Abstract
This paper combines ideas from models of electoral competition with forward-looking voters and models of electoral competition with backward-looking voters. Two political parties can commit in advance to policy platforms, but not to a maximum level of rent extraction. In the case without uncertainty, the electorate can limit rents to the same extent as in a purely backward-looking model of accountability, and the policy preferred by the voter who represents the median preferences of the electorate is implemented. In the case with uncertainty about the bliss point of the representative voter, the electorate has to accept higher rent seeking by the incumbent politician, but nonetheless retains some control over rent extraction. The policy positions of the two competing parties do not converge as they do in the case without uncertainty. I show in an example that this nonconvergence can increase the welfare of the representative voter.
1 Introduction
Do voters reward incumbents for past success and honesty or do they disregard the past and only consider future policies when they vote? This is one of the most fundamental questions for a positive theory of electoral competition. In models of pre-election politics, candidates commit to their post-election actions before the election takes place. In contrast, in models of post-election politics, politicians are free to decide about their policies when they are in office. However, in the successive election, the voters can condition their vote on the performance of the incumbent party.[1]
In this paper, I combine a simple prospective model of Downsian spatial electoral competition on an ideological policy dimension and a simple retrospective model of electoral accountability with rent extraction. Specifically, parties commit to a policy position before an election takes place, as in Downs (1957), but decide on the level of rent extraction once they are in office, as in Barro (1973) and the simplified model of political accountability discussed in Persson and Tabellini (2000).
In the baseline model in Section 2, I show that, as long as there is certainty about the position of the representative voter, having voters with divergent policy preferences does not restrict the possibility of holding politicians accountable. The possible equilibrium rent levels are the same as in a model without the additional ideological policy dimension. The representative voter achieves this by following a straightforward and intuitive lexicographic voting strategy. More specifically, if the parties commit to policy positions that differ in attractiveness to a voter, the voter casts her vote for the party that minimizes her disutility on the policy dimension. Only when she is indifferent with respect to the parties’ policy platforms, she conditions her vote on the degree of rent extraction of the incumbent party. She supports the incumbent party only if the rents have not exceeded a maximum acceptable level. I call this voting strategy “lexicographic” because voters cast their votes as if they had lexicographic preferences over policy and rents.[2] My model is the first to show that lexicographic voting reconciles backward-looking and forward-looking voting when the identity of the decisive voter is known. The lowest possible rent level that is sustainable in equilibrium is positive, but smaller than the maximum rent the incumbent party could extract. Moreover, it is the same as in a model without ideological policy dimension.
The lexicographic voting strategy forces the parties to converge on the policy dimension, and also allows for control of the incumbent party’s rent extraction. It is intuitive that a voter who is indifferent will take past actions of the parties into account, whereas it is impossible for a rational forward-looking voter to consider the past when she is not indifferent with respect to the future.
Generally, the equilibria in backward-looking models hinge on the fact that voters are indifferent between the incumbent party and the opposition and can therefore reward or punish past actions while playing undominated strategies. The fact that a simple strategy can solve the accountability problem in a model combining rent extraction with Downsian competition can be explained by the fact that competition on the ideological policy dimension forces both parties to choose the same platform so that voters are indeed indifferent between the parties in equilibrium. Full convergence of policy is a result of the lack of uncertainty over the preferences of the representative voter in the baseline model.
Section 3 provides the most interesting results. It shows that with uncertainty over voters’ preferences, the minimum equilibrium rent extraction by the incumbent party increases. Because the parties do not know the position of the representative voter’s bliss point with certainty, the opposition party now has a chance of winning office by offering a different policy position than the incumbent party. Nonetheless, the incumbent party has an incentive to accept rents below the maximum level in return for being re-elected whenever the voters are indifferent between the policy positions of the two parties as this increases its chances of being reelected. Now, the parties play mixed strategies and choose different policy positions with positive probability in equilibrium. Consequently, convergence of policy platforms becomes random and the exception rather than the rule. In equilibrium the incumbent party wins with a probability that is larger than 50%, but not with certainty.
Platform divergence is an interesting result because it is usually observed only in models where uncertainty over the preferences of the representative voter is combined with ideological politicians, and not in models in which parties have no policy preferences (Persson and Tabellini 2000). The reason is simply that in standard models without rent-seeking there is one platform that maximizes the probability of winning for both parties, but this is no longer the case when voters decide according to past behavior when they are indifferent. In addition, the minimum amount of rent-seeking is now partly determined by the additional ideological dimension of policy. Consequently, relying on a separate analysis for accountability and competition on the policy dimension could not capture this important interaction between accountability and policy choice, although backward-looking and forward-looking voting motives are combined in the strategy of the voter in the same way as in the case with certainty.
1.1 Related Literature
Models of pre-election politics are especially popular for modeling spatial policy choices in the tradition of Downs (1957), where voters decide between announced policy positions, while models of post-election politics are often, but not exclusively, applied to accountability issues. In models of post-election politics, politicians are induced to put in more effort or to limit rent extraction due to the possibility of losing the successive election and office if they do not comply (Barro 1973). Essentially, these accountability models apply a principal-agent framework to elections with the politicians as agents and the voters as their principals.[3]
Van Weelden (2013) and a follow-up paper that provides some additional results, Van Weelden (2015), provide, to the best of my knowledge, the only other model that combines rent-seeking and competition on policy positions. A major difference to my model is that, instead of parties, Van Weelden assumes a continuum of possible candidates who are ideological and cannot commit to policy platforms. As a consequence, incumbent parties can be held accountable by the threat of the election of an alternative candidate who implements policies they do not like. This reduces the minimum rents sustainable in equilibrium, but comes at the cost of policies that diverge from the bliss point of the representative voter. It remains open how the model could deal with uncertainty over the preferences of the representative voter.
There is a growing subbranch of the literature on political accountability that is dealing with the question how elections can incentivize politicians to exert effort when effort is not directly observable. This literature is related to my model because the rents in my setup could alternatively be interpreted as shirking by the party of politician in office (that is, the politician does not provide the optimal amount of unobservable effort).[4] The major difference to my approach is that while my model researches the interaction with competition (and in Section 3 also uncertainty) on a Downsian policy dimension, the literature so far focuses on heterogeneity (and uncertainty over) the candidates’ types. Many ideas in this literature go back to a seminal theoretical paper by Holmström (1982) and were applied to elections by Banks and Sundaram (1993). The main difference to a standard principal-agent problem is that the payoff of the agent cannot be directly linked to the output produced. However, output can still influence future wage (Holmström), respectively, the reelection prospects of a politician (Banks and Sundaram). A more recent paper in this vein is Schwabe (2011). He presents a model closely related to Banks and Sundaram, but while Banks and Sundaram present only equilibria in which voters use simple retrospective voting rules with a performance threshold that is the same in all periods (as in the model presented here), Schwabe shows that in his slightly less general setup equilibria exist in which the performance threshold is not constant over time, voters are better off and the equilibrium is renegotiation proof. Moreover, contrary to the results in Banks and Sundaram, voters are in equilibrium indifferent between high-quality and low-quality politicians. Ashworth, de Mesquita, and Friedenberg (2010) combine models of selecting high-quality politicians with rewarding effort of politicians and ask whether it is possible to incentivize politicians even when it is known that not all politicians have the same quality. Moreover, this paper contains a very useful discussion about the distinction between standard setting for creating incentives (as in the model presented here) and standard setting for the purpose of selecting good types and shows that the two purposes can be consistent with each other.
Several papers on Downsian competition are related to the model I present. Aragones and Palfrey (2002) model Downsian competition in a model where one of the candidates is of higher quality. As a consequence, just as in the model with uncertainty presented in Section 3, there is only an equilibrium in mixed strategies. While Aragones and Palfrey (2002) present a one-shot model, the model I present is a contribution to the literature that models electoral competition on an ideological policy dimension as a repeated game. Important papers in this literature are Duggan (2000), Duggan and Fey (2006), Aragones, Palfrey, and Postlewaite (2007) and Banks and Duggan (2008). However, none of these papers considers the rent-seeking issue. Duggan (2000) and Banks and Duggan (2008) model repeated elections when the policy preferences of the candidates are private information. The first paper shows that there is an equilibrium that is consistent with prospective and retrospective voting at the same time, while the second paper extends the model to multiple policy dimensions. Aragones, Palfrey, and Postlewaite (2007) address the credibility of policy announcements when politicians have policy preferences that are known to the voters, a problem that makes a dynamic model necessary. Not surprisingly, what kind of promises politicians can make in a credible way depends on their policy preferences. Similar to Duggan (2000) and Banks and Duggan (2008), it is shown that how policy compromise is possible in repeated games with ideological candidates.
Duggan and Fey (2006) assume parties that care only about winning office. Their paper shows what kind of equilibria are possible in an infinitely repeated Downsian model of political competition. As the folk theorem suggests, many equilibria can be supported in a model of repeated elections. Duggan and Fey (2006) make some additional restrictions that are standard in game-theoretic models of elections and show that arbitrary paths of policies can be supported in equilibrium if some conditions on discount factors hold.
1.2 Organization of the Paper
The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 develops the model with certainty about the position of the representative voter and discusses its equilibrium. Section 3 shows that uncertainty over the position of the representative voter leads to less electoral accountability and higher minimum rents in equilibrium. The paper ends with a conclusion and an example for an equilibrium with uncertainty is provided in the Appendix.
2 The Model
I consider a polity with two parties interested in winning office only for rent-seeking purposes, and voters interested in policy as well as rent reduction. The ideological policy space is the interval
where rents in future periods are discounted by the factor
The representative (median) voter’s utility is given by:
where
2.1 The Order of Moves
The order of moves is the following: In any period
2.2 Strategies
To denote the entire history of a variable
2.3 Stationarity
In the analysis, we consider only subgame perfect equilibria with strategies that are stationary and symmetric according to the following definition:[5]
Stationary symmetric strategies.
Strategies are stationary if and only if:
The voting decision of the representative voter depends only on announced policy positions and rent-seeking by the incumbent party in the previous period.
The parties’ rent-seeking and policy platforms are not influenced by the history of the game.
The parties’ strategies are symmetric if and only if:
Both parties play the same strategy.
Strategies that are stationary and symmetric are called stationary symmetric strategies.
2.3.1 Discussion of Stationarity and Symmetry
In a stationary equilibrium in which both parties follow the same strategy, the representative voter is not able to influence the future policy announcements or rents. As a consequence, when she maximizes her utility with respect to policy in the next period, she also maximizes her total utility. This has the advantage that the results are robust to changes in voters’ preferences and changes in the electorate when we interpret the representative voter as the median voter of the electorate whose identity can change over time. In addition, our definition of stationarity implies that on the policy dimension the analysis essentially boils down to the analysis of a one-shot game as in standard models of Downsian competition and the fact that the election game is infinitely repeated allows us to deal with issues of rent-seeking and accountability in the way that is standard in the accountability literature. Consequently, the differences to the results in the literature that we will find in Section 3 are due to the interaction of accountability and Downsian competition, and not to the additional dynamics of the game.
2.4 An Equilibrium with Lexicographic Voting
The strategies formulated in Proposition 1 constitute an equilibrium which has all the essential features of a backward-looking model in the tradition of Barro (1973) and Ferejohn (1986) as well as those of a forward-looking model in the tradition of Downs (1957). Parties converge on the ideological dimension and rents are at the lowest level sustainable in the purely backward-looking model without policy dimension. This is the result of the intuitive lexicographic voting strategy. The representative voter casts her ballot in favor of her preferred policy position. Only when she is indifferent in this respect does she decide according to past rent extraction by the incumbent party. With this a strategy, she encounters no credibility or time-inconsistency problem.
An equilibrium of the game is constituted by the following strategies: The parties play
where
The representative voter plays
Given the strategies, it follows that
The party with the support of the representative voter wins. Given the equilibrium strategies of the parties,
Given the strategies of the parties, the representative voter in period
The fact that the opposition party cannot be better off by deviating follows from the fact that given the position and rent extraction of the incumbent party and the strategy of the representative voter, it either wins with certainty or has no possibility of winning office. Moreover, it cannot influence any election results or rent payments in the future with its choice of policy position. For the incumbent party, any policy position different from
Therefore, no deviation from the given strategy increases the utility of the incumbent party. ■
The identity of the incumbent party in period
There is no equilibrium with a present discounted value of future rent payments in any period
Suppose that there is an equilibrium with
Therefore, the equilibrium rent level in Proposition 1 gives a lower bound for rents in equilibrium.[6] The rent level is identical to the lower bound on rent extraction in a model without a policy dimension.[7]
As is also common in models of political accountability, the given equilibrium is not unique and other equilibria with larger rent payments exist. However, the existence of the equilibrium presented above is sufficient to establish that retrospective and prospective motives in voting are not inconsistent with each other. The voter who represents the median preferences of the electorate has only one instrument, namely her single vote, but this is sufficient to control policy as well as to hold politicians accountable to a certain degree.
While certainty over the preferences of the median voter and our restriction to symmetric stationary strategies seems to imply convergence on the policy dimension, there are equilibria without full policy convergence because a party that never wins in equilibrium can choose any policy position. However, there are no equilibria with symmetric stationary strategies that lead to policies different from the median bliss point.
2.5 Discussion of the Different Treatment of Rents and Policy
I assume that commitments to electoral platforms are credible on the policy dimension, but lack credibility on the rent dimension. These are widely accepted standard assumptions for both types of models and thus it is important to explore whether combining them leads to results that cannot be found by looking at the models separately. A justification for the different treatment can be seen in the fact that parties have no reason to break their electoral promises with regard to policy because it does not enter their utility function.
3 Uncertainty Over the Electorate’s Preferences
So far, I have assumed that the identity of the representative voter is known when parties decide on their policy platforms. How robust are the results to relaxing this assumption? This section shows that voters retain some control over rent extraction in a straightforward and plausible equilibrium, where they follow again a lexicographic voting strategy as in Section 2. However, now parties do not converge on the policy dimension, and the minimum rent sustainable in equilibrium is larger.
The assumptions and the order of moves are the same as in Section 2. The only difference is that the favorite position of the representative voter is now uncertain.[8] Voters keep some control over rent extraction, but the control is limited because sometimes the incumbent party loses office even when it does not deviate and therefore can demand higher rents in equilibrium.
As before, there is one representative voter. Her expected utility is now given by:
where
The expected utility function of the parties
3.1 The Simultaneous Policy Choice Game
We now analyze a simultaneous policy choice of the parties, taking as given that a representative voter plays a lexicographic strategy similar to the one introduced in Section 2.4. Consequently, the representative voter elects the party she prefers with respect to the policy position whenever one of the two parties is closer to her policy bliss point, but votes for her favorite party
In the game at hand, for a party to maximize its expected payoff is the same as maximizing its probability of winning the elections. A strategy in the simultaneous policy choice game simply assigns a nonnegative probability
Without analyzing a specific simultaneous policy choice game described by two sets
so that
3.2 The Equilibrium with Uncertainty
Now we put together our analysis of the simultaneous move policy choice with the complete model. The following Proposition gives the equilibrium with the lowest possible rent level that can be achieved with lexicographic voting.
The equilibrium of the game with uncertainty over the bliss point of the representative voter with lexicographic voting and lowest possible rent extraction
Again, we can apply the single deviation principle. In Section 3.1, we have defined
The third possible deviation we have to check is the rent level chosen by the incumbent. Because the chances of reelection depend only on the threshold
It remains to show that a rent threshold of
The first equation gives the value of being in office and taking the equilibrium value of rent
The solution of the system of three equations is given by:
Consequently, given the strategies of the player an incumbent is indifferent between taking
3.3 Interpretation
Essentially, just in Section 2, due to stationarity of all strategies the parties play a one-shot game on the policy dimension. However, due to the uncertainty over the bliss point of the representative voter we no longer find policy platform convergence in all periods. This leads a major difference to most other models that combine prospective and retrospective voting motives (and Section 2): The representative voter is not always (in equilibrium) indifferent between the parties when she votes as in many papers mentioned in the introduction. This makes the intuition for and plausibility of the lexicographic voting strategy of the representative voter rather stronger. After all, in elections we often observe that some parties seem genuinely to offer policy positions that are more attractive to a majority of voters than other parties in an election. However, whenever they are indifferent voters can reward or punish the past behavior of the politicians in power. The more likely this is to be the case in equilibrium, the higher are the performance thresholds the voters can set.
3.4 Minimum Equilibrium Rent Level
Given symmetric stationary strategies as defined in Section 2.3, the party that offers the policy closest to the bliss point of the representative voter wins. This implies that there is no equilibrium with stationary strategy of the representative voter that would not give a party at least a chance of victory of at least
3.5 An Example
To provide an example for the equilibrium with uncertainty, we focus on a situation with just three possible policy positions. These are at the same time the three possible bliss points of the representative voter. The three possible bliss points are denoted
And from Proposition 2 we know that in equilibrium
3.5.1 Welfare
Lower rents make the representative voter better off for given policy. However, we now also compare the result of lexicographic voting to an equilibrium in which past behavior of the parties play no role for the decision of the representative voter as in a model of policy determination in which rent-seeking plays no role. If the representative voter always votes for the policy positions that makes her better off, but tosses a coin to determine her vote whenever she is indifferent instead of considering the past, the equilibrium strategy of both parties will be to always choose a rent
Thus, the expected loss on the policy dimension is increasing in
We want to contrast the welfare in a lexicographic equilibrium with a purely forward-looking model of electoral competition. In the purely forward-looking setup an indifferent representative voter does not consider the past, but throws a fair coin before making her voting decision. In such a setup both parties converge on the median bliss point even in the case of uncertainty as long as parties have no policy preferences. Consequently, the expected loss of the representative voter on the policy dimension is:
Now we can compare
Solving for
For
Thus, with lexicographic voting the representative voter achieves not only a lower rent level than in an equilibrium in which the past is not considered by the electorate, but also made better off (compared to a model with policy platform convergence on the median bliss point) by the policy divergence of the parties as long as she is not to risk averse. A risk-averse representative voter with large
4 Conclusion
It is surprising that until now, there seem to have been no attempts to combine models of retrospective voting with aspects of Downsian competition. My model shows that forward-looking and backward-looking motives can be reconciled in a single model. This should be considered in future empirical research because so far, the question seems to have been if voters vote retrospectively or prospectively. If there is not necessarily a contradiction, some empirical results might have to be re-evaluated.
As long as there is certainty about the position of the voter who represents the median preferences of the electorate, I find that on the policy dimension where commitment is possible, the usual median voter results apply, while rent extraction by politicians is limited to the same degree as in a standard model without a policy dimension. If there is uncertainty over the position of the representative voter, voters cannot limit rent extraction to the same degree as in the case with certainty about the preference of the representative voter, but accountability is not completely lost either. The reason is that even when the incumbent party complies with the voters demands for limited rent extraction, it will still lose office if the opposition party commits to a policy that is more attractive to the majority of voters. Models of political accountability can explain the often observed incumbency advantage, as is pointed out by Austen-Smith and Banks (1989). Models in the Downsian tradition, on the other hand, provide no explanation for an incumbency advantage. My basic model in Section 2 leads to the implausible result that in equilibrium, the incumbent party is always re-elected. In the extended model with uncertainty over the exact position of the representative voter in Section 3, I find that the incumbent party always has a chance of winning the elections that is larger than
Acknowledgement
I would like to thank Philippe Aghion, Ruixue Jia, Thomas Kittsteiner, David Levine, Massimo Morelli, Torsten Persson, Christian Schultz, David Strömberg, Rongrong Sun and Richard van Weelden for helpful comments and suggestions. I am also grateful to an anonymous referee who had several insights that helped to improve this research.
Appendix
The Example
We use
Given the structure of the game the expected payoffs are:
Next, suppose the challenger party would not play a totally mixed strategy. Then, playing a best reply against such a strategy, the favorite party would only play the positions played by the challenger with positive probability because this always gives a higher expected payoff than choosing any position that is never chosen by the challenger. But this is a contradiction because we have already established that the favorite plays a totally mixed strategy. Thus, both parties play totally mixed strategies in equilibrium.
A party is only willing to play a totally mixed strategy when it has the same expected payoff from all three possible policy positions, and we solve for the unique equilibrium using
From
Using
From
Using
Welfare in the Example
Given the equilibrium strategies of both players we can calculate the welfare implications of the equilibrium for the voters and contrast it with other models.
The probability that none of the parties chooses
Consequently, in any period a representative voter with bliss point
from policy because the distance between
Given the equilibrium strategies of the parties, the probability that both parties choose
The probability that at least one party chooses
Using the probability that both parties choose
We denote the expected loss of the representative voter on the policy dimension with
References
Aragones, E., and T. Palfrey. 2002. “Mixed Equilibrium in a Downsian Model with a Favored Candidate.” Journal of Economic Theory 103 (1):131–61.10.1006/jeth.2001.2821Search in Google Scholar
Aragones, E., T. Palfrey, and A. Postlewaite. 2007. “Political Reputations and Campaign Promises.” Journal of the European Economic Association 5 (4):846–84.10.1162/JEEA.2007.5.4.846Search in Google Scholar
Ashworth, S. 2012. “Electoral Accountability: Recent Theoretical and Empirical Work.” Annual Review of Political Science 15:183–201.10.1146/annurev-polisci-031710-103823Search in Google Scholar
Ashworth, S., E. de Mesquita, and A. Friedenberg. 2010. “Creating Incentives and Selecting Good Types Revisited.” Unpublished Manuscript.Search in Google Scholar
Austen-Smith, D., and J. Banks. 1989. “Electoral Accountability and Incumbency.” In Models of Strategic Choice in Politics, edited by P. Ordeshook, 121–50. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Search in Google Scholar
Banks, J., and J. Duggan. 2008. “A Dynamic Model of Democratic Elections in Multidimensional Policy Spaces.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 3 (3):269–99.10.1561/100.00006009Search in Google Scholar
Banks, J. S., and R. K. Sundaram. 1993. “Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard in a Repeated Elections Model.” In Political Economy: Institutions, Information, Competition, and Representation, edited by M. Hinich, M. H. W. Bartnett and N. Schofield, 295–311. New York: Cambridge University Press.Search in Google Scholar
Barro, R. 1973. “The Control of Politicians: An Economic Model.” Public Choice 14 (1):19–42.10.1007/BF01718440Search in Google Scholar
Bernhardt, D., J. Duggan, and F. Squintani. 2009. “The Case for Responsible Parties.” American Political Science Review 103 (4):570–87.10.1017/S0003055409990232Search in Google Scholar
Besley, T. 2006. Principled Agents? The Political Economy of Good Government. New York: Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar
Downs, A. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harpers and Collins.Search in Google Scholar
Duggan, J. 2000. “Repeated Elections with Asymmetric Information.” Economics & Politics 12 (2):109–35.10.1111/1468-0343.00071Search in Google Scholar
Duggan, J., and M. Fey. 2006. “Repeated Downsian Electoral Competition.” International Journal of Game Theory 35 (1):39–69.10.1007/s00182-006-0046-1Search in Google Scholar
Dutter, L. 1981. “Voter Preferences, Simple Electoral Games, and Equilibria in Two-Candidate Contests.” Public Choice 37 (3):403–423.10.1007/BF00133742Search in Google Scholar
Ferejohn, J. 1986. “Incumbent Performance and Electoral Control.” Public Choice 50 (1):5–25.10.1007/BF00124924Search in Google Scholar
Holmström, B. 1982. Managerial incentive problems: A dynamic perspective. Essays in Economics and Management in Honor of Lars Wahlbeck. Swedish School of Economics; reprinted in Review of Economic Studies 66 (1999):169–82.10.1111/1467-937X.00083Search in Google Scholar
Hotelling, H. 1929. “Stability in Competition.” The Economic Journal 39 (153):41–57.10.1007/978-1-4613-8905-7_4Search in Google Scholar
Martinez, L. 2009. “A Theory of Political Cycles.” Journal of Economic Theory 144 (3):1166–86.10.1016/j.jet.2008.10.006Search in Google Scholar
Mas-Colell, A., M. D. Whinston, J. R. Green. 1995. Microeconomic Theory. New York: Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar
Myerson, R. 1991. Game Theory: Analysis of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Search in Google Scholar
Persson, T., and G. Tabellini. 2000. Political Economics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar
Schwabe, R. 2011. “Reputation and Accountability in Repeated Elections.” Unpublished Manuscript.Search in Google Scholar
Soberman, D., and L. Sadoulet. 2007. “Campaign Spending Limits and Political Advertising.” Management Science 53 (10):1521–32.10.1287/mnsc.1070.0717Search in Google Scholar
Van Weelden, R. 2013. “Candidates, Credibility, and Re-election Incentives.” Review of Economic Studies 80 (4):1622–51.10.1093/restud/rdt014Search in Google Scholar
Van Weelden, R. 2015. “The Welfare Implications of Electoral Polarization.” Social Choice and Welfare. Forthcoming.10.1007/s00355-015-0874-7Search in Google Scholar
©2015 by De Gruyter
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Advances
- Turf and Illegal Drug Market Competition between Gangs
- Do Environmental Regulations Increase Bilateral Trade Flows?
- A Macroeconomic Model of Imperfect Competition with Patent Licensing
- Contributions
- Heterogeneous Effects of Informational Nudges on Pro-social Behavior
- Limiting Profit Shifting in a Model with Heterogeneous Firm Productivity
- Public Education, Accountability, and Yardstick Competition in a Federal System
- Social Status, Conspicuous Consumption Levies, and Distortionary Taxation
- Optimal Regulation of Invasive Species Long-Range Spread: A General Equilibrium Approach
- Cooperation or Competition? A Field Experiment on Non-monetary Learning Incentives
- Geographic Mobility and the Costs of Job Loss
- Supply Chain Control: A Theory of Vertical Integration
- Lexicographic Voting: Holding Parties Accountable in the Presence of Downsian Competition
- Topics
- The Transmission of Education across Generations: Evidence from Australia
- Tying to Foreclose in Two-Sided Markets
- Smoking within the Household: Spousal Peer Effects and Children’s Health Implications
- The Dynamics of Offshoring and Institutions
- Long-Run Effects of Catholic Schooling on Wages
- The Interdependence of Immigration Restrictions and Expropriation Risk
- The Effects of Extensive and Intensive Margins of FDI on Domestic Employment: Microeconomic Evidence from Italy
- Are You There God? It’s Me, a College Student: Religious Beliefs and Higher Education
Articles in the same Issue
- Frontmatter
- Advances
- Turf and Illegal Drug Market Competition between Gangs
- Do Environmental Regulations Increase Bilateral Trade Flows?
- A Macroeconomic Model of Imperfect Competition with Patent Licensing
- Contributions
- Heterogeneous Effects of Informational Nudges on Pro-social Behavior
- Limiting Profit Shifting in a Model with Heterogeneous Firm Productivity
- Public Education, Accountability, and Yardstick Competition in a Federal System
- Social Status, Conspicuous Consumption Levies, and Distortionary Taxation
- Optimal Regulation of Invasive Species Long-Range Spread: A General Equilibrium Approach
- Cooperation or Competition? A Field Experiment on Non-monetary Learning Incentives
- Geographic Mobility and the Costs of Job Loss
- Supply Chain Control: A Theory of Vertical Integration
- Lexicographic Voting: Holding Parties Accountable in the Presence of Downsian Competition
- Topics
- The Transmission of Education across Generations: Evidence from Australia
- Tying to Foreclose in Two-Sided Markets
- Smoking within the Household: Spousal Peer Effects and Children’s Health Implications
- The Dynamics of Offshoring and Institutions
- Long-Run Effects of Catholic Schooling on Wages
- The Interdependence of Immigration Restrictions and Expropriation Risk
- The Effects of Extensive and Intensive Margins of FDI on Domestic Employment: Microeconomic Evidence from Italy
- Are You There God? It’s Me, a College Student: Religious Beliefs and Higher Education