Abstract
This paper analyzes the Ak model with anticipated future consumption. In the model with internal anticipation individual’s utility depends on current consumption and a forward-looking reference level which is formed from individual’s own future consumption. The global dynamics of the economy is characterized by means of a qualitative phase diagram analysis. In the model with external anticipation the consumption reference level is formed from economy-wide average future consumption, which is taken as given by individuals and causes the competitive equilibrium to be inefficient. Characterizing the global dynamics of the economy is required to characterize an optimal fiscal policy that corrects the inefficiency brought about by this external effect.
Funding source: MCIN/AEI/10.13039/501100011033
Award Identifier / Grant number: PID2021-127599NB-I00
Funding source: European Regional Development Fund A way of making Europe
Award Identifier / Grant number: PID2021-127599NB-I00
Acknowledgments
I gratefully acknowledge the helpful comments of an anonymous referee. Grant PID2021-127599NB-I00 funded by MCIN/AEI/10.13039/501100011033 and by “ERDF A way of making Europe”.
Appendix A: The Condition
sign
det
H
u
(
c
,
1
)
=
constant
To give an intuition on the meaning of condition P#6, let us note definition (14),
so −π(c) is the slope of the indifference curves of u depicted in the (A, C)–plane, and its absolute value is the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) of A for C. Differentiating π(c) we obtain
so that
We have that
Hence, the convexity of the indifference curves can be studied from
where P#3 entails that c + π(c) > 0, so
If u
A
> 0, so both C and A are ‘goods’, the indifference curves are downward sloping and strictly convex (resp., concave) if π′(c) > 0 (resp., π′(c) < 0), and so, an increase in C, keeping A constant, causes the indifference curves to become steeper (flatter), and an increase in A, keeping C constant, causes the indifference curves to become flatter (steeper). If u
A
< 0, so A is a bad, the indifference curves are upward sloping and strictly concave (resp., convex) if π′(c) < 0 (resp., π′(c) > 0), and so, an increase in C, keeping A constant, causes the indifference curves to become flatter (steeper), and an increase in A, keeping C constant, causes the indifference curves to become steeper (flatter). Thus, the higher is the value of C, the higher is the increase in C needed to compensate a given increase in A to keep utility constant. Hence, the more meaningful situation seems to be that π′(c) > 0 if u
A
> 0 and π′(c) < 0 if u
A
< 0. The assumption P#6 that
To illustrate the former discussion, let us consider the CES utility function
which tends to the additive specification
as ϕ → 1, and to the multiplicative specification
as ϕ → 0. This specification implies that
and so,
Appendix B: Dynamics of the Centrally Planned Economy
From (6) we have that
Using that
Log-differentiating (B.1), after simplification we get
Now, using (3) and (7) and the homogeneity of degree −v of u C , we can obtain that
where σ(c) is defined in (13). From
Appendix C: Dynamics of the Market Economy with Government
The agent maximizes her utility (1) subject to the budget constraint (27), taking as given
where λ D is the shadow value of capital. The first-order conditions for an interior optimum, which are also sufficient, are
together with the initial condition, K(0) = K 0, and the usual transversality condition lim t→∞e−βt λ D K = 0. From (27) and (28), we get the resources’ constraint
In what follows we will use that
Denoting c ≡ C/A and a ≡ A/K, and using the homogeneity of degree −v of u C , this equation can be rewritten as
where σ(c) is defined in (13).
From
References
Abel, A. B. 1990. “Asset Prices Under Habit Formation and Catching Up with the Joneses.” The American Economic Review 80 (2): 38–42.10.3386/w3279Suche in Google Scholar
Bambi, M., and F. Gozzi. 2020. “Internal Habits Formation and Optimality.” Journal of Mathematical Economics 91: 165–72. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmateco.2020.09.008.Suche in Google Scholar
Baucells, M., and S. Bellezza. 2016. “Temporal Profiles of Instant Utility During Anticipation, Event, and Recall.” Management Science 63 (3): 729–48. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2015.2362.Suche in Google Scholar
Becker, G. S., and K. M. Murphy. 1988. “A Theory of Rational Addiction.” Journal of Political Economy 96 (4): 675–700. https://doi.org/10.1086/261558.Suche in Google Scholar
Caplin, A., and J. Leahy. 2001. “Psychological Expected Utility Theory and Anticipatory Feelings.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 116 (1): 55–79. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355301556347.Suche in Google Scholar
Carroll, C. D., J. Overland, and D. N. Weil. 1997. “Comparison Utility in a Growth Model.” Journal of Economic Growth 2 (4): 339–67. https://doi.org/10.1023/a:1009740920294 10.3386/w6138Suche in Google Scholar
Carroll, C. D., J. Overland, and D. N. Weil. 2000. “Saving and Growth with Habit Formation.” The American Economic Review 90 (3): 341–55. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.3.341.Suche in Google Scholar
Chatterjee, B., R. Escobar-Posada, and G. Monteiro. 2023. “Anticipation in Leisure – Effects on Labor-Leisure Choice.” International Journal of Economic Theory 19 (2): 384–412. https://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12358.Suche in Google Scholar
Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbaum, and C. L. Evans. 2005. “Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy.” Journal of Political Economy 113 (1): 1–45. https://doi.org/10.1086/426038.Suche in Google Scholar
Chun, H. H., K. Diehl, and D. J. MacInnis. 2017. “Savoring an Upcoming Experience Affects Ongoing and Remembered Consumption Enjoyment.” Journal of Marketing 81 (3): 96–110. https://doi.org/10.1509/jm.15.0267.Suche in Google Scholar
Constantinides, G. M. 1990. “Habit Formation: A Resolution of the Equity Premium Puzzle.” Journal of Political Economy 98 (3): 519–43. https://doi.org/10.1086/261693.Suche in Google Scholar
Faria, J. R., and P. McAdam. 2013. “Anticipation of Future Consumption: A Monetary Perspective.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 45 (2–3): 423–47. https://doi.org/10.1111/jmcb.12008.Suche in Google Scholar
Faria, J. R., and P. McAdam. 2018. “The Green Golden Rule: Habit and Anticipation of Future Consumption.” Economics Letters 172: 131–3. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2018.08.026.Suche in Google Scholar
Fuhrer, J. C. 2000. “Habit Formation in Consumption and its Implications for Monetary-Policy Models.” The American Economic Review 90 (3): 367–90. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.3.367.Suche in Google Scholar
Gilovich, T., A. Kumar, and L. Jampol. 2015. “A Wonderful Life: Experiential Consumption and the Pursuit of Happiness.” Journal of Consumer Psychology 25 (1): 152–65. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcps.2014.08.004.Suche in Google Scholar
Gómez, M. A. 2008. “Convergence Speed in the Ak Endogenous Growth Model with Habit Formation.” Economics Letters 100 (1): 16–21. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2007.10.022.Suche in Google Scholar
Gómez, M. A. 2021. “On the Closed-Form Solution of an Endogenous Growth Model with Anticipated Consumption.” Journal of Mathematical Economics 95: 102471. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmateco.2021.102471.Suche in Google Scholar
Gómez, M. A. 2022. “The Good, the Bad and the Worse: Current, Past and Future Consumption Externalities and Equilibrium Efficiency.” Journal of Economics 137: 195–228. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-022-00788-6.Suche in Google Scholar
Gómez, M. A., and G. Monteiro. 2022. “Anticipated Future Consumption in an Endogenous Growth Model.” Macroeconomic Dynamics 26 (5): 1202–38. https://doi.org/10.1017/s136510052000053x.Suche in Google Scholar
Guo, L. 2020. “Anticipatory Consumptions.” Management Science 66 (8): 3717–34. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2019.3367.Suche in Google Scholar
Hardisty, D. J., and E. U. Weber. 2020. “Impatience and Savoring vs. Dread: Asymmetries in Anticipation Explain Consumer Time Preferences for Positive vs. Negative Events.” Journal of Consumer Psychology 30 (4): 598–613. https://doi.org/10.1002/jcpy.1169.Suche in Google Scholar
Harris, C. R. 2012. “Feelings of Dread and Intertemporal Choice.” Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 25 (1): 13–28. https://doi.org/10.1002/bdm.709.Suche in Google Scholar
He, Y., J. S. Dyer, and J. C. Butler. 2019. “A Decision-Making Model with Utility from Anticipation and Disappointment.” Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis 26 (1–2): 35–50. https://doi.org/10.1002/mcda.1657.Suche in Google Scholar
Kőszegi, B. 2006. “Emotional Agency.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 121 (1): 121–55. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355306776083554.Suche in Google Scholar
Köszegi, B., and M. Rabin. 2006. “A Model of Reference-Dependent Preferences.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 121 (4): 1133–65. https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.121.4.1133.Suche in Google Scholar
Köszegi, B., and M. Rabin. 2007. “Reference-Dependent Risk Attitudes.” The American Economic Review 97 (4): 1047–73. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.97.4.1047.Suche in Google Scholar
Kumar, A., M. A. Killingsworth, and T. Gilovich. 2014. “Waiting for Merlot: Anticipatory Consumption of Experiential and Material Purchases.” Psychological Science 25 (10): 1924–31. https://doi.org/10.1177/0956797614546556.Suche in Google Scholar
Kuznitz, A., S. Kandel, and V. Fos. 2008. “A Portfolio Choice Model with Utility from Anticipation of Future Consumption and Stock Market Mean Reversion.” European Economic Review 52 (8): 1338–52. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2008.07.002.Suche in Google Scholar
Leitmann, G. 1981. “The Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control.” In Mathematical Concepts and Methods in Science and Engineering, Vol. 24. New York: Springer Science+Business Media.10.1007/978-1-4899-0333-4Suche in Google Scholar
Loewenstein, G. 1987. “Anticipation and the Valuation of Delayed Consumption.” Economic Journal 97 (387): 666–84. https://doi.org/10.2307/2232929.Suche in Google Scholar
Loewenstein, G., and J. Elster, eds. 1992. Choice Over Time. New York: Rusell Sage Foundation.Suche in Google Scholar
Monteiro, G., and S. J. Turnovsky. 2016. “Anticipated Consumption and its Impact on Capital Accumulation and Growth: ‘Forward-Looking’ vs. ‘Backward-Looking’ Consumption Reference.” International Journal of Economic Theory 12 (3): 203–32. https://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12091.Suche in Google Scholar
Mukherjee, A., R. Smith, and S. Burton. 2023. “The Effect of Positive Anticipatory Utility on Product Pre-Order Evaluations and Choices.” Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science 51 (3): 551–69, https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-021-00810-1.Suche in Google Scholar
Nowlis, S. M., N. Mandel, and D. B. McCabe. 2004. “The Effect of a Delay Between Choice and Consumption on Consumption Enjoyment.” Journal of Consumer Research 31 (3): 502–10. https://doi.org/10.1086/425085.Suche in Google Scholar
Smets, F., and R. Wouters. 2003. “An Estimated Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model of the Euro Area.” Journal of the European Economic Association 1 (5): 1123–75. https://doi.org/10.1162/154247603770383415.Suche in Google Scholar
Van Boven, L., and L. Ashworth. 2007. “Looking Forward, Looking Back: Anticipation is More Evocative than Retrospection.” Journal of Experimental Psychology: General 136 (2): 289–300. https://doi.org/10.1037/0096-3445.136.2.289.Suche in Google Scholar
Wang, X. T. X., P. Wang, J. Lu, J. Zhou, G. Li, and S. Garelik. 2022. “Episodic Future Thinking and Anticipatory Emotions: Effects on Delay Discounting and Preventive Behaviors During Covid-19.” Applied Psychology: Health and Well-Being 14 (3): 842–61. https://doi.org/10.1111/aphw.12350.Suche in Google Scholar
© 2024 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Frontmatter
- Research Articles
- Global Dynamics and Optimal Policy in the Ak Model with Anticipated Future Consumption
- Offsetting Distortion Effects of Head Starts on Incentives in Tullock Contests
- Collusive Price Leadership Among Firms with Different Discount Factors
- Motivating Loyal Bureaucrats in Sequential Agency
- Disclosure of Product Information After Price Competition
- Uncertain Commitment Power in a Durable Good Monopoly
- Optimal Trade Policy in a Ricardian Model with Labor-Market Search-and-Matching Frictions
- Consumer-Benefiting Transport Costs: The Role of Product Innovation in a Vertical Structure
- Information Disclosure by Informed Intermediary in Double Auction
- Notes
- Strategic Partial Inattention in Oligopoly
- The Role of Informative Advertising in Aligning Preferences Over Product Design
- To Bequeath, or Not to Bequeath? On Labour Income Risk and Top Wealth Concentration
Artikel in diesem Heft
- Frontmatter
- Research Articles
- Global Dynamics and Optimal Policy in the Ak Model with Anticipated Future Consumption
- Offsetting Distortion Effects of Head Starts on Incentives in Tullock Contests
- Collusive Price Leadership Among Firms with Different Discount Factors
- Motivating Loyal Bureaucrats in Sequential Agency
- Disclosure of Product Information After Price Competition
- Uncertain Commitment Power in a Durable Good Monopoly
- Optimal Trade Policy in a Ricardian Model with Labor-Market Search-and-Matching Frictions
- Consumer-Benefiting Transport Costs: The Role of Product Innovation in a Vertical Structure
- Information Disclosure by Informed Intermediary in Double Auction
- Notes
- Strategic Partial Inattention in Oligopoly
- The Role of Informative Advertising in Aligning Preferences Over Product Design
- To Bequeath, or Not to Bequeath? On Labour Income Risk and Top Wealth Concentration