popular vote as the only two alternatives. The status quo is one where successful political candidates optimize campaign strategies for the voting rules. This obvious fact is why candidates are ruthlessly focused on the battleground states. Their goal is to tip enough voters in their favor to garner the state’s precious Electoral College votes. Two strategies are pursued: (1) attract undecided voters and (2) encourage more supporters to vote or non-supporters not to vote. The 2024 presidential election was clearly defined by Mr. Trump succeeding in this capacity by winning all seven key battleground states, although by slim margins.
Realistically, most other states don’t matter. Harris won California, and Trump won Texas, as anticipated. It is inconceivable that any one person’s vote in these states impacted the overall outcome. Campaigning in these states is primarily about winning the majority in Congress for the candidate’s party. Gerrymandering makes this difficult but not impossible in the House. Ask the Democrats residing in Austin, Texas. The Austin districts are drawn to bring in enough rural Republicans that the Republicans win. Knowing your vote does not matter frustrates voters.
These gaming behaviors also distort who we are apt to see at the top of the ticket. Chess grandmasters are good at chess. Likewise, top presidential candidates are good at gaming the Electoral College. The key attribute is succeeding is improving the margin in the marginal states. This is an implication of the Electoral College. Unfortunately, there is no reason to suspect that candidates who are superb at gaming the Electoral College will necessarily be good at serving the public interest. A better voting rule may better align incentives to avoid the possibility of electing a candidate who is exceptionally good at Electoral College gaming yet has no interest in serving the public at large.
Improving presidential voting rules is challenging because it would require passing a Constitutional Amendment, which requires a two-thirds supermajority vote in the House and Senate and subsequent ratification by three-quarters of the states. Such consensus is made all the more difficult because whichever party is in power wants to stay there. In recent presidential elections, the status quo has favored the Republican party, so Republican representatives may hesitate to alter a system that has worked for them. Still, it is worth exploring the issue.
Market design provides a pragmatic and powerful lens through which to study election reform. The market design has brought successful innovations in many critical markets, such as electricity and communications, two crucial commodities, but also to matching markets that do not use price as the key instrument to manage scarcity, such as matching doctors to residencies, students to public schools, and organ donors to recipients. Like all markets, these involve allocating scarce resources. The market rules define an algorithm for eliciting preferences from market participants and then mapping these preferences into an outcome that best satisfies the market’s goals.
The benefit of a market-designed system is that it is flexible and allows for agile, incremental change as needed, thus ensuring its durability. Specific details are crucial, and deviations from those details can be catastrophic. Unfortunately, system implementation is sometimes plagued by compromises needed to adopt the system, and these compromises can lead to catastrophic results.
The Constitution of the United States provides an excellent example of a good idea gone awry. The ideals of the Constitution, such as protection from authoritarians and freedom of the people, are unquestionable. However, for ratification, substantial deviations from those ideals were embedded in the country’s founding document, including several that affected elections. Amongst the defects in the Constitution, it let individual states decide who was allowed to vote in Federal elections, most of which did not extend suffrage to women and Black people. This is despite the Constitution declaring the rights of “people” and “persons.” Compromise led to the most egregious of the defections from the ideal when the “Three-Fifths Compromise” emerged from the 1787 Constitutional Convention. Not only could Black people not vote, but they were also not even counted as full human beings.
Although the Constitution does provide a pathway for change, in protecting against the tyranny of the majority, it installed a rigidity in its amendment process that nearly led to the destruction of the country in the Civil War. The amendment process ultimately gave Black men the right to vote in 1865, but women did not receive that right until 1920. A more agilely designed system may have averted the split of the Confederacy and spared more than half a million American lives. Although the market design principles were not developed then, they are now. We argue that it is time to apply them in politics. Election reform is an immediate need.
Still, a change to the Constitution would be difficult. From this perspective, we stress that the market design process could also be applied to local and state elections, producing better political leaders at those levels who then “fill the pipeline” and improve the pool of future presidential candidates. Likewise, the market design process can be applied to presidential primaries, where the parties can reform their primaries so that the winner can perform better in the general election.
We can think of voting rules as a means to elicit voters’ preferences and translate them into a winner that best satisfies the electoral goals. The approach combines insights from economics, computer science, and political science. The innovations we describe here are not new. Most have been implemented with success in various settings. We can learn from theory and practice (Foley and Maskin 2022; Foley 2023; Boudreau, Mathews, and Schwartz 2024). We show how the market design approach can be applied to reform presidential voting rules.
2 Historical Background
In the 60 US presidential elections, only five resulted in the winner differing from the popular vote.
1824: John Quincy Adams was elected president by the House of Representatives despite Andrew Jackson receiving more popular and electoral votes.
1876: Rutherford B. Hayes won the Electoral College by one vote, despite Samuel J. Tilden receiving a majority of the popular vote.
1888: Benjamin Harrison won the Electoral College by 65 votes, despite Grover Cleveland receiving more popular votes.
2000: George W. Bush won the Electoral College by five votes, despite Al Gore receiving more popular votes.
2016: Donald Trump won the Electoral College by 77 votes despite Hillary Clinton receiving more popular votes.
The two most similar outcomes of these elections are in 1888 and 2016 when a candidate secured a solid majority in the Electoral College despite losing the popular vote. In contrast, in 1876, Hayes narrowly won the Electoral College by the slimmest of margins even though Tilden’s portion of the popular vote received was three percentage points higher. Specifically, Tilden got 50.9 percent of the popular vote to Hayes’ 47.9 percent. In 2000, the Electoral College and popular vote were very close. Gore received 48.4 percent of the popular vote to Bush’s 47.9 percent.
Many changes in how we elect the president have occurred since the first election 1788. The most significant changes were about who could vote. However, changes related to the Electoral College have also been made. The first came in 1804 as the Twelfth Amendment, which required electors to cast separate votes for president and vice president. Before then, each elector in the Electoral College cast two votes for president with no distinction between the presidency and vice presidency. The candidate with the most electoral votes became president, the runner-up vice president. The election in 1800 revealed a flaw. Thomas Jefferson and Aaron Burr each received an equal number of electoral votes, leading to a tie that had to be broken in the House. Tie-breaking rules are an important element of market design.
Individual states adopted other changes. State legislatures have the power to decide how their electors are chosen. Initially, they had varying methods of selecting electors, including popular vote, appointment by state legislatures, or a combination. In the 1824 election mentioned above, there was no popular vote in 6 of the then 24 states in the union. Since 1868, however, 48 states have adopted the winner-takes-all rule, where the candidate with the most votes in a state gets all its electoral votes. The only exceptions are Maine and Nebraska, where electoral votes are allocated based on the popular vote counts within each congressional district. A further change came in 1961 with the Twenty-third Amendment, which granted the District of Columbia three electoral votes so its residents could participate in presidential elections. The district also uses the winner-takes-all rule.
A more recent issue has been non-compliant electors – those who do not vote according to their state’s popular vote. Three electors from Washington state refused to vote for Hillary Clinton in 2016 when she won the popular vote. The three were fined $1,000 each for their non-compliance. The Supreme Court in Chiafalo v. Washington, 591 US 578 (2020) addressed the matter in a unanimous decision, affirming the state court’s ruling that states can require electors to vote by the state’s popular vote and that they can penalize or replace non-compliant electors. Though not an actual change to the system, the verdict has added to the debate over whether the Electoral College should be replaced.
The closest the US has come to abolishing the Electoral College was the Bayh-Celler amendment, proposed in 1969, which explicitly aimed to replace the Electoral College with the popular vote. It passed in the House but failed in the Senate due to a filibuster. Those who objected were from smaller states who argued that getting rid of the Electoral College would reduce their political influence, reinforcing the idea that those in power prioritize hanging onto it.
Another recent effort to remove the Electoral College, though not an official change to the national system, has been the National Popular Vote Interstate Compact. The Compact is a formal interstate agreement to award all participating states’ electoral votes to whichever presidential ticket wins the national popular vote. If it is ever adopted by states comprising 270 or more electoral votes, it would de facto guarantee that the nation’s popular vote winner becomes president without technically doing away with the Electoral College. As of this writing, the Compact has been adopted by 17 states, comprising 209 electoral votes, further adding to the debate over the role of the Electoral College. This approach could also be used to leverage US election reform. If the Compact has 270 votes, then these states can argue, “Reform or we will impose the popular vote, which we can do unilaterally.”
The evolution of the electoral process points to a desire for change. Although most proposals have favored a shift to the popular vote, including a recent call from vice-presidential candidate Tim Walz (Tait 2024), we suggest a more thoughtful approach based on insights from market design. The benefit comes from thinking beyond the popular vote and Electoral College options. Voting rules evolve in most political systems, and America should not be complacent with the status quo. Continuous improvement is essential. A looming crisis may provide an opportunity.
3 Market Design
After inventing the mobile phone in 1973, the US mobile market fell behind Europe in the early 1990s because the US regulator failed to license radio spectrum essential for mobile communications. This motivated Congress to pass legislation granting the regulator, the Federal Communications Commission (FCC), spectrum auction authority. The FCC, recognizing its inexperience in auctions, began a thoughtful process to identify the best approach to auctions informed by debate among experts (McMillan 1994). The result was an initial auction design that performed well in this complex setting. In 2020, Paul Milgrom and Robert Wilson won the Nobel Prize in Economics partly for their pioneering, practical auction design that was adopted globally.
A successful market design identifies practical tradeoffs and carefully tests them against prioritized goals. The FCC has continued to improve the design of its auctions to address issues identified from experience. Early on, for example, bidders encoded messages in their bids to collude (Cramton and Schwartz 2000). Later, auctions adjusted the rules to prevent this behavior. This kind of iterative adjustment is a hallmark of effective market design. Similarly, lessons from ranked-choice voting implementations – such as those in Alaska, Maine, and various municipalities – have shown that incomplete ballots can compromise results yet are an often-overlooked issue in elections that allow voters to list multiple preferences (Kilgour, Grègoire, and Foley 2020; Boudreau, Mathews, and Schwartz 2024).
The market design approach is pragmatic and problem-specific, similar to the clinical approach to poverty reduction policies in development (Sachs 2005). Solutions are tailored to specific problems: one country might require mosquito nets to combat malaria, while another needs debt relief. As market design adapts tools to the issue, successful programs are tested locally and broadly adopted if proven effective.
There are many other examples of market design in action. The Clean Air Act’s sulfur dioxide market, Uber’s redesign of ride-sharing markets, and Milgrom’s auction for milk products highlight the diverse applications of these principles. Market design is not static. It evolves as new problems and technologies emerge, with lab and field trials essential in refining theory and practice.
Experience also teaches us to account for real-world constraints. Alvin Roth’s work on organ donor matching (2016) provides a powerful example: given that monetary exchanges are not allowed, the mechanism must accommodate specific challenges like finding compatible donors and managing geographic and temporal constraints. Similarly, Roth (2008) described modifications to the National Resident Matching Program to address the needs of married medical school graduates who require placements in nearby hospitals. This constraint became more significant as more women entered the medical profession, illustrating how market design evolves to keep pace with societal changes.
Market design starts with broad goals. In spectrum auctions, the FCC wants to allocate the spectrum to those most effective at providing valuable communications services for consumers. In the residency match, hospitals and new doctors want efficient doctor assignments to hospitals. In wholesale electricity, the regulator seeks reliable electricity at the lowest cost.
Once a goal is established, an iterative process harnesses the scientific method of continuous improvement through design and experiment. From theory, promising trial mechanisms are identified. These designs are then tested in the laboratory or a low-stakes field environment. The mechanism is then rolled out, recognizing the importance of measuring and publicly reporting performance. Weaknesses are found, and improvements are developed. Proven designs are adopted more widely, geographically, and across sectors. Spectrum auctions, kidney exchanges, and electricity markets gradually improved, and adoption broadened over decades of continuous refinement.
Despite the success of market design, there are instances where not adopting the approach has led to failure. Troubled by high costs, Congress passed legislation requiring the Department of Health and Human Services (HHS) to use competitive bidding to price Medicare’s durable medical equipment. Cramton, Katzman, and Ellermeyer (2010) showed that HHS’s proposed auction design had fatal flaws. These flaws were confirmed experimentally (Merlob, Plott, and Zhang 2012). Nonetheless, HHS pushed forward with its flawed approach, and unsurprisingly, the identified flaws materialized in the field. Only after a costly failure and a ten-year delay did HHS begin to implement the recommendations of the market designers.
In the most challenging settings, even good market designs can fail. Texas’s winter storm Uri in February 2021 is an example. Sustained extreme cold produced an impossible gap between demand and supply, causing multi-day outages for one-quarter of Texans. The dollar cost exceeded $100 billion, and 262 Texans died. Despite having a best-practice wholesale electricity market design, it was vulnerable to extreme cold. The event highlighted the need for electricity markets globally to be resilient to extreme weather, which is becoming increasingly important with climate change and the transition to renewable electricity (Cramton 2022). The crisis has triggered design improvements that are gradually being adopted in markets globally (Cramton et al. 2025).
Market design is an iterative process that tailors mechanisms to specific problems and refines them based on empirical evidence and real-world constraints. By learning from successes and failures, we can better inform efforts to redesign complex systems, such as the one for electing the president of the United States.
4 Election Design
Long before Arrow’s (1950) impossibility theorem, a substantial body of literature explored the challenges of aggregating individual votes into collective social preferences. Market design principles become relevant because of the complex tradeoffs in crafting an effective electoral system. A critical debate is whether to judge an election system by how closely it mirrors an ideal or to take a more practical approach that weighs feasible alternatives on their merits. As Sen (2009) explains, in the context of social justice, the goal should be “comparative assessment and not merely identifying a transcendental ideal.” Arrow’s theorem undercuts any notion of measuring an election system against an unattainable ideal, leaving only practical, comparative assessments.
Electoral goals are many. Here, we outline some while acknowledging that the list is not exhaustive.
4.1 Legitimacy and Participation
Without voter participation, an election cannot have legitimacy. An effective electoral system should ensure that all votes matter – not just those in battleground states. One of the major flaws of the Electoral College is that it erodes voter engagement in non-competitive states, particularly given the winner-take-all method by which most states allocate their Electoral votes. For example, a California voter knows that even if his vote is decisive in the outcome of the national popular vote, it would have no impact on the outcome in the Electoral College since the Democrat will invariably win the state’s popular vote and therefore get the state’s electoral votes. Although the probability of any individual vote being decisive is always tiny with a large electorate, the difference between a slight chance and zero chance is vast regarding voter motivation.
4.2 Expression of Preferences
A well-designed election system should allow voters to express their rankings of candidates and the intensity of their preferences. This raises the question of whether voters should be able to trade their votes on issues or offices they care less about for more influence on ones they care more about. Suppose a voter is indifferent to presidential candidates but cares deeply about the gubernatorial race. Should the election mechanism allow them to trade their presidential vote for additional influence in the gubernatorial election? Vote trading aligns with market principles, where participants seek to maximize their utility across different dimensions. It is seen as log rolling in Congressional votes – “I’ll vote for your bill if you’ll vote for mine.” However, it is not the only way to express intensity.
4.3 Limiting Undue Influence
Monetary influence in elections, especially by wealthy donors, is contentious. Should individuals outside a particular jurisdiction be allowed to influence elections through financial contributions? Financial contributions to political parties or political action committees do just that. The funds are strategically spent throughout an election, especially during the campaign phase, to maximize their impact in critical districts, the battleground states for the presidential race, and state and district races where the money has the greatest impact per dollar spent. Undue influence is a concern in any electoral process. Election finance reform is one way to tackle the problem; voting rules are another.
4.4 Simplicity and Transparency
Like market design for matching doctors to hospitals or students to schools, election systems must be simple and transparent. Voters must understand the process and how best to express preferences within the system. A major lesson from redesigning the National Resident Matching Program and school choice mechanisms has been that simpler systems encourage greater trust and participation (Abdulkadiroğlu and Sönmez 2003; Roth and Peranson 1999). Spectrum auctions started with a simple design, then shifted to a more complex design to solve more challenging economic problems, but recently returned to simpler designs better suited for today (Cramton 2013).
4.5 Peaceful Transition of Power
A stable electoral system must facilitate a smooth and peaceful power transfer, the last step in an election. This is more likely to occur when the voting system and rules are viewed as fair, legitimate, and transparent. A smooth, peaceful transition of power is crucial for maintaining the integrity of the democratic process.
4.6 Flexibility for Future Adaptations
The electoral system must be adaptable to changing circumstances without making minorities susceptible to exploitation. Elections should not be assessed solely by discrepancies between the popular vote and the Electoral College; a comprehensive audit should consider factors like candidate selection, campaign incentives, and governance post-election. For example, ranked-choice voting is often praised for reducing negative campaigning, as candidates seek to be ranked highly, even if not first.
A market design approach to elections mirrors the lessons from spectrum auctions, electricity markets, and environmental policy. One such lesson is that short- and long-term incentives must be evaluated. Just as the design of electricity markets impacts the operation of existing resources and the long-run investment incentives in new resources, an election system must consider how rules influence participation, pre-election behavior – such as candidate platforms and campaign strategies – and post-election governance. Milgrom’s work on the knapsack auction (2017) offers a helpful metaphor: just as climbers must choose which gear to buy based on auction prices for Sherpas’ carrying capacity, political actors make strategic decisions based on the incentives embedded in electoral rules.
5 Prioritizing Goals
In designing elections, some tradeoffs are unavoidable. For instance, Condorcet consistency, where the candidate preferred by a majority wins, and responsiveness to voter intensity, as seen in quadratic voting, are mutually exclusive (Nitzan and Nitzan 2024). In a scenario where 51 out of 100 voters prefer Candidate A but with lukewarm enthusiasm, and 49 voters strongly prefer Candidate B, a Condorcet consistent system would elect A. However, a system like quadratic voting, which allows voters to weigh their preferences more heavily at some cost, might result in B winning. Decisions about which goal to prioritize – majority rule or preference intensity – are central to designing a fair and effective electoral system.
Ultimately, the design of an electoral system must weigh all tradeoffs and allow for a continuous process of refinement and adaptation, learning from past implementations and evolving political, social, and technological contexts.
6 Alternative Voting Rules
We now discuss voting rules tested in smaller settings to determine which components merit consideration. These are fledgling examples of change that could greatly benefit from a market design approach.
6.1 Ranked-Choice Voting
Ranked-choice voting has been implemented in many settings,[1] including its use in Alaska and Maine, but its full effects are yet to be realized, perhaps due to inertia and voters, candidates, and parties taking time to learn the system. For instance, despite Alaska’s adoption of ranked-choice voting, voters and parties in the state are stuck in a two-party mindset.
Under Alaska’s ranked-choice voting rules for electing statewide offices, there is first an open primary in which voters can cast a single vote for any candidate of their choosing. The top four candidates in this open primary compete in a general election where voters can order the candidates as their first, second, third, and fourth choice. If a candidate is ranked first by over 50 percent of voters, they win. If no candidate achieves this threshold, the candidate with the fewest votes is dropped from the ballot, and votes are recounted to see if any remaining candidates achieve majority support. Regardless of the submitted ballots, this iterative process will eventually result in a winner being elected with a majority. Part of the appeal of this system is that it undermines the argument that a vote for a third candidate is a wasted vote that could tip an election to a voter’s least desired option; for example, “a vote for Ralph Nader is a vote for George Bush since it takes a vote away from Al Gore.”
In Alaska’s 2022 special election to fill a vacant US House seat – the first election after Alaska adopted ranked-choice voting – the four individuals who advanced in the primary were Nick Begich III (Republican), Al Gross (Independent), Sarah Palin (Republican), and Mary Peltola (Democrat). Al Gross withdrew before the general election and endorsed Peltola. This was a highly anticipated and essential election involving three candidates with great statewide name recognition. One would think that most voters would have a clear, ordered preference over the three, yet of the 192,289 ballots submitted in the general election, over 26 percent of the ballots included votes for only one candidate. Only Palin was named by 20,199 voters – no preference was expressed between Begich and Peltola.
In the 2024 primary for this same seat, incumbent Mary Peltola received 50.9 percent of the votes. Nick Begich III (Republican) came in second with 26.6 percent, Nancy Dahlstrom (Republican) came in third with 19.9 percent, and Matthew Salisbury (Republican) came in fourth with 0.6 percent. Illustrating how Alaska politicians/parties seem stuck in a two-party mindset, Dahlstrom and Salisbury have withdrawn from the general election, presumably not to siphon Begich’s support. Even with ranked-choice voting, the November vote was a mainstream Democrat against a mainstream Republican. This illustrates how rule changes may not lead to immediate voter or candidate behavior shifts. As another broad example, women gained the right to vote in 1920, but only recently has a substantial share of women been elected to Congress and none to the presidency.
Ranked-choice voting can enhance legitimacy and participation by ensuring the winner has broader support and reducing voter apathy, particularly for those supporting third parties. It also allows for a more accurate expression of preferences by letting voters rank candidates, minimizing the impact of vote-splitting. It can limit undue influence by encouraging candidates to appeal to a broader audience. The latter effect could lessen the impact of negative campaigning and special interests. At the same time, the system may appear more complex, which undermines simplicity and transparency. Voters may be unsure or unconvinced of how to submit their rankings. While ranked-choice voting promises more flexibility of expression, it may take the electorate time to adapt to new rules.
6.2 Quadratic Voting and Storable Votes
An essential criticism of majority rule is the “tyranny of the majority.” Quadratic voting offers one potential solution: voters can express the intensity of their preferences in a way that reduces the outsized influence of wealthy individuals. Instead of a linear influence system – where more money or votes equals more power – quadratic voting ensures that the louder you shout, the less additional influence you gain. Voters each begin with a fixed number of votes that they can distribute across different options, and the cost of each additional vote for a given option increases quadratically (one vote costs one unit, two votes cost four units, three votes cost nine units, etc.). This allows voters to show stronger support for issues they care more about but prevents a few individuals from overpowering others because the cost of expressing intensity grows rapidly. This method can be implemented with or without money. While it may not be a perfect system, it encourages new thinking beyond the usual debate of the popular vote versus the Electoral College (Lalley and Weyl 2018).
A related innovation is storable votes, where voters can “save” their votes in elections or issues they care less about to “spend” them on issues or elections where they are more passionate (Casella 2012). As with quadratic voting, this allows voters to concentrate their influence on outcomes that matter most to them, allowing them to express preference intensity without introducing financial barriers.
Both approaches provide voters more freedom to express the intensity of their preferences and address undue influence by limiting the impact of small but passionate minorities. Perhaps to an even greater extent than ranked-choice voting, these methods also introduce complexity that could challenge simplicity and transparency. Regarding how voters allocate their voting budgets, the mathematical and strategic aspects of quadratic voting and storable votes might be challenging for some to understand and trust. As in the case of ranked-choice voting, that confusion could complicate the peaceful transition of power in contested elections, and the even greater departure from traditional voting methods could lead to an even larger variety of unforeseen and unintended consequences.
6.3 Approval Voting
Approval voting, a voting system popular with voting theorists (Laslier 2012), allows voters to approve or disapprove of as many candidates as they like. The candidate with the highest number of approvals wins. This system has several potential advantages: it can reduce negative campaigning, prevent the spoiler effect, and increase voter participation (Brams and Herschbach 2001; Brams and Fishburn 1978). Approval voting is simpler and easier to understand than ranked-choice voting, an essential consideration for electoral design.
The majority judgment concept proposed by Balinski and Laraki (2007) is related to approval voting. Majority judgment is a voting system where voters grade each candidate on a scale (e.g., A, B, C…, or “Excellent,” “Good,” “Fair,” …rather than “approve” or “disapprove”), and the candidate with the highest median grade wins. This guarantees that at least half of those submitting scores agree the candidate’s grade should be no lower while at the same time allowing for some expression of the intensity of voter preferences. It addresses some issues with strategic voting by allowing voters to express detailed judgments about each candidate rather than forcing them to rank or pick only one. As argued in their book (Balinski and Laraki 2011), this system avoids many Arrow-type impossibilities by focusing on grades for each candidate rather than rankings based only on ordinal preferences.
Both systems allow voters to express preferences more freely than in single-vote elections, though not to the extent of ranked-choice or quadratic voting. They can increase participation by encouraging voters to support candidates they genuinely like without fear of wasting their votes. Both are relatively straightforward, particularly approval voting, enhancing simplicity and transparency and potentially making future adaptations more straightforward. Despite their strengths, however, these systems do not explicitly address undue influence, as high-profile candidates with greater resources may still dominate. Public disagreement over the granularity or other aspects of a specific grading system could also impede the transition of power in the case of majority judgment.
7 More Drastic Changes
7.1 Compulsory Voting
One proposal to address low voter turnout is compulsory voting, as practiced in Australia. This encourages universal voter participation, but there are significant objections. Critics argue that it infringes on personal freedom and the right to abstain and may lead to less meaningful involvement. Still, it could address issues such as determining a “true” Condorcet winner by maximizing voter turnout. While there are disadvantages, it remains a direct solution to voter disengagement.
7.2 Beyond Geographic Divisions
Historically, elections have been structured around geographical boundaries – states, counties, and precincts – due to the logistical challenges of travel and communication. In the 19th century, for instance, it took Abraham Lincoln two weeks to travel from Chicago to New York City due to disconnected railroads and slow transport (Gordon 2016). Geographic divisions made sense when most cities were no larger than a few miles in diameter, but today, technology has drastically reduced these barriers.
Landsburg (2007) proposed a radical idea: Congressional districts based not on geography but on last names. He argues, “It’s easy to invent a project that transfers income to a particular region, but much trickier to concoct a scheme that transfers income precisely to those whose names happen to begin with Q” (Landsburg 2007, page 76). Special interests lobbying for a massive rail infrastructure project are among the many vivid examples. The jurisdiction benefits from the jobs building the project irrespective of the rail’s benefit to society, as in California’s Central Valley highspeed rail and the coastal rail south of San Clemente. In an age where people identify along various non-geographic lines – such as religious, environmental, or political affiliations – relying solely on geographic divisions seems increasingly outdated.
Congressional districts based on characteristics like last names rather than geography could advance the goal of limiting undue influence by making it harder for politicians to cater to specific local interests and encouraging broader, issue-based platforms. However, such a change may hinder participation and legitimacy if voters feel less connected to a representative chosen based on an arbitrary characteristic rather than a common geographic or community interest.
7.3 Aggregating Votes Across Interests
Another idea is to let people split their votes among different interest groups – such as unions, environmental groups, or religious organizations – based on their passions and priorities. This would allow voters to direct their influence toward the issues they care most about. While an individual vote may not carry much weight, aggregations of votes could shape national policies by reflecting more nuanced voter preferences.
8 Modernizing the Voting System
With modern technology, it is possible to design a voting system that is both secure and sophisticated. Today, even people experiencing homelessness often have access to the internet and cell phones. If financial institutions can securely protect millions of individual accounts, we could develop a system that protects the integrity of a more modern and complex voting system. As suggested by some voting theorists, transparency and accuracy are the top priorities. In that case, we should have room to innovate beyond a simple one-person, one-vote system within local jurisdictions.
However, more radical innovations might be limited if transparency and audibility are deemed more important than other goals. Our current system reflects the importance of continuity with past elections and the ability to transparently double-check the accuracy of vote counts. Shifting priorities away from this may open the door to more advanced and responsive voting systems.
9 Conclusions
The 2024 Presidential election temporarily turned a bubbling-over crisis into a more slow-burning situation. Still, citizens understand that the status quo of presidential elections leaves much room for improvement. Simply going from the Electoral College to the Popular Vote is undesirable if smaller states would be made worse off and would not be on board with a constitutional amendment. However, the market design approach that we have described provides a pragmatic way forward. Although existing theoretical and empirical work has not identified a definitive choice, promising alternatives exist, and we summarize some of them here with the understanding that the best opportunity for fixing the presidential election is to first experiment with these election designs at the state and local levels.
Ranked choice voting is already being tested, and expanded testing would be easily implemented. It is a strong option because it allows voters to express their preferences over candidates more fully and may, in time, lead to less polarizing candidates who must compete to be favored by voters as – if not their top choice – a second or third choice. For example, Maine adopted a version of rank-choice voting that was first used in the November 2018 US House elections. Alaska also has been using ranked-choice-voting, beginning with the August 2022 special election for the US House after the death of Republican incumbent Don Young. Further experimentation is on the horizon, as evidenced by Colorado, Idaho, Nevada, Oregon, and Washington, DC, offering referenda to do so on their November 2024 ballots.
However, ranked-choice voting is not a single process; there are many ways in which it can be implemented. Should candidate elimination be based on the fewest first-place votes, as in Alaska and Maine, or by the fewest total votes, as recommended by Foley and Maskin (2022)? This is an important detail in implementing ranked-choice voting: it may lead to drastic differences in how voters choose to rank their opponents on their ballots, how candidates position themselves in the race, and ultimately, who wins the election. For example, elimination by the fewest first-place votes is usually called “instant runoff” or a Hare system. It can eliminate a Condorcet winner, while eliminating by the fewest total votes is known as “Borda’s Elimination Rule” and never eliminates a Condorcet winner. For more on these and other voting rules and how they sometimes perform poorly, see Felsenthal and Nurmi (2019).
Other important rules within ranked-choice voting that need to be vetted are whether to require strict rankings or allow for tied rankings and whether or how to treat partial rankings in the elimination procedures. Open versus closed primaries can also impact the election. State elections provide the perfect opportunity to experiment with election rules. At the same time, metrics for election performance, such as voter turnout and voter satisfaction, can be worked out to see which version works most effectively and to make appropriate adjustments to improve the process.
Alaska in 2024 provides a cautionary tale concerning market design’s iterative improvement process. Their ballot included a proposition to revert from ranked-choice voting to the previous popular vote rule. In the end, ranked-choice voting survived by the narrowest of margins. However, the instinct to discard rather than improve experimental changes is concerning. We should not expect the first iteration of a new voting rule to be perfect but as a step towards a better system.
However, Alaska’s experimentation with ranked-choice voting highlights our final point: experimentation at local and state levels could not only provide benefits to the stakeholders in those elections, but the benefits should filter up to state and national levels in several ways. This includes potential changes in Democrat and Republican primaries. Currently, both parties have convoluted primary structures likely resulting from party “elders” wanting to have control over nominees. Much like passing a Constitutional Amendment, convincing party elders to relinquish their power will likely be a daunting obstacle to reform.
Currently, the Democrats allocate convention delegates to states half based on each state’s contribution to electors in the Electoral College and half based on what percentage of Democrat voters live there. That means California gets more delegates than is in proportion to their Electoral College representation. Some view Californians as being more progressive on many issues and pushing the party to nominate a more progressive candidate. Republicans have a similar system, although it awards delegates based on Gubernatorial and legislative control by Republicans in the state rather than by the percentage of Republican voters in that state. Having elected a Republican Governor, US Senators, or a majority of US House seats. Thus, solid red states push more conservative candidates.
These primary processes result in the country having highly polarized candidates. The moderates in the middle feel ignored. Most presidential nominees appeal to a broad swath of party members in the primaries and take positions left/right of center. However, once they become the party nominee, they must tack back to the middle to appeal to the general electorate, and this turns off many voters who get tired of these political machinations and view them as flip-flopping or downright lying. A primary system that produces a more centrist candidate in the first place would alleviate this problem for both parties.
This is the opposite of what makes sense for the parties. Parties should seek to nominate candidates who thrive in more middle-of-the-road swing states. Instead, under the current primary systems, more extreme candidates are nominated, requiring massive amounts of money to be spent trying to trick swing-state voters into believing that the extreme candidates are centrists.
Better-designed elections, whether at the local, state, or primary levels, have two potential benefits. First, what is learned at lower levels can be applied and further refined at higher levels. Second, if election rules emerge that elect more broadly appealing candidates, then we should start to see more broadly appealing candidates elevated to the state and national levels, and the investment locally will pay dividends more broadly over time.
We have recommended several possible election formats as a starting point, but our list is not exhaustive. Efforts should be part of an ongoing process involving public comment, experience, and experimentation to determine what works and what does not. The debate should be much broader and more thoughtful than whether to replace the Electoral College with a popular vote. The nation needs an electoral system that can evolve to represent voters’ interests best and reflect our societal changes. We propose that such a system be developed using a market design approach.
Funding source: German Science Foundation
Award Identifier / Grant number: EXC 2126/1 390838866
References
Abdulkadiroğlu, A., and T. Sönmez. 2003. “School Choice: A Mechanism Design Approach.” The American Economic Review 93 (3): 729–47. https://doi.org/10.1257/000282803322157061.Search in Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. 1950. “A Difficulty in the Concept of Social Welfare.” Journal of Political Economy 58 (4): 328–46. https://doi.org/10.1086/256963.Search in Google Scholar
Balinski, M., and R. Laraki. 2007. “A Theory of Measuring, Electing, and Ranking.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 104 (21): 8720–5. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0702634104.Search in Google Scholar
Balinski, M., and R. Laraki. 2011. Majority Judgment: Measuring, Ranking, and Electing. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press.10.7551/mitpress/9780262015134.001.0001Search in Google Scholar
Boudreau, J. W., T. M. Mathews, and J. A. Schwartz. 2024. “Incomplete Ballots and Condorcet Consistency.” Working Paper.Search in Google Scholar
Brams, S. J., and P. C. Fishburn. 1978. “Approval Voting.” American Political Science Review 72 (3): 831–47. https://doi.org/10.2307/1955105.Search in Google Scholar
Brams, S. J., and R. D. Herschbach. 2001. “The Science of Elections.” Science 292: 1449. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.292.5521.1449.Search in Google Scholar
Burnett, C. M., and V. Kogan. 2015. “Ballot (and Voter) ‘Exhaustion’ Under Instant Runoff Voting: An Examination of Four Ranked-Choice Elections.” Electoral Studies 37: 41–9. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.electstud.2014.11.006.Search in Google Scholar
Casella, A. 2012. Storable Votes: Protecting the Minority Voice. Oxford: Oxford University Press.10.1093/acprof:oso/9780195309096.001.0001Search in Google Scholar
Cramton, P. 2013. “Spectrum Auction Design.” Review of Industrial Organization 42 (2). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-013-9376-x.Search in Google Scholar
Cramton, P. 2022. “Fostering Resiliency with Good Market Design: Lessons from Texas.” University of Maryland Working Paper.10.1049/icp.2021.2601Search in Google Scholar
Cramton, P., and J. A. Schwartz. 2000. “Collusive Bidding: Lessons from the FCC Spectrum Auctions.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 17 (3): 229–52. https://doi.org/10.1023/a:1008174031940.10.1023/A:1008174031940Search in Google Scholar
Cramton, P., B. Katzman, and S. Ellermeyer. 2010. “Designed to Fail: The Medicare Auction for Durable Medical Equipment.” Economic Inquiry 53 (1): 469–85. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecin.12101.Search in Google Scholar
Cramton, P., S. Brandkamp, H. Chao, J. Dark, D. Hoy, A. S. Kyle, et al.. 2025. “A Forward Energy Market to Improve Reliability and Resiliency.” University of Maryland Working Paper.Search in Google Scholar
Felsenthal, D. S., and H. Nurmi. 2019. Voting Procedures Under a Restricted Domain: An Examination of the (In) Vulnerability of 20 Voting Procedures to Five Main Paradoxes. Cham: Springer.10.1007/978-3-030-12627-8Search in Google Scholar
Foley, E. B. 2023. “Total Vote Runoff: A Majority-Maximizing Form of Ranked-Choice Voting.” New Hampshire Law Review 21 (2): 323–67.10.2139/ssrn.4328946Search in Google Scholar
Foley, E. B., and E. S. Maskin. 2022. “Alaska’s Ranked-Choice Voting is Flawed. But There’s an Easy Fix.” Washington Post, November 1.Search in Google Scholar
Gordon, R. J. 2016. The Rise and Fall of American Growth. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Search in Google Scholar
Kilgour, M. D., J. C. Grègoire, and A. M. Foley. 2020. “The Prevalence and Consequences of Ballot Truncation in Ranked-Choice Elections.” Public Choice 184 (1–2): 197–218. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00723-2.Search in Google Scholar
Lalley, S. P., and E. G. Weyl. 2018. “Quadratic Voting: How Mechanism Design Can Radicalize Democracy.” The American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings 108: 33–7. https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20181002.Search in Google Scholar
Landsburg, S. E. 2007. More Sex is Safer Sex: The Unconventional Wisdom of Economics. New York: Free Press.Search in Google Scholar
Laslier, J. F. 2012. “And the Loser is … Plurality Voting.” In Electoral Systems: Studies in Choice and Welfare, edited by D. Felsenthal, and M. Machover, 327–51. Berlin: Springer.10.1007/978-3-642-20441-8_13Search in Google Scholar
McMillan, J. 1994. “Selling Spectrum Rights.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 8 (3): 145–62. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.8.3.145.Search in Google Scholar
Merlob, B., C. Plott, and J. Zhang. 2012. “The CMS Auction: Experimental Studies of a Median-Bid Procurement Auction with Nonbinding Bids.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 127 (2): 793–828. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjs013.Search in Google Scholar
Milgrom, P. 2017. Discovering Prices. New York: Columbia University Press.10.7312/milg17598Search in Google Scholar
Nitzan, A. D. M., and S. I. Nitzan. 2024. “Balancing Democracy: Majoritarianism Versus Expression of Preference Intensity.” Public Choice 200 (1–2): 149–71. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-024-01146-4.Search in Google Scholar
Roth, A. E. 2008. “Deferred Acceptance Algorithms: History, Theory, Practice, and Open Questions.” International Journal of Game Theory 36: 537–69. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00182-008-0117-6.Search in Google Scholar
Roth, A. E. 2016. Who Gets What – And Why. New York: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt Publishing Company.Search in Google Scholar
Roth, A. E., and E. Peranson. 1999. “The Redesign of the Matching Market for American Physicians: Some Engineering Aspects of Economic Design.” The American Economic Review 89 (4): 748–80. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.89.4.748.Search in Google Scholar
Sachs, J. D. 2005. The End of Poverty. New York: The Penguin Press.Search in Google Scholar
Sen, A. 2009. The Idea of Justice. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.10.4159/9780674054578Search in Google Scholar
Tait, R. 2024. “Tim Walz Calls for Scrapping of Electoral College to Decide US Presidential Race.” The Guardian, October 9. https://www.theguardian.com/us-news/2024/oct/09/election-tim-walz-electoral-college.Search in Google Scholar
© 2025 the author(s), published by De Gruyter, Berlin/Boston
This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Editorial
- Editorial: Bureaucracy, Regulation and Deregulation
- Policy Papers (No Special Focus)
- Using Market Design to Reform the US Electoral College
- Financial Stability and Monetary Policy Autonomy in Japan. Should Japan Peg the Yen to the Dollar?
- The Present Monetary Policy Framework is Seriously Flawed
- On the Reform of Fiscal Rules in the European Union: What Has Been Achieved, and How Did We Get Here?
- Efficacy of Economic Sanctions on Imposing Costs to State-Owned Enterprises: The Case of Iran
- Policy Forum: Bureaucracy, Regulation and Deregulation
- “The Report of My Death was an Exaggeration”: Business Dynamism in the United States
- Balancing Power: The Impact of Legislative Structure on Sunset Laws and Administrative Procedure Acts
- When Less Means More: Policy Accumulation, Administrative Capacities, and Policy Performance
- Lost Economic Output due to High Bureaucratic Burden: The Case for Germany
- Regulation and Income Mobility
- A 3D Look at Argentina: Deregulation, Dollarization, Deflation
- Taxonomy Disclosure in the EU – A Useful Framework, Despite Current Challenges
- Comment on “EU Taxonomy: Mission Impossible” by Kooths (2023)
- Reply to Comment on “EU Taxonomy: Mission Impossible”
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Editorial
- Editorial: Bureaucracy, Regulation and Deregulation
- Policy Papers (No Special Focus)
- Using Market Design to Reform the US Electoral College
- Financial Stability and Monetary Policy Autonomy in Japan. Should Japan Peg the Yen to the Dollar?
- The Present Monetary Policy Framework is Seriously Flawed
- On the Reform of Fiscal Rules in the European Union: What Has Been Achieved, and How Did We Get Here?
- Efficacy of Economic Sanctions on Imposing Costs to State-Owned Enterprises: The Case of Iran
- Policy Forum: Bureaucracy, Regulation and Deregulation
- “The Report of My Death was an Exaggeration”: Business Dynamism in the United States
- Balancing Power: The Impact of Legislative Structure on Sunset Laws and Administrative Procedure Acts
- When Less Means More: Policy Accumulation, Administrative Capacities, and Policy Performance
- Lost Economic Output due to High Bureaucratic Burden: The Case for Germany
- Regulation and Income Mobility
- A 3D Look at Argentina: Deregulation, Dollarization, Deflation
- Taxonomy Disclosure in the EU – A Useful Framework, Despite Current Challenges
- Comment on “EU Taxonomy: Mission Impossible” by Kooths (2023)
- Reply to Comment on “EU Taxonomy: Mission Impossible”